<<

Risk and of Collateralized Obligations

Darrell Duffie and Nicolae Gârleanu

In this discussion of analysis and valuation of collateralized debt obligations, we illustrate the effects of correlation and prioritization on valuation and discuss the “diversity score” (a measure of the risk of the CDO collateral pool that has been used for CDO risk analysis by rating agencies) in a simple setting for correlated intensities.

collateralized debt obligation is an - main issue we address is the impact of the joint backed whose collat- distribution of default risk of the underlying collat- eral is typically a portfolio of (corporate eral securities on the risk and valuation of the CDO A or sovereign) bonds or . A CDO . We are also interested in the efficacy of flow structure allocates income and alternative computational methods and the role of principal repayments from a collateral pool of dif- “diversity scores,” a measure of the risk of the CDO ferent debt instruments to a prioritized collection collateral pool that has been used for CDO risk of CDO securities, which we call “tranches.” analysis by rating agencies. Although many forms of prioritization exist, a stan- dard prioritization scheme is simple subordination: CDO Design and Valuation Senior CDO notes are paid before mezzanine and lower subordinated notes are paid, with any resid- In perfect capital markets, CDOs would serve no ual cash flow paid to an equity piece. We provide purpose; the costs of constructing and marketing a some examples of prioritization later in this article. CDO would inhibit its creation. In practice, CDOs A cash flow CDO is one for which the collateral address some important market imperfections. portfolio is not subjected to active trading by the First, and certain other financial institutions CDO manager, which implies that the uncertainty have regulatory capital requirements that make regarding interest and principal payments to the valuable the securitizing and selling of some por- CDO tranches is induced mainly by the number tion of their ; the value lies in reducing the and timing of defaults of the collateral securities. A amount of (expensive) regulatory capital they must market-value CDO is one in which the CDO tranches hold. Second, individual bonds or loans may be receive payments based essentially on the marked- illiquid, which reduces their market values; if secu- to-market returns of the collateral pool, as deter- ritization improves their liquidity, it raises the total mined largely by the trading performance of the valuation to the of the CDO structure. CDO manager. We concentrate here on cash flow In light of these market imperfections, at least CDOs, thus avoiding an analysis of the trading two classes of CDOs are popular. The behavior of CDO managers. CDO, typically in the form of a collateralized A generic example of the contractual relation- obligation (CLO), is designed to remove loans from ships involved in a CDO is shown in Figure 1. The the balance sheets of banks, thereby providing cap- ital relief and perhaps also increasing the valuation collateral manager is charged with the selection 1 and purchase of collateral assets for the CDO spe- of the assets through an increase in liquidity. An cial-purpose vehicle (SPV). The trustee of the CDO CDO, often underwritten by an invest- is responsible for monitoring the contractual provi- ment bank, is designed to capture some fraction of sions of the CDO. Our analysis assumes perfect the likely difference between the total cost of adherence to these contractual provisions. The acquiring collateral assets in the and the value received from management fees and the sale of the associated CDO structure. Balance sheet CDOs are normally of the cash flow type. Darrell Duffie is James I. Miller Professor of and Arbitrage CDOs may be collateralized obli- Nicolae Gârleanu is a graduate student at the Stanford gations and have either cash flow or market-value University Graduate School of Business. structures.

January/February 2001 41

Financial Analysts Journal

Figure 1. Typical CDO Contractual Relationships

Ongoing Communication Collateral Trustee Manager

CDO Underlying Provider Special-Purpose Securities (if needed) (collateral) Vehicle

Mezzanine Senior Fixed/ Subordinated Fixed/Floating- Floating-Rate Notes/Equity Notes Rate Notes

Source: Morgan Stanley, from Schorin and Weinreich (1998).

Among the sources of illiquidity that promote, For a relatively small junk bond or a single or limit, the use of CDOs are adverse selection, bank loan to a relatively obscure borrower, the trading costs, and . market of potential buyers and sellers may be 2 With regard to adverse selection, enough pri- small; thus, trading may be costly. Searching for vate information may exist about the quality such buyers can be expensive, for example, and to of a junk bond or a bank loan that an is sell such an illiquid asset quickly, one may be concerned about being “picked off” when trading forced to sell to the highest bidder among the rela- such an instrument. For instance, a better-informed tively few buyers with whom one can negotiate on seller has an to trade or not at the given notice. One’s negotiating may also price. The value of this option is related to the be poorer than it would be in an active market. The quality of the seller’s private information. Given value of the asset is correspondingly reduced. the risk of being picked off, the buyer offers a price Potential buyers recognize that they are placing themselves at the risk of facing the same situation that, on average, is below the price at which the when they try to resell in the future, which results asset would be sold in a setting of symmetric infor- in yet lower valuations. The net cost of bearing mation. This reduction in price as a result of these costs may be reduced through adverse selection is sometimes called a “lemon’s into relatively large homogeneous senior CDO premium” (Akerlof 1970). tranches, perhaps with significant retention of In general, adverse selection cannot be elimi- smaller and less easily traded junior tranches. nated by securitization of assets in a CDO, but it can Moral hazard, in the context of CDOs, bears on be mitigated. The seller achieves a higher total the issuer’s or CDO manager’s incentives to select valuation (for what is sold and what is retained) by high-quality assets for the CDO and to engage in designing the CDO structure so as to concentrate costly enforcement of covenants and other restric- into small subordinate tranches the majority of the tions on the behavior of obligors. Securitizing and risk that may be cause for adverse selection. For selling a significant portion of the cash flows of the example, a large senior , relatively immune underlying assets dilute these incentives. Reduc- to the effects of adverse selection, can be sold at a tions in value through lack of effort are borne to small lemon’s premium. The issuer can retain, on some extent by . Also, the opportunity average, significant fractions of the smaller subor- may arise for “cherry picking” (sorting assets into dinate tranches, which are more subject to adverse the issuer’s own portfolio or into the SPV portfolio selection. For models supporting this design and based on the issuer’s private information). In addi- retention behavior, see DeMarzo (1999) and tion, opportunities may arise for , in DeMarzo and Duffie (1999). which a CDO manager trades on its own account

42 ©2001, Association for Management and Research¨

Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations in advance of trades on behalf of the CDO. These tranches, with their ratings. The bulk of the under- moral hazards act against the creation of CDOs, lying assets are floating-rate NationsBank loans because the incentives to select and monitor assets rated BBB or BB. Any fixed-rate loans were hedged promote greater efficiency and higher valuation if in terms of risk by fixed-to-floating the issuer retains a 100 percent interest in the asset interest rate swaps. As predicted by theory, cash flows. NationsBank retained the majority of the (unrated) The opportunity to reduce the other market lowest tranche. imperfections through a CDO may be sufficiently Our valuation model does not deal directly large—especially in light of the advantages in with the effects of market imperfections. It takes as building and maintaining a reputation for not given the default risk of the underlying loans and exploiting CDO investors—to offset the effects of assumes that investors are symmetrically moral hazard. In this case, the issuer has an incen- informed. Although this approach is not perfectly tive to design the CDO so that the issuer retains a realistic, it is not necessarily inconsistent with the significant portion of one or more subordinate roles of moral hazard or adverse selection in the tranches that would be among the first to suffer original security design. For example, DeMarzo losses stemming from poor monitoring or poor and Duffie demonstrated a “fully separating equi- asset selection. Doing so demonstrates a degree of librium,” in which the sale price of the security or commitment to diligent efforts to manage the issue. the amount retained by the seller signals to all Similarly, for arbitrage CDOs, a significant portion of the management fees may be subordinated to the investors any of the seller’s privately held value- issued tranches (Schorin and Weinreich 1998). In relevant information. Moral hazard can be light of this commitment, investors may be willing addressed by the model because the diligence of the to pay more for tranches, and the total valuation to issuer or manager is, to a large extent, determined the issuer will be higher than in an unprioritized by the security design and the fractions retained by structure, such as a straight equity pass-through the issuer. Once these factors are known, the security. Innes (1990) described a model that sup- default risk of the underlying debt is also known. ports this motive for security design. Our simple model does not, however, account for An example of a CLO structure consistent with the valuation effects of many other forms of market this theory is shown in Figure 2. The figure illus- imperfections. Moreover, inferring separate risk trates one of a pair of CLO cash flow structures premiums for default timing and default recovery issued by NationsBank in 1997. A senior tranche of from the prices of the underlying debt and market $2 billion in face value, whose credit rating is AAA, risk-free interest rates is generally difficult (see is followed by successively lower subordination Duffie and Singleton 1999.) These risk premiums

Figure 2. NationsBank CLO Tranches for Three-Year Floating Rate Notes

Obligors $2,164 million

Issuer Interest Rate Swaps

A. $2,000 million (AAA) B. $43 million (A) C. $54 million (BBB) D. $64 million (not rated)

Source: Fitch.

