1907 Lessons Learned

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

1907 Lessons Learned The Panic of Lessons Learned from the Market’s Perfect Storm 1907 By Robert F. Bruner and Sean D. Carr To understand fully the crash and had disturbed the equilibrium of the panici of 1907, one must consider its nation’s fragile financial system. As context: it was a time somewhat like Mark Twain supposedly said, “His- the present. A Republican moralist tory may not repeat itself, but it occa- was in the White House. War was sionally rhymes.” fresh in mind. Immigration was fuel- Exactly 100 years ago the United ing dramatic changes in society. New States was teetering on the edge of technologies were changing people’s economic collapse. Markets were in everyday lives. Business consolidators disarray, anxious depositors were and their Wall Street advisers were cre- forming long lines in front of banks, ating large, new combinations through and Wall Street investors were ner- mergers and acquisitions, while the vous and distressed. By November government was investigating and 1907 a major market crash had prosecuting prominent executives—led resulted in a 37 percent decline in by an aggressive young prosecutor from the value of all listed stocks, affect- New York. The public’s attitude toward ing nearly every industrial sector. business leaders, fueled by a muckrak- During the sharpest part of this ing press, was largely negative. The downturn, a banking panic led to government itself was becoming the failure of at least 25 banks and increasingly interventionist in society 17 trust companies.ii Money was and, in some ways, more intrusive in increasingly scarce, brokerages were individual life. Much of this was stim- forced to close, and the City of New ulated by a postwar economic expan- York was twice unable to find buy- sion that, with brief interruptions, had ers for its bonds, forcing the munic- lasted about 50 years, although in ipal government to the brink of recent months a major natural disaster bankruptcy. Financial History ~ Fall 200720 www.financialhistory.org Despite its severity, the 1907 crisis was mercifully short. Altogether it lasted 15 months, from the market’s peak in September 1906 to its trough in November 1907. From then until now, many observers have credited the relative brevity of this crisis to the actions of private bankers whose heroic interventions averted absolute catastrophe. In 1907, the United States lacked a central bank and the federal government possessed little A authority to address widespread eco- P g n i nomic distress. Moreover, at the very l r e t nadir of the crisis, the trust-busting S , s r U.S. President, Theodore Roosevelt, e h t o was literally hunting for bear in the r B n canebrakes of Louisiana. w o r Under these circumstances, as the B market crash and banking panic spun Lines in front of the Lincoln Trust Company during the Panic of 1907. wildly out of control, J. Pierpont Mor- gan, the colossus of American finance, information, and management theory. A ably asserted himself as the nation’s de pluralistic interpretation of the panic facto central banker. Using his personal and crash of 1907 that draws from these influence among other leading financiers, diverse intellectual perspectives suggests Morgan and a small circle of his peers that financial crises may result from a raised the funds necessary to relieve the powerful convergence of seven overlap- nation’s credit anorexia and support her ping and interrelated forces—a “perfect faltering financial institutions–all within storm”iii in the financial markets. the span of a few weeks. Reflecting on the 1907 crisis, then, let us The bold intervention of Morgan, consider the elements of the storm and however, does not tell the whole story. how they may gather force: A P The significance of Morgan’s leadership g System-like architecture. A financial n i l r e is undeniable, and his actions deserve system has two vitally important char- t S , s continued consideration as scholars acteristics that can serve as the foun- r e h t and practitioners draw innumerable dations for crises. First, various finan- o r lessons from his temerity, judgment, B cial institutions may be controlled by n w o and resolve. However, a thorough the same investors, and these interme- r understanding of America’s first finan- B diaries (banks, trust companies, bro- J.P. Morgan at the Pujo Hearings, 1912. cial crisis of the 20th century would be kerage firms) may be lenders and cred- incomplete were we only to study its itors to each other by virtue of the cash In 1907, the financial system in the remediation. Morgan’s dramatic reso- transfers they facilitate. The very exis- United States was highly fractional- lution of the 1907 crisis should not tence of such a network means that ized, localized, and complex. All told, blind us to the lessons that can be trouble can travel quickly, and the dif- the system held about 16,000 financial learned from a deeper examination of