January/February 2001 43

Financial Analysts Journal play separate roles in the valuation of CDO We adopt a pre-intensity model that is a special tranches. We simply take these risk premiums as case of the “affine” family of processes that have given in the form of “risk-neutral” parametric mod- been used for this purpose and for modeling short- els for default timing and recovery distributions term interest rates.5 Specifically, we suppose that under an equivalent martingale measure. each obligor’s default time has some pre-intensity process λ solving a differential equation Default Risk Model of the form λ() κθ[] λ() σλ() () ∆ () We lay out some of the basic default modeling for d t = Ð t dt + t dW t + Jt , (3) the underlying collateral. First, we propose a sim- where W is a standard Brownian motion and ∆J(t) ple model for the default risk of one obligor. Then, denotes any jump that occurs at time t of a pure- we turn to the multi-issuer setting. Throughout, we jump process J, independent of W, whose jump work under risk-neutral probabilities, so value is sizes are independent and exponentially distrib- given by expectations of discounted future cash uted with mean µ and whose jump times are those flows. If objective likelihoods or variances are of of an independent Poisson process with mean jump interest, however, the results should be interpreted arrival rate l. (Jump times and jump sizes are also as if the probabilities were actual, not risk neutral. independent.6) We call a process λ of this form (Equation 3) a basic affine process with parameters (κ, Obligor Default Intensity. We suppose that θ, σ, µ, l ). These parameters can be adjusted in each underlying obligor defaults at some expected several ways to control the manner in which default arrival rate. The idea is that at each time t before the risk changes over time. For example, we can vary default time τ of the given obligor, the default the mean-reversion rate κ, the -run mean arrives at some “intensity” λ(t), given all currently m = θ + ()κl µ ⁄ , or the relative contributions to λ available information. We thus have the approxi- the total variance of t that are attributed to jump mation risk and to diffusive . We can also vary the relative contributions to P ()λτ < t + ∆t ≅ ()∆t t t (1) jump risk of the mean jump size µ and the mean for the conditional probability at the time t of jump arrival rate l. A special case is the no-jump default within a “small” time interval ∆t > 0.3 For (l = 0) model of Feller (1951), which was used by example, if time is measured in years (as we do Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985) to model interest rates. From the results of Duffie and Kan (1996), here), a current default intensity of 0.04 implies that ≥ the conditional probability of default within the we can calculate that for any t and any s 0, next three months is approximately 0.01. Immedi- + α()s + β()λs ()t E []exp()tsÐλ du = e , (4) ately after default, the intensity drops to zero. Sto- t ∫t u chastic variation in the intensity over time, as new where explicit solutions for the coefficients α(s) and information becomes available, reflects any β(s) are provided in Appendix A. Together, Equa- changes in perceived credit quality. Correlation tion 2 and Equation 4 give a simple, reasonably rich, across obligors in the changes over time of their and tractable model for the default time probability credit qualities is reflected by correlation in the distribution and how it varies at random over time changes of those obligors’ default intensities. as information arrives in the market. Indeed, our model has the property that all correla- 4 tion in default timing arises in this manner. We call Multi-Issuer Default Model. To study the λ a a pre-intensity for a stopping implications of changing the correlation in the τ τ time if whenever t < , first, the current intensity default times of the various participations (collat- λ is t and, second, eralizing bonds or loans) in a CDO while holding constant the default risk model of each underlying P ()τ > ts+ = E []()ts+ Ðλ du t t exp ∫t u , s>0, (2) obligor, we will exploit the following result. We state that a basic affine model can be written as the where Et denotes conditional expectation given all sum of independent basic affine models as long as information at time t and s is the length of the the parameters κ, σ, and µ governing, respectively, period over which survival (no default) is consid- the mean reversion rate, diffusive volatility, and ered. A pre-intensity need not fall to zero after mean jump size are common to the underlying pair default. For example, default at a constant pre- of independent basic affine processes. intensity of 0.04 means that the intensity itself is Proposition 1: Suppose X and Y are indepen- 0.04 until default and is zero thereafter. dent basic affine processes with respective

44 ©2001, Association for and Research¨ Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations

κ θ σ µ κ θ σ µ parameters ( , X, , , l X) and ( , Y, , , l Y). easy. We can use the independence of the underly- Then, X + Y is a basic affine process with ing state variables to see that κ θ σ µ parameters ( , , , , l ), where l = l X + l Y and θ θ θ 7 ts+ = X + Y. E exp[]∫ Ðλ ()u du tt i This result allows us to maintain a fixed, par- (7) α() β() () β () () β() ()] simonious, and tractable one-factor Markov model = exp[ s ++i s Xi t ci() s Yci() t +z s Zt , for each obligor’s default probabilities while vary- where α(s) = α (s) + α (s) + α (s) and all the α and ing the correlations between different obligors’ i c(i) Z β coefficients are obtained explicitly from Appen- default times, as explained in the following discus- dix A, from the respective parameters of the under- sion. lying basic affine processes X , Y , and Z. Suppose that the N participations in the collat- i c(i) Even more generally, we can adopt multifactor eral pool have default times τ , . . ., τ with pre- 1 N affine models in which the underlying state vari- intensity processes λ , . . ., λ , respectively, that are 1 N ables are not independent. Interest rates that are basic affine processes.8 To introduce correlation in jointly determined by an underlying multifactor a simple way, we suppose that affine jump diffusion model can also be accommo- λ i = Xc + Xi, (5) dated. We refer the interested reader to the Duffie and Gârleanu 1999 working paper. where Xc and Xi are basic affine processes with, κ θ σ µ κ θ σ respectively, parameters ( , c, , , l c) and ( , i, , Recovery Risk. µ We suppose that, at default, , l i) and where X1, . . ., XN and Xc are independent. λ any given piece of debt in the collateral pool may By Proposition 1, i is itself a basic affine process κ θ σ µ θ θ θ be sold for a fraction of its face value whose risk- with parameters ( , , , , l ), where = c + i and neutral conditional expectation, given all informa- l = l c + l i. One may view Xc as a state process tion available at any time t before default, is a governing common aspects of economic perfor- constant f ∈ ()01, that does not depend on t. The mance in an industry, sector, or region and recovery fractions of the underlying participations Xi as a state variable governing the idiosyncratic are assumed to be independently distributed and default risk specific to obligor i. The parameter independent of default times and interest rates. (Here again, we are referring to risk-neutral behav- l c ρ = ----- , (6) ior.) For simplicity, we assume throughout that the l recovered fraction of face value is uniformly dis- tributed on (0, 1). is the long-run fraction of jumps to a given obligor’s intensity that are common to all (surviving) obli- Collateral Credit Spreads. We suppose for gors’ intensities. One can also see that ρ is the λ simplicity that changes in default intensities and probability that the pre-intensity j jumps at time t λ changes in interest rates are (risk-neutrally) inde- given that i jumps at time t for any time t and any 9 θ ρθ pendent. Combined with the preceding assump- distinct i and j. We also suppose that c = . tions, this implies that for an issuer whose default time τ has a basic affine pre-intensity process λ, a Sectoral, Regional, and Global Risk. Exten- zero- bond maturing at time t has an initial sions of the model to handle multifactor risk market value of (regional, sectoral, and other sources) could easily α()t + β()λt ()0 be incorporated with repeated use of Proposition 1. p[]δt, λ()0 = ()t e + f ∫t δ()πu ()u du, (8) Suppose, for example, that we have S different 0 sectors. We denote by c(i) the sector to which the ith where δ(t) denotes the default-free zero-coupon obligor belongs; consequently, c(1), c(2), . . ., c(S) are discount to time t and disjoint and exhaustive subsets of (1, 2, . . ., N). τ π()u = Ð -----d-P()τ > u Suppose that the default time i of the ith obligor du λ (9) has a pre-intensity i = Xi + Yc(i) + Z, where the α()u + β()λu ()0 = Ðe []α′()u + β′()λu ()0 sector factor Yc(i) is common to all in the “sector” c(i), where Z is common to all issuers, and is the (risk-neutral) probability density at time u of where (X1, . . ., XN, Y1, . . .,YS, Z) are independent the default time. basic affine processes. The first term of Equation 8 is the market value If we do not restrict the parameters of the of a claim that pays 1 at in the event of underlying basic affine processes, then an individ- survival. The second term is the market value of a ual obligor’s pre-intensity need not itself be a basic claim to any default recovery between times 0 and affine process, but calculations are nevertheless t. The integral is computed numerically by use of

January/February 2001 45 Financial Analysts Journal our explicit solutions from Appendix A for α(t) and n! k nkÐ qkn(), = ------p ()1 Ð p , (12) β(t).10 ()nkÐ !k! Using this defaultable discount function, p(•), where n! (read “n factorial”) is the product 1 × 2 × we can value any straight coupon bond or deter- … × n. From this “binomial-expansion” formula, a mine par coupon rates. For example, for quarterly risk analysis of the CDO can be conducted by coupon periods, the (annualized) par coupon rate, assuming that the performance of the collateral c(s), for maturity in s years (for an integer s > 0) is pool is sufficiently well approximated by the per- determined at any time t by the identity formance of the comparison portfolio. Table 1 shows the diversity score that cs()4s j 1 = ps(), λ + ------∑ p -- , λ , (10) Moody’s would apply to a collateral pool of t 4 4 t j = 1 equally sized bonds of different companies in the same industry.11 Table 1 also shows the implied which is easily solved for c(s). probability of default of one participation given We develop our numerical example with con- the default of another, as well as the implied cor- stant interest rates r, for which the risk-free dis- δ relations of the 0–1, survival–default, random vari- count has the simple form ables associated with any two participations for δ(t) = e–rt.(11)two levels of individual default probability, namely, p = 0.5 and p = 0.05. Diversity Scores. A key measure of collateral diversity developed by Moody’s Investors Service for CDO risk analysis is the diversity score. The Table 1. Diversity Scores, Conditional Default diversity score of a given pool of participations is Probabilities, and Default Correlations the number, n, of bonds in an idealized comparison Conditional Default Default portfolio that meets the following criteria: Number Probability Correlation • The total face value of the comparison portfolio of Diversity Companies Score (p = 0.5) (p = 0.05) (p = 0.5) (p = 0.05) is the same as the total face value of the collat- eral pool. 1 1.00 • The bonds of the comparison portfolio have 2 1.50 0.78 0.48 0.56 0.45 equal face values. 3 2.00 0.71 0.37 0.42 0.34 4 2.33 0.70 0.36 0.40 0.32 • The comparison bonds are equally likely to 5 2.67 0.68 0.33 0.36 0.30 default, and their default is independent. 6 3.00 0.67 0.31 0.33 0.27 • The comparison bonds are, in some sense, of 7 3.25 0.66 0.30 0.32 0.26 the same average default probability as the 8 3.50 0.65 0.29 0.31 0.25 participations of the collateral pool. 9 3.75 0.65 0.27 0.29 0.24 • The comparison portfolio has the same total 10 4.00 0.64 0.26 0.28 0.23 loss risk, according to some measure of risk, as does the collateral pool. Note: Situations in which the number of companies is greater than 10 are evaluated on a case-by-case basis. At least in terms of publicly available informa- tion, it is not clear how the (equal) probability p of default of the bonds of the comparison portfolio is determined. A method discussed by Schorin and Weinreich for this purpose is to assign a default Pricing Examples probability corresponding to the weighted-average In this section, we apply a standard risk-neutral rating score of the collateral pool by using pre- valuation approach to the pricing of determined rating scores and weights that are pro- CDO tranches. In the absence of any tractable alter- portional to face value. Given the average rating native, we use Monte Carlo simulation of the score, one can assign a default probability to the default times. Essentially, any intensity model resulting “average” rating. For the choice of prob- could be substituted for the basic affine model that ability p, Schorin and Winreich discussed the use of we have adopted here. An advantage of the affine the historical default frequency for that rating. model is the ability one has to quickly calibrate the A diversity score of n and a comparison-bond model to the underlying participations, in terms of default probability of p imply, under the indepen- given correlations, default probabilities, dence assumption for the comparison portfolio, spreads, and so on. that the probability of k defaults out of n bonds of We study various alternative CDO cash flow the comparison portfolio is structures and default risk parameters. The basic

46 ©2001, Association for Investment Management and Research¨ Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations

CDO structure consists of a special-purpose vehicle the 10-year par-coupon spread (in basis points) and λ that acquires a collateral portfolio of participations the long-run variance of i(t). To illustrate the qual- (debt instruments of various obligors) and allocates itative differences between parameter sets, Figure interest, principal, and default recovery cash flows 4 shows sample paths of new 10-year par spreads from the collateral pool to the CDO tranches—and for two issuers, one with the base-case parameters perhaps to a manager. (Set 1) and the other with pure-jump intensity (Set 2) calibrated to the same initial spread curve. Collateral. The collateral pool has N participa- tions. Each participation pays quarterly cash flows to the SPV at its coupon rate until maturity or default. At default, a participation is sold for its Table 2. Risk-Neutral Default Parameter Sets recovery value and the proceeds from the sale are Spread also made available to the SPV. Set κθ σ l µ (bps) var∞ Let A(k) denote the subset of {1, . . ., N} contain- 1 0.6 0.0200 0.141 0.2000 0.1000 254 0.42 ing the surviving participations at the kth coupon 2 0.6 0.0156 0.000 0.2000 0.1132 254 0.43 period. The total interest income in coupon period 3 0.6 0.0373 0.141 0.0384 0.2500 253 0.49 k is then 4 0.6 0.0005 0.141 0.5280 0.0600 254 0.41