ficulties of one financial intermediary institutionsv (compared to about 7,500 its underlying causes. can spread to others. Second, the very in 2007), and the vast majority of them Over the years the causes of large and complexity of a financial system also were small “unit” banks having no systemic financial crises have been the means that it is difficult for all partici- branches. In 1907, the systemic nature focus of considerable research—both pants in the financial system to be of financial crises can be seen in the directly and through varied intellectual equally well informed — thus an chain of linkages as the panic spread, streams: macroeconomics, game theory, “information asymmetry” may moti- beginning on October 16, from one group psychology, financial economics, vate perverse behavior that can trigger institution to many others in New complexity theory, the economics of or worsen a financial crisis.iv York City and beyond (see Figure 1). www.financialhistory.org21 Financial History ~ Fall 2007 As for the effects of information Figure 1: Some Linkages Among Financial Institutions in 1907. asymmetry, one is struck by how lit- tle the average depositor in 1907 — Central Actors: NY Related: NY Unrelated: NY Unrelated: Distant L or even J. P. Morgan himself — could Failure of Otto Heinze & Co. L Mercantile Bank, Trust Company of L Correspondent banks and Gross & Kleeberg State Savings Bank of Butte America; and other Trust in the “interior”: money know about the condition of financial National Bank of North America; companies; New York centers and small local institutions. To resolve this asymme- New Amsterdam Bank; Mechanics Stock Exchange; Moore banks; foreign financial & Traders Bank; Knickerbocker Trust. & Schley. institutions. try, Morgan had privately chartered audits of the assets of various institu- tions and debtors. But he must have process of credit expansion and con- the risk of crisis. Like rapid growth known that the more serious asym- traction that significantly amplifies and inadequate safety buffers, the mis- metry lay not between him and the changes in markets and economic takes of leadership can help to foster institutions, but between the public growth. The boom part of the credit an environment vulnerable to shocks. and the institutions — therefore, Mor- cycle erodes the shock absorbers that In 1907, Theodore Roosevelt was on gan attempted to use the press, and cushion the financial system in the the warpath against anticompetitive even the pulpits, to shape public per- slump. Some banks, eager to make business practices. He wielded the ceptions about the safety and sound- profits, unwisely expand their lending power of the Department of Justice ness of the financial system. to less and less creditworthy clients as and the Sherman Antitrust Act, and he Buoyant growth. As lightning pre- the boom proceeds. Then some exter- used the bully pulpit to excoriate the cedes thunder, a volatile environment nal shock occurs and the bank direc- “malefactors of great wealth.” is a precursor to financial instability. tors awaken to the inadequacy of State governments followed suit Indeed, volatility in the form of buoy- their capitalization relative to the with new legislation to limit railroad ant economic growth may be espe- credit risks they have taken; banks rates; New York State employed a cially pernicious since it engenders reduce or cut off the new loans avail- young prosecutor, Charles Evans false optimism about the stability of able to their clients. This triggers a Hughes, to investigate the insurance markets and institutions. Every major liquidity crisis that drives both a stock industry. The Supreme Court financial panic has occurred after an market crash and a depositor panic. famously imposed a massive fine on episode of rapid economic growthvi The fragility of such a system stems Standard Oil for rate fixing. though not all panics are associated not only from the behavior of some Should Roosevelt and the Progres- with recessions.vii Of special interest is banks. It also grows from the struc- sives really be implicated in the crash? not the fact of growth, but rather the ture of the industry. A system with Financial markets withstand political cause of the inflection, the downturn many small and undiversified banks bluster fairly well — were Roosevelt’s from boom to slump. Rapid economic — such as existed in the United States speeches just empty rhetoric, we growth creates a demand for money in 1907 — is more prone to panics.x might absolve him. But markets are that eventually imposes liquidity In addition, the economists Ellis highly sensitive to changes in govern- strains on the financial system. Tallman and Jon Moen (1990) found ment policy (such as rate regulation, The crash and panic of 1907 punc- that the emergence of trust compa- taxation, and antitrust enforcement) tuated a period of very rapid eco- nies — a relatively new and lightly reg- that affect the underlying drivers of nomic growth in the United States.