() Ci With d denoting the event of default by the ith Wk = ∑ Mi----- , (13) i iAk∈ () n participation, Table 3 shows for each parameter set and each of three levels of the correlation parameter where M is the face value of participation i and C i i ρ, the unconditional probability of default and the is the coupon rate on participation i. conditional probability of default by one participa- If B(k) denotes the set of participations default- tion given default by another. Table 3 also shows ing between coupon periods k – 1 and k,12 the total the diversity score of the collateral pool that is cash flow in period k is implied by matching the (risk-neutral) variance of () () () the total loss of principal of the collateral portfolio Zk = Wk + ∑ Mi Ð Li , (14) iBk∈ () to that of a comparison portfolio of bonds of the same individual default probabilities.14 where Li is the loss of face value at the default of For our basic examples, we suppose, first, that participation i. any cash in the SPV reserve account is invested at For our example, the initial pool of collateral the default-free short-term rate. We later consider available to the CDO structure consists of N = 100 investment of SPV free cash flows in additional participations that are straight quarterly coupon risky participations. 10-year par bonds of equal face value. Without loss of generality, we take the face value of each bond Sinking-Fund Tranches. We consider a CDO to be 1. structure that pays SPV cash flows to a prioritized We initiate the common and the idiosyncratic sequence of sinking-fund bonds and a junior sub- risk factors, Xc and Xi, at their long-run means, ordinated residual. θ + µ/κ and θ + µ/κ, respectively. Thus, the c l c i l i In general, a sinking-fund bond with n coupon initial condition (and long-run mean) for each obli- periods per year has some remaining principal, gor’s (risk-neutral) default pre-intensity is 5.33 per- F(k), at coupon period k, some annualized coupon cent. Our base-case default-risk model is defined rate c, and a scheduled interest payment at coupon by Parameter Set Number 1 in Table 2 and by letting ρ = 0.5 determine the degree of diversifica- period k of F(k)c/n. In the event that the actual tion. The three other parameter sets shown in Table interest paid, Y(k), is less than the scheduled inter- 2 are designed to illustrate the effects of replacing est payment, any difference F(k)c/n–Y(k) is some or all of the diffusive volatility with jump accrued at the bond’s own coupon rate, c, so as to volatility or the effects of reducing the mean jump generate an accrued unpaid interest at period k of size and increasing the mean jump arrival fre- U(k), where U(0) = 0 and quency l.  Uk()= + --c- Uk()Ð + cFk()Ð Yk(). (15) All the parameter sets have the same long-run 1 n 1 n--- mean θ + µl/κ. The parameters θ, σ, l, and µ were adjusted so as to maintain essentially the same term To prioritize payments in light of the default and structure of zero-coupon yields, as illustrated in recovery history of the collateral pool, some pre- Figure 3.13 Table 2 provides, for each parameter set, payment of principal, D(k), and some contractual

January/February 2001 47 Financial Analysts Journal

Figure 3. Zero-Coupon Yield Spreads with and without Diffusion

Zero-Coupon (basis points) 280

260

240

220

200

180

160

140

120 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Maturity (years)

Base Case Zero Diffusion unpaid reduction in principal, J(k), may also occur rates of the tranches over the default-free par cou- in period k. By contract, we have D(k)+J(k) ≤ F(k – pon rate. 1), so the remaining principal at quarter k is Prioritization Schemes. We experiment with F(k) = F(k – 1) – D(k) – J(k). (16) the relative sizes and prioritization of two CDO At maturity (coupon period number K), any bond tranches, one 10-year senior sinking-fund unpaid accrued interest and unpaid principal, U(K) bond with some initial principal F1(0) = P1 and one and F(K), respectively, are paid to the extent pro- 10-year mezzanine sinking-fund bond with initial vided in the CDO contract. (A shortfall does not principal F2(0) = P2. The residual junior tranche constitute default so long as the contractual priori- receives any cash flow remaining at the end of the 15 tization scheme is maintained. ) The total actual 10-year structure. Because the base-case coupon payment in any coupon period k is Y(k) + D(k). rates on the senior and mezzanine CDO tranches The par coupon rate on a given sinking-fund are, by design, par rates, the base-case initial mar- bond is the scheduled coupon rate c with the prop- ket value of the residual tranche is P3 = 100 – P1 – P2. erty that the initial market value of the bond is At the kth coupon period, tranche j has a face equal to its initial face value, F(0). If the default-free value of Fj(k) and accrued unpaid interest Uj(k) short rate r(k) is constant, as in our results, any calculated at its own coupon rate, cj. Any excess sinking-fund bond that pays all remaining princi- cash flows from the collateral pool (interest income pal and all accrued unpaid interest by or at its and default recoveries) are deposited in a reserve maturity date has a par coupon rate equal to the account. To begin, we suppose that the reserve default-free coupon rate, no matter the timing of account earns interest at the default-free one- the interest and principal payments. period interest rate, denoted r(k) at the kth coupon We illustrate our initial valuation results in date. At maturity, coupon period K, any remaining terms of the par coupon spreads of the respective funds in the reserve account after payments at tranches, which are the excess of the par coupon quarter K to the two tranches are paid to the

48 ©2001, Association for Investment Management and Research¨ Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations

Figure 4. New 10-Year Par-Coupon Spreads for The reserve available before payments at the Base-Case Parameters and for period k, R(k), is thus defined by [recall that Z(k) is the Pure-Jump Intensity Parameters the total cash flow from the participations in Coupon Spread period k] (basis points) rk() Rk()= 1 + ------600 4 (17) a × []Rk()Ð 1 Ð Y ()k Ð 1 Ð Y ()k Ð 1 550 1 2 z + Zk(). 500 Unpaid reductions in principal from default losses occur in reverse priority order, so the junior 450 residual tranche suffers the reduction J (k) = min[F (k – 1), H(k)], (18) 400 3 3 where 350  () []() () () Hk = max∑ Li Ð Wk Ð Y1 k Ð Y2 k , 0 , (19) 300 iBk∈ () is the total of default losses since the previous cou- 250 pon date less collected and undistributed interest income. Then, the mezzanine and senior tranches 200 0 2 4 6 8 10 are successively reduced in principal by, respec- tively, Time (years) J2(k) = min[F2(k – 1), H(k) – J3(k)] (20a) Base Case Pure Jumps and subordinated residual tranche. (Later, we investi- J1(k) = min[F1(k – 1), H(k) – J3(k) – J2(k)]. (20b) gate the effects of investing the reserve account in Under uniform prioritization, no early pay- additional participations that are added to the col- ments of principal are made, so D (k) = D (k) = 0 for lateral pool.) We ignore management fees. 1 2 k < K. At maturity, the remaining reserve is paid in This example investigates valuation for two priority order, and principal and accrued interest prioritization schemes: Given the definition of the are treated identically, so without loss of generality sinking funds in the previous subsection, complete for purposes of valuation, we take specification of cash flows to all tranches requires only that we define for the senior sinking fund and Y1(K) = Y2(K) = 0, (21a) for the mezzanine sinking fund, respectively, the D1(K) = min[F1(K) + U1(K), R(K)], (21b) actual interest payments, Y (k) and Y (k); any pay- 1 2 and ments of principal, D1(k) and D2(k); and any con- D (K) = min[F (K) + U (K), R(K) – D (K)]. (21c) tractual reductions in principal, J1(k) and J2(k). 2 2 2 1 Under our uniform prioritization scheme, inter- The residual tranche finally collects est W(k) collected from the surviving participations D (K) = R(K) – Y (K) – D (K) – Y (K) – D (K). (21d) is allocated in priority order, with the senior 3 1 1 2 2 tranche getting Y1(k) = min[U1(k), W(k)] and the For the alternative fast-prioritization scheme, mezzanine getting Y2(k) = min[U2(k), W(k) – Y1(k)]. the senior tranche is allocated interest and principal

Table 3. Conditional Probabilities of Default and Diversity Scores ρ = 0.1 ρ = 0.5 ρ = 0.9 Diversity Diversity Diversity Set P(di) P(di|dj) Score P(di|dj) Score P(di|dj) Score 1 0.386 0.393 58.5 0.420 21.8 0.449 13.2 2 0.386 0.393 59.1 0.420 22.2 0.447 13.5 3 0.386 0.392 63.3 0.414 25.2 0.437 15.8 4 0.386 0.393 56.7 0.423 20.5 0.454 12.4

January/February 2001 49 Financial Analysts Journal payments as quickly as possible until maturity or ability that more than one default will occur during until its principal remaining is reduced to zero, one time step is very small; hence, we ignore it. whichever is first. Until the senior tranche is paid Based on experimentation, we chose to simu- in full, the mezzanine tranche accrues unpaid inter- late 10,000 pseudo-independent scenarios.16 est at its coupon rate. Then, the mezzanine tranche is paid interest and principal as quickly as possible Results for Par CDO Spreads. The esti- until maturity or until the mezzanine tranche is mated par spreads of the senior (s1) and mezzanine retired. Finally, any remaining cash flows are allo- (s2) CDO tranches for the four-parameter sets are cated to the residual tranche. Specifically, in cou- shown in Table 4 for various levels of overcollater- pon period k, the senior tranche is allocated the alization and for the two prioritization schemes. To interest payment, illustrate the accuracy of the simulation methodol- ogy, we show in parentheses estimates of the stan- Y (k) = min[U (k), Z(k)] (22a) 1 1 dard deviation of these estimated spreads resulting and the principal payment from “Monte Carlo noise.” Table 5 and Table 6 show estimated par spreads for the case of, respec- D1(k) = min[F1(k – 1), Z(k) – Y1(k)], (22b) tively, “low” (ρ = 0.1) and “high” (ρ = 0.9) default where the total cash generated by the collateral correlations. In all these examples, the risk-free rate pool, Z(k), is again defined by Equation 14. The is 0.06 and no management fees are considered. mezzanine receives the interest payments,

Y2(k) = min[U2(k), Z(k) – Y1(k) – D1(k) – Y2(k)] (23a) and principal payments Table 4. Par Spreads (ρ = 0.5) (estimated standard deviation in D2(k) = min[F2(k – 1), Z(k) – Y1(k) – D1(k) – Y2(k)]. (23b) parentheses) Finally, any residual cash flows are paid to the junior subordinated tranche. For this scheme, no Uniform Scheme Fast Scheme contractual reductions in principal occur [that is, Set s1 s2 s1 s2 J (k) = 0]. i Principal: P1 = 92.5; P2 = 5 In practice, many other types of prioritization 1 18.7 bps 636 bps 13.5 bps 292 bps schemes are possible. For example, during the life (1) (16) (0.4) (1.6) of a CDO, failure to meet certain contractual over- 2 17.9 589 13.5 270 collateralization ratios in many cases triggers a shift (1) (15) (0.5) (1.6) to some version of fast prioritization. For our exam- 3 15.3 574 11.2 220 ples, the CDO yield spreads for uniform and fast (1) (14) (0.5) (1.5) prioritization would provide upper and lower 4 19.1 681 12.7 329 bounds, respectively, on the senior spreads that (1) (17) (0.4) (1.6) would apply if one were to add such a feature to the uniform prioritization scheme that we illustrated. Principal: P1 = 80; P2 = 10 1 1.64 bps 67.4 bps 0.92 bps 38.9 bps Simulation Methodology. Our computa- (0.1) (2.2) (0.1) (0.6) tional approach consists of simulating piecewise lin- 2 1.69 66.3 0.94 39.5 ear approximations of the paths of Xc and X1, . . ., XN (0.1) (2.2) (0.01) (0.6) for time intervals of some relatively small fixed- 3 2.08 51.6 1.70 32.4 ∆ ∆ length t. (We use a t interval of one week.) (0.2) (2.0) (0.2) (0.6) Defaults during one of these intervals are simulated 4 1.15 68.1 0.37 34.6 at the corresponding discretization of the total (0.1) (2.0) (0.2) (0.6) arrival intensity, Figure 5 and Figure 6 illustrate the impacts on Λ()t = ∑ λ()t 1 , (24) i i Ait(), the market values of the three tranches of a given CDO structure of changing the correlation param- ρ where the variable 1A(i,t) equals 1 if issuer i has not eter (with uniform prioritization). The base-case defaulted by t and equals 0 otherwise. (That is, only CDO structures used for this illustration were the intensities of the participations still alive are determined by uniform prioritization of senior and summed.) When a default arrives, the identity of the mezzanine tranches whose coupon rates are at par defaulter is drawn at random, with the probability for the base-case Parameter Set 1 and with the that i is selected as the defaulter given by the discret- correlation parameter ρ = 0.5. For example, suppose λ Λ ization approximation of i(t)1A(i,t)/ (t). The prob- this correlation parameter is moved from the base

50 ©2001, Association for Investment Management and Research¨ Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations

Table 5. Par Spreads (ρ = 0.1) Figure 5. Impact on Tranche Value of Correla- tion: High Overcollateralization Uniform Scheme Fast Scheme (P1 = 80) Set s1 s2 s1 s2 Principal: P = 92.5; P = 5 Premium 1 2 (percentage of face value) 1 6.7 bps 487 bps 2.7 bps 122.bps 0.5 2 6.7 492 2.9 117 3 6.3 473 2.5 102 4 7.0 507 2.7 137

Principal: P1 = 80; P2 = 10 1 0.27 bps 17.6 bps 0.13 bps 7.28 bps 0 2 0.31 17.5 0.15 7.92 3 0.45 14.9 0.40 6.89 4 0.16 19.0 0.05 6.69

Table 6. Par Spreads (ρ = 0.9) –0.5 ρ = 0.1 ρ = 0.5 ρ = 0.9 Uniform Scheme Fast Scheme Initial Correlation Set s1 s2 s1 s2 Senior Mezzanine Junior Principal: P1 = 92.5; P2 = 5 1 30.7 bps 778 bps 23.9 bps 420.bps Note: Uniform prioritization. The premium is the market value 2 29.5 687 23.7 397 net of par. 3 25.3 684 20.6 325 4 32.1 896 23.1 479 Figure 6. Impact on Tranche Value of Correla- tion: Low Overcollateralization Principal: P1 = 80; P2 = 10 (P1 = 92.5) 1 3.17 bps 113.bps 1.87 bps 68.8 bps Premium 2 3.28 112 1.95 70.0 (percentage of face value) 3 4.03 90 3.27 60.4 0.8 4 2.52 117 1.06 65.4 0.6 case of 0.5 to 0.9. Figure 6, which treats the case of 0.4 relatively little subordination available to the 0.2 senior tranche (P1 = 92.5), shows that the loss in diversification reduces the market value of the 0 senior tranche from 92.5 to about 91.9. The market value of the residual tranche, which benefits from –0.2 volatility in the manner of a , increases –0.4 from 2.5 to approximately 3.2, a dramatic relative change. Although a precise statement of convexity –0.6 is complicated by the timing of the prioritization –0.8 effects, the effect illustrated by Figures 5 and 6 is ρ = 0.1 ρ = 0.5 ρ = 0.9 along the lines of Jensen’s inequality; an increase in Initial Correlation correlation also increases the (risk-neutral) vari- ance of the total loss of principal. These opposing Senior Mezzanine Junior reactions to diversification of the senior and junior Note: Uniform prioritization. The premium is the market value tranches also show that the residual tranche may net of par. offer some benefits to certain investors as a volatil- ity hedge against default risk for the senior tranche. The mezzanine tranche absorbs the net effect of the impacts of correlation changes on the market the collateral portfolio is not affected by the corre- values of the senior and junior residual tranches (in lation of default risk. These effects can be compared this example, the result is a decline in market value with the impact of correlation on the par spreads of of the mezzanine from 5.0 to approximately 4.9), the senior and mezzanine tranches that are shown which it must do because the total market value of in Tables 4, 5, and 6. Clearly, given the relatively