Recommended publications
  • Front Matter
    1_McKnight_FM_McKnight.qxd 7/10/13 12:13 PM Page vii © University Press of Kansas. All rights reserved. Reproduction and distribution prohibited without permission of the Press. Contents Preface to the Paperback Edition ix Acknowledgments xvii Introduction 1 1 Assembling the “Official Truth” of Dallas 8 2 Creating the Warren Commission 30 3 Oswald in Mexico—Seven Days That Shook the Government 60 4 The Warren Commission Behind Closed Doors 89 5 The Warren Commission Confronts the Evidence 108 6 The Warren Commission’s “Smoking Guns” 128 7 The JFK Autopsy 153 8 Birth of the “Single-Bullet” Fabrication 181 9 Politics of the “Single-Bullet” Fabrication 213 10 FBI Blunders and Cover-Ups in the JFK Assassination 247 11 Senator Russell Dissents 282 12 Was Oswald a Government “Agent”? 298 13 JFK, Cuba, and the “Castro Problem” 330 Conclusion 354 Appendix A. FBI Damage Control Tickler 363 Appendix B. J. Lee Rankin’s Memorandum 366 Appendix C. A Brief Chronology and Summary of the Commission’s Case against Oswald 369 vii 1_McKnight_FM_McKnight.qxd 7/10/13 12:13 PM Page viii © University Press of Kansas. All rights reserved. viii ContentsReproduction and distribution prohibited without permission of the Press. Notes 373 Selected Bibliography 455 Index 463 A photograph section appears following page 236. 1_McKnight_FM_McKnight.qxd 7/10/13 12:13 PM Page ix © University Press of Kansas. All rights reserved. Reproduction and distribution prohibited without permission of the Press. Preface to the Paperback Edition Conspiracy is central to Breach of Trust—but it is not a conspiracy tale about who killed President Kennedy.
    [Show full text]
  • RIPON For(.JM COMMENTARY
    RIPON fOR(.JM COMMENTARY COMMENTARY The I rani:lII Crisis 2 Piercing the Myth of Soviel Superiority 4 Theodore Jacqucney 5 PR ES IDENTIAL SPOTLIGHT John Connally's Big Poli tical C:unble: A New U.S. Pol icy 6 for the Midd le East EDITORS NOTE 7 The The Palestinian Question and Iranian American Interests in the 8 Middle East Crisis A View From Amman 11 BOOK REVIEW Chea p Oil : How To Break 12 ew IIllernational events in the last three decades have OPEC seared the American psyche like the mass kidnapping Fof the American embassy staff by theocratic led mobs POLITICAL POTPOURRI 13 in Tehran. As we go 10 publication. this crisis remains 3t a fever pilch with the ultimate fate of the hostages still quite BUREAUCRACY uncerl3in. MARCHES ON 16 Yet not since the Japanese surpri se attack on Pearl ~la rbor has there been such a virtual unan imity of America n resolve to sta nd up 10 an adversary. Public reticence for direct U.S, intervention secrns linked almost exclusively to concern for KIPON fOK~M the safe return of the hostages. Should any harm befall Ihe hostages. the dovish position in Ame rican politics might be Ed itor: Arthul M. /l ill II to seizc Ayatollah Khomeini and his Revolutionary Council ElIccu\ivc Editor: Sleven D. ljl'cngood Art Director: Elizabeth Lee (The Graphic Tuna) for U.S. convened intern ational war crimes tribunals pur­ TilE RIPON FORUM (l5SN 0035-5526) is published month­ suant to the Nuremberg and Eichmann precedents. More in­ ly (except for the March/April and July/ August combined terventionist alternatives migh t range from U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • “To Establish a More Effective Supervision of Banking:” How the Birth of the Fed Altered Bank Supervision
    “To Establish a More Effective Supervision of Banking:” How the Birth of the Fed Altered Bank Supervision Abstract Although bank supervision under the National Banking System exercised a light hand and panics were frequent, the cost of bank failures was minimal. Double liability induced shareholders to carefully monitor bank managers and voluntarily liquidate banks early if they appeared to be in trouble. Inducing more disclosure, marking assets to market, and ensuring prompt closure of insolvent national banks, the Comptroller of the Currency reinforced market discipline. The arrival of the Federal Reserve weakened this regime. Monetary policy decisions conflicted with the goal of financial stability and created moral hazard. The appearance of the Fed as an additional supervisor led to more “competition in laxity” among regulators and “regulatory arbitrage” by banks. When the Great Depression hit, policy-induced deflation and asset price volatility were misdiagnosed as failures of competition and market valuation. In response, the New Deal shifted to a regime of discretion-based supervision with forbearance. 100th Anniversary of the Jekyll Island Conference Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Eugene N. White Rutgers University and NBER Department of Economics New Brunswick, NJ 08901 USA Phone: 732-932-7363 Fax: 732-932-7416 [email protected] October 2010 “An Act to provide for the establishment of Federal reserve banks, to furnish an elastic currency, to afford means of rediscounting commercial paper, to establish a more effective supervision of banking in the United States, and for other purposes.”—the title of the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 [emphasis added] While the formation and development of the Federal Reserve has been intensively studied, histories of the Fed, from Milton Friedman and Anna J.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case for a Limited Central Bank Yeareen