January/February 2001 51 Financial Analysts Journal small size of the mezzanine principal, the mezza- Figure 7. Risky Reinvestment: Senior Tranche nine par spreads can be dramatically influenced by Spreads correlation. Moreover, experimenting with various Spread (bps) mezzanine overcollateralization values shows that 30 the effect is ambiguous: Increasing default correla- tion may raise or lower mezzanine spreads. 25 Prioritization Scheme. For our example, ensuring faster payments to the senior and then to 20 the mezzanine tranches makes these tranches safer; that is, their par coupon spreads are smaller when 15 the fast prioritization scheme is adopted. For the senior tranche, this statement holds for two rea- sons: This tranche no contractual loss of prin- 10 cipal (and hence no contractual loss of future interest) and it loses no interest payments to the 5 mezzanine tranche. For the mezzanine tranche, the statement holds in our example because the effect 0 of experiencing no contractual principal losses is 123 4 stronger than that of postponing the interest pay- Parameter Set ments, which carries the risk of not receiving them in full. Tables 4–6 provide the computed spreads. Safe Reinvestment Risky Reinvestment

Risky Reinvestment. This method can also Figure 8. Risky Reinvestment: Mezzanine be used to allow for collateral assets that mature Tranche Spreads before the termination of the CDO. The default intensity of each new collateral asset is of the type Spread (bps) given by Equation 5, where Xi is initialized at the 700 time of the purchase at the initial base-case level λ 600 (long-run mean of i). Figure 7 and Figure 8 show the effect of changing from safe to risky reinvest- 500 ment (with uniform prioritization). Given the 400 “short-option” aspect of the senior tranche, it becomes less valuable when reinvestment becomes 300 risky. Note that the mezzanine tranche benefits 200 from the increased variance in this case. 100

Analytical Results 0 In this section, exploiting the symmetry assump- 1234 tions of our special example, we provide analytical Parameter Set results for the probability distribution for the num- ber of defaulting participations and the total of Safe Reinvestment Risky Reinvestment default losses of principal, including the effects of random recovery. ance under permutation) in the unconditional joint The key to calculating these probability distri- distribution of default times, butions exactly is the ability to explicitly compute the probability of survival of all participations in any PM()= k = chosen subgroup of obligors. These explicit proba- N ()∩∩∩c ∩∩c (25) Pd … dk d k + 1 … d N , bilities must be evaluated with extremely high k 1 numerical accuracy, however, because of the numer- ous combinations of subgroups to be considered. where For a given time horizon T, let dj denote the N N! = ------event that obligor j defaults by T. That is, dj = k ()NkÐ !k! . (26) τ c { j < T}. Also, let dj denote the event complemen- c τ ∩ ∩ ∩ c ∩ ∩ c tary to dj, namely, dj = { j > T}. Let M denote the We let q(k, N) = P(d1 . . . dk d k+1 . . . dN ). ∪ ∪ number of defaults. Assuming symmetry (invari- The probability pj = P(d1 . . . dj) that at least one

52 ©2001, Association for Investment Management and Research¨ Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations of the first j names will default by T is computed Equations A2 and A3 for the case in which n = –κ, σ2 κθ α β later; for now, we take this calculation as given. p = , q = –j, l = lc, and m = c; i(T) and i(T) are Proposition 2: We have17 the explicitly given solutions of Equations A2 and κ σ2 A3 for the case in which n = – , p = , q = –1, l = li, N κθ ()jkN++ +1 k and m = i. qkN(), = ∑ ()Ð1 p . (27) j It is not hard to see how to generalize Proposi- j = 1 NjÐ tion 2 so as to accommodate more than one type of A proof, found in the Duffie and Gârleanu 1999 intensity—that is, how to treat a case with several working paper, is based on a careful counting of the internally symmetric pools. Introducing each such number of scenarios in which k participations group increases by one the dimensions of the array default. Using the fact that the pre-intensity of the p, however, and the summation. Thus, given the τ(j) τ τ first-to-arrive = min( 1, . . ., j) of the stopping relatively lengthy computation required to obtain τ τ λ λ times 1, . . ., j is 1 + . . . + j and using the adequate accuracy for even two subgroups of issu- independence of X1, . . ., XN and Xc, we have ers, one might prefer simulation to this analytical approach for multiple types of issuers. []τ()j > Based on this analytical method, Figure 9 pj = 1 Ð P T shows the probability q(k, 100) of k defaults within j 10 years out of the original group of 100 issuers for = 1 Ð Eexp Ð T ∑ λ ()t dt (28) ∫0 i i = 1 Parameter Set 1 for a correlation-determining parameter ρ that is high (0.9) or low (0.1). Figure 10 α ()T +++ β()T X ()0 jα ()T jβ ()T X ()0 = 1 Ð e c c c i i i , shows the associated cumulative probability func- tions, including the base case of ρ = 0.5. For exam- α β where c(T) and c(T) are given explicitly in Appen- ple, from Figure 9, the likelihood of at least 60 dix A as the solutions of the ordinary differential defaults out of the original 100 participations in 10

Figure 9. Probability of k Defaults for High and Low Correlation

Probability of k Defaults 0.08

0.07

0.06

ρ = 0.1 0.05

0.04

0.03

0.02 ρ = 0.9

0.01

0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

Number of Defaults, k

January/February 2001 53 Financial Analysts Journal

Figure 10. Cumulative Probability of Number of Defaults: High, Low, and Base-Case Correlation

Probability of k or Fewer Defaults 1.0

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

Number of Defaults, k

ρ = 0.9 ρ = 0.5 ρ = 0.1 years is on the order of 1 percent for the low- bution rather than through a much more arduous correlation case, whereas it is roughly 12 percent simulation of the pre-intensity processes. The algo- for the high-correlation case. One can use this rithm is roughly as follows: method to compare the probability q(k, 100) of k • Simulate n draws from the explicit distribution defaults across all four parameter sets.18 of the default time of a participation in the One can also compute analytically the likeli- comparison portfolio. Record those default hood of a total loss of principal of a given amount times that are before T—say, M in number— x.19 The approach is to add up, over k, the proba- and ignore the others. bilities q(k, 100) of k defaults multiplied by the prob- • Simulate M fractional losses of principal. abilities that the total loss of principal from k • Allocate cash flows to the CDO tranches, defaults is at least x.20 A sample of the resulting loss period by period, according to the desired pri- distributions is illustrated in Figure 11. oritization scheme. One can also analytically compute the variance • Discount the cash flows of each CDO tranche to a present value at risk-free rates. of total loss of principal, from which come diversity • For each tranche, average the discounted cash scores, as tabulated for our example in Table 3. A flows over independently generated scenarios. description of the computation of diversity scores A comparison of the resulting approximation for a general pool of collateral, not necessarily with of CDO spreads with those computed earlier is symmetric default risk, is in Appendix B. Given a provided for certain cases in Figures 12–14. For (risk-neutral) diversity score of n, one can estimate well-collateralized tranches, the diversity-based CDO yield spreads by a much simpler algorithm, estimates of spreads are reasonably accurate (as which approximates by substituting the compari- shown in Figures 12 and 14), at least relative to the son portfolio of n independently defaulting partic- uncertainty that one would in any case have ipations for the actual collateral portfolio. regarding the actual degree of diversification in the The default times can be independently simu- collateral pool. For highly subordinated tranches lated directly from an explicit unconditional distri- and with moderate or large default correlations, the

54 ©2001, Association for Investment Management and Research¨ Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations

Figure 11. Probability Density of Total Losses of Principal through Default: High Correlation

Probability Density 0.07

0.06

0.05

0.04

0.03

0.02

0.01

0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60

Total Losses (percentage of face value)

Set 1 Set 3 Set 2 Set 4

Figure 12. Spread Comparisons for Senior Figure 13. Spread Comparisons for Mezzanine Tranches: High Correlation (ρ = 0.9), Tranches: Moderate Correlation ρ Low Subordination (P1 = 92.5) ( = 0.5), Low Subordination (P1 = 92.5, P2 = 5) Spread (bps) 40 Spread (bps) 1,200

30 1,000

800

20 600

400 10 200

0 0 1 234 1 234

Parameter Set Parameter Set

Full-Simulation Spread Diversity-Score Spread Full-Simulation Spread Diversity-Score Spread

January/February 2001 55 Financial Analysts Journal diversity-based spreads can be rather inaccurate, as Figure 14. Spread Comparisons for Mezzanine can be seen in Figure 13. Tranches: Moderate Correlation Another source of approximation error from (ρ = 0.5), High Subordination diversity-score-based calculations is concentration (P1 = 80, P2 = 10) risk in the original portfolio. Suppose, for example, Spread (bps) that the notional amount of one obligor is a large fraction of the total notional amount of the collat- 80 eral pool. The hypothetical comparison portfolio, with equal notional amounts to each obligor, may have tail risk of default losses that is markedly 60 smaller than the tail risk of the actual portfolio, despite having the same mean and variance of default losses. One might allow for concentration 40 risk by construction of a comparison portfolio with similar concentration but still assuming no correla- tion of default losses. 20 Figure 15 shows the likelihood of a total loss of principal of at least 24.3 percent of the original face ρ 0 value as the correlation-determining parameter is 1 234 varied. The figure also illustrates the calculation of the probability of failing to meet an overcollateral- Parameter Set ization target. Full-Simulation Spread Diversity-Score Spread

Conclusions Figure 15. Likelihood of Total Default Losses of Default-time correlation has a significant impact on at Least 24.3 Percent of Principal the market values of individual tranches. The pri- within 10 Years ority of the senior tranche, by which it is effectively Probability “short a call option” on the performance of the underlying collateral pool, causes its market value 0.28 to decrease with the risk-neutral default-time cor- relation, fixing the (risk-neutral) distribution of 0.24 individual default times. The value of the equity piece, which resembles a call option, increases with correlation. Intermediate tranches exhibit no clear 0.20 Jensen effect. With sufficient overcollateralization, the option “written” (to the lower tranches) domi- 0.16 nates, but it is the other way around for sufficiently low levels of overcollateralization. Spreads, at least for mezzanine and senior 0.12 tranches, are not especially sensitive to the “lump- iness” in the arrival of information about credit 0.08 quality, in that replacing the contribution of diffu- 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 sion with jump risks (of various types), while hold- Initial Correlation ing constant the degree of mean reversion and the term structure of credit spreads, plays a relatively small role in the determination of spreads. Regarding alternative computational meth- This work was supported in part by a grant from the ods, if (risk-neutral) diversity scores can be evalu- Gifford Fong Associates Fund at the Graduate School of ated accurately, which is computationally simple Business, Stanford University. We are grateful for dis- in the framework we proposed, these scores can be cussions with Ken Singleton of Stanford University, used to obtain good approximate market valua- Reza Bahar of Standard and Poor’s, and Sergio Kostek tions for reasonably well-collateralized tranches. of Morgan Stanley Dean Witter. Helpful comments and Currently, the weakest link in the chain of research assistance were provided by Jun Pan. We are CDO analysis is the availability of empirical data also grateful for several helpful suggestions for improve- that would bear on the correlation, actual or risk ment by Kazuhisa Uehara of the Fuji Research Institute neutral, of default. Corporation.

56 ©2001, Association for Investment Management and Research¨ Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations

Appendix A. Solution for the d Ð µa = ------1 1 d2 c Basic Affine Model 1 For the basic affine model, the expectation With these explicit solutions, we can compute the characteristic function ϕ(•) of λ(s) given λ(0), vu+ λ()s α()s + β()s Eexp[]∫s qλ()t dt e = e (A1) defined by 0 izλ()s ϕ()z = Ee[] α β (A6) is given by coefficient functions (s) and (s) solv- α()s + β()λs ()s ing the following differential equations: = e , µβ by taking q to equal zero and u to equal iz and α′ = mβ + l ------s - (A2) treating the coefficients α(s) and β(s) as complex. s s 1 Ð µβ s The Laplace transform L(•) of λ(s) is computed and analogously:

2 Ðzλ()s β′ = nβ ++--1 pβ q , (A3) Lz()= Ee[] s s 2 s (A7) α()s + β()λs ()s = e . with the general boundary conditions α(0) = v and β(0) = u. The survival probability (Equation 4) is In this case, we take u = –z. For details and exten- obtained as a special case, with u = v = 0, n = –κ, sions to a general affine jump diffusion setting, see p = σ2, q = –1, and m = κθ. Barring degenerate cases, Duffie, Pan, and Singleton (2000). which may require separate treatment, the solutions are given by Appendix B. Computation of b1s ma()c Ð d c + d e m Diversity Scores α = v + ------1 1 1- log------1 1 + ----- s s b c d c + d c 1 1 1 1 1 1 We define diversity score S associated with a “tar- (A4) b2s get” portfolio of bonds of total principal F to be the l ()a c Ð d c + d e  + ------2 2 2 log------2 2 + ----l- Ð l s number of identically and independently default- b c d c d c 2 2 2 2 2 2 ing bonds, each with principal F/S, whose total and default losses have the same variance as the target portfolio’s default losses. The computation of S entails computation of the variance of losses on the b s 1 + a e 1 target portfolio of N bonds, which we address in β = 1 s ------b s , (A5) this appendix. c + d e 1 1 1 For simplicity, we ignore any interest rate where effects on losses in the calculation of diversity, although such effects could be tractably incorpo- a1 = (d1 + c1)u–1 rated—by the discounting of losses, for example. d ()n + qc + a ()nc + p 1 2 1 1 1 (With correlation between interest rates and b1 = ------a1c1 Ð d1 default losses, the meaningfulness of direct dis- counting is questionable.) Also, we do not sepa- 2 – nn+ Ð 2pq c = ------rately consider lost-coupon effects in diversity 1 2q scores. These effects, which could be particularly important for high-premium bonds, can be cap- ()2 ()2 ()npu++ npu+ Ð ppu ++2nu 2q d1 = 1 Ð c1u ------2 - tured along the lines of the following calculations. 2nu++ pu 2q Finally, diversity scores do not account directly for the replacement of defaulted collateral or new d1 a2 = ----- investment in defaultable securities during the life c1 of a product, except insofar as covenants or ratings b2 = b1 requirements stipulate a minimum diversity score u that is to be maintained for the current collateral c2 = 1 Ð ----- c1 portfolio for the life of the CDO structure. Letting di denote the indicator of the event that participation i defaults by a given time T and letting Li denote the random loss of principal when this event occurs, the variance of total default losses is

January/February 2001 57 Financial Analysts Journal

To end the computation, one uses the identities

N N 2 N 2 p(1) = p1 and p(2) = 2p1 – p2, where p1 and p2 are var∑ L d = EL∑ d Ð EL∑ d computed according to Equation 28 in the text, and i i i i i i i = 1 i = 1 i = 1 2 2 the fact that E(Li ) = 1/3 and [E(Li)] = 1/4 if we N assume losses are uniformly distributed on (0,1). 2 2 = ∑ E(Li ) E(di ) (Other assumptions about the distribution of Li, i=1 (B1) even allowing for correlation here, can be accom- + ∑ EL()L Ed()d modated.) i j i j λ i≠1 More generally, suppose i(t) = bi[X(t)] and λ N j(t) = bj[X(t)], where X is a multivariate affine []()2[]()2 Ð ∑ ELi Edi . process of the general type considered in Appendix i=1 A and bi and bj are coefficient vectors. Even in the absence of symmetry, for any times t(i) and t(j), ≤ Given an affine intensity model, one can com- assuming without loss of generality that t(i) t(j), pute all terms in Equation B1. In the symmetric the probability of default by i before t(i) and of j before t(j) is case, letting p(1) denote the marginal probability of default of a bond and p(2) denote the joint probabil- () ity of default of any two bonds, Equation B1 ti λ () Ð∫ i u du reduces to () 0 Edidj = 1 Ð Ee

N tj() 2 Ð λ () var∑ L d = Np EL() ∫ j u du i i ()1 i 0 (B5) i=1 ÐEe 2 (B2) + NN()Ð 1 p()[]EL() 2 i tj() Ð bt()Xt()du ∫0 2 2 []()2 + Ee , Ð N p()1 ELi .

Equating the variance of the original pool to that of the comparison pool yields where b(t) = bi + bj for t < t(i) and b(t) = bj for t(i) ≤ t ≤ t(j). Each of the terms in Equation B5 is analytically explicit in an affine setting, as can be  gathered from Appendix A. N2 2 2 2 ----() []() p()1 ELi Ð p()1 ELi = p()1 E(Li ) Beginning with Equation B5, the covariance of S  (B3)  default losses between any pair of participations ()[]()2 + N Ð 1 p()2 ELi during any pair of respective time windows may be calculated, and from that result, the total vari- ÐNp 2 []EL()2 . ()1 i ance of default losses on a portfolio and, finally, Solving Equation B3 for the diversity score, S, one diversity score S can be calculated. With lack of gets symmetry, however, one must take a stand on the definition of “average” default risk to be applied to 2 2 2 Np()EL()Ð p()[]EL() each of the S independently defaulting issues of the 1 1 1 i S = ------. (B4) comparison portfolio. We do not address that issue ()2 ()[]()2 2 []()2 p()1 E L1 + N Ð 1 p()2 ELi Ð Np()1 ELi here. A pragmatic decision could be based on fur- ther investigation, perhaps accompanied by addi- tional empirical work.

Notes

1. A synthetic CLO differs from a conventional CLO in that Unfortunately, regulations do not always provide the same for a synthetic CLO, the bank originating the loans does not capital relief for a synthetic CLO as for a standard balance actually transfer ownership of the loans to the SPV but, sheet CLO (see Punjabi and Tierney 1999). instead, uses credit derivatives to transfer the default risk 2. This issue is related to the effects of adverse selection, but to the SPV. A synthetic CLO may be preferred when the it also depends on the total size of the issue. direct sale of loans to SPVs might compromise client rela- 3. Supporting technical details are provided in the Duffie and tionships or secrecy or would be costly because of contrac- Gârleanu 1999 working paper. tual restrictions on transferring the underlying loans.

58 ©2001, Association for Investment Management and Research¨ Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations

4. An alternative would be a model in which simultaneous 13. Because all parameter sets have the same κ parameter, defaults could be caused by certain common credit events. maintaining the same term structure of zero-coupon yields An example is a multivariate exponential model (see Duffie was a rather straightforward numerical , with and Singleton 1998). Another alternative is a contagion Equation 4 used for risk-neutral default probabilities. model, such as the static “infectious default” model of 14. This calculation is based on the analytical methods Davis and Lo (1999). described in the next section, “Analytical Results.” 5. An affine interest-rate process is one in which zero-coupon 15. As a practical matter, if the investors’ losses from default in yields are linear with respect to underlying state variables. the underlying collateral pool are sufficiently severe, For a more precise definition, see Duffie and Kan (1996). Moody’s may assign a “default” to a CDO tranche even if 6. A technical condition that is sufficient for the existence of a it meets its contractual payments. strictly positive solution to Equation 3 is that κθ ≥ σ2/2. We 16. The basis for this approach and other multi-obligor default- do not require it because none of our results depends on time simulation approaches is discussed in Duffie and Sin- gleton (1998). strict positivity. m 17. We use the convention that = 0 if l < 0 or m < l . 7. A proof can be found in the Duffie and Gârleanu 1999 l working paper. The method of the proof is to verify that the 18. We have not included the graphs in this article, but we note Laplace transform of Xt + Yt is that of an affine process with that low-correlation distributions are rather more similar κ θ σ µ initial condition X0 + Y0 and parameters ( , , , , l ). across the various parameter sets than are high-correlation 8. Our model is “doubly stochastic,” in the sense that, condi- distributions. The full set of graphs is in the Duffie and λ λ τ tional on the processes 1, . . ., N, the default times 1, . . ., Gârleanu 1999 working paper. τ n are independent and are the first jump times of counting 19. We are referring to the risk-neutral likelihood, unless the processes with these respective intensities. Thus, the only model under the objective probability is used. source of default time correlation in our model is through 20. For computation, we did not use the actual distribution of correlation in the intensity processes. the total fractional loss of principal of a given number k of 9. A modeling alternative allowing for the treatment of corre- defaulting participations. For ease of computation, we sub- lated interest rate risk, and technical details, is in the 1999 stituted with a central limit (normal) approximation for the Duffie and Gârleanu working paper. distribution of the sum of k identically and independently distributed uniform (0, 1) random variables, which is 10. This pricing approach was developed by Lando (1998) for merely the distribution of a normally distributed variable slightly different default intensity models. Lando also with the same mean and variance. We were interested in allowed for correlation between interest rates and default this calculation for moderate to large levels of x, corre- intensity. sponding to, for example, estimating the probability of 11. Moody’s would not rely exclusively on the diversity score failure to meet an overcollateralization target. We have in rating CDO tranches. verified that, even for relatively few defaults, the central 12. That is, B(k) is the subset of A(k – 1) that is not in A(k). limit approximation is adequate for our purposes.

References

Akerlof, G. 1970. “The Market for ‘Lemons’: Qualitative ———. 1999. “Modeling Term Structures of Defaultable Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” Quarterly Journal of Bonds.” Review of Financial Studies, vol. 12, no. 4 (Special):687– Economics, vol. 84, no. 3:488–500. 720. Cox, J.C., J. Ingersoll, and S. Ross. 1985. “A Theory of the Term Duffie, D., J. Pan, and K. Singleton. 2000. “Transform Analysis Structure of Interest Rates.” Econometrica, vol. 53, no. 2 and for Affine Jump Diffusions.” Econometrica, vol. (March):385–407. 68, no. 6 (November): 1343–76. Davis, M., and V. Lo. 1999. “Infectious Default.” Working paper, Feller, W. 1951. “Two Singular Diffusion Problems.” Annals of Research and Product Development, Tokyo-Mitsubishi Mathematics, vol. 54, no. 1:173–182. International PLC. DeMarzo, P. 1999. “Asset Sales and Security Design with Private Innes, R. 1990. “Limited Liability and Incentive Contracting Information.” Working paper, Haas School of Business, with Ex-Ante Choices.” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 52, no. University of California at Berkeley. 1:45–67. DeMarzo, P., and D. Duffie. 1999. “A Liquidity-Based Model of Lando, D. 1998. “On Cox Processes and Credit-Risky Security Design.” Econometrica, vol. 67, no. 1:65–99. Securities.” Review of Derivatives Research, vol. 2, nos. 2–3:99–120. Duffie, D., and N. Gârleanu. 1999. “Risk and Valuation of Punjabi, S., and J. Tierney. 1999. “Synthetic CLOs and Their Role Collateralized Debt Obligations, Unabridged Version.” in Bank Balance Sheet Management.” Working paper, Fixed Working paper, Graduate School of Business, Stanford Income Research, Deutsche Bank. University (www.Stanford.edu/~duffie/working.htm). Schorin, C., and S. Weinreich. 1998. “Collateralized Debt Duffie, D., and R. Kan. 1996. “A Yield Factor Model of Interest Obligation Handbook.” Working paper, Rates.” , vol. 6, no. 4 (October):379–406. Research, Morgan Stanley Dean Witter. Duffie, D., and K. Singleton. 1998. “Simulating Correlated Defaults.” Working paper, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.

January/February 2001 59