    The case for a Limited Central Bank Yun The Case for a Limited Central Bank Yeareen Yun [email protected] MOUNT HOLYOKE COLLEGE Volume 5, Number 1 Journal for Global Business and Community http://jgbc.fiu.edu Consortium for Undergraduate International Business Education The case for a Limited Central Bank Yun In his book, The Alchemists, Neil Irwin (2013) follows the history of the recent financial crisis of 2007, examining the difficult decisions made and the bold actions carried out by three central bankers: Ben Bernanke of the Federal Reserve, Mervyn King of the Bank of England, and Jean-Claude Trichet of the European Central Bank (ECB). Irwin not only justifies the unconventional methods such as quantitative easing, that was used by these three men, but applauds them, for “peace and prosperity… require people like Bernanke, King, and Trichet to safeguard them, often by doing things that are widely unpopular” (p.388). He accepts the expanding role of the central banks as a necessary measure given the changing times. He believes “central banks [should not] let precedent or politics stop them from doing what they need to do to keep their economies healthy” at all costs even, if it means bailing out investment banks, telling Parliament how to manage its books, and propping up financially troubled economies (p.390). Irwin believes we shouldn’t expect perfection, but rather progress, and trust intelligent men to handle economic crises and manage the economies in ways that they best see fit because they are so “technically complex that we can’t put them to a vote” (p.390).
    [Show full text]
  • Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Investment Shocks and Business Cycles Alejandro Justiniano Giorgio E. Primiceri Andrea Tambalotti Staff Report no. 322 March 2008 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. Investment Shocks and Business Cycles Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 322 March 2008 JEL classification: C11, E22, E30 Abstract Shocks to the marginal efficiency of investment are the most important drivers of business cycle fluctuations in U.S. output and hours. Moreover, like a textbook demand shock, these disturbances drive prices higher in expansions. We reach these conclusions by estimating a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model with several shocks and frictions. We also find that neutral technology shocks are not negligible, but their share in the variance of output is only around 25 percent and even lower for hours. Labor supply shocks explain a large fraction of the variation of hours at very low frequencies, but not over the business cycle. Finally, we show that imperfect competition and, to a lesser extent, technological frictions are the key to the transmission of investment shocks in the model. Key words: DSGE model, imperfect competition, endogenous markups, Bayesian methods Justiniano: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago (e-mail: [email protected]).
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 9 Quiz
    Name: ___________________________________ Date: ______________ 1. The diffusion of authority and power throughout several entities in the executive branch and the bureaucracy is called A) the split executive B) the bureaucratic institution C) the plural executive D) platform diffusion 2. A government organization that implements laws and provides services to individuals is the A) executive branch B) legislative branch C) judicial branch D) bureaucracy 3. What is the ratio of bureaucrats to Texans? A) 1 bureaucrat for every 1,500 Texas residents B) 1 bureaucrat for every 3,500 Texas residents C) 1 bureaucrat for every 4,000 Texas residents D) 1 bureaucrat for every 10,000 Texas residents 4. The execution by the bureaucracy of laws and decisions made by the legislative, executive, or judicial branch, is referred to as A) implementation B) diffusion C) execution of law D) rules 5. How does the size of the Texas bureaucracy compare to other states? A) smaller than most other states B) larger than most other states C) about the same D) Texas does not have a bureaucracy 6. Standards that are established for the function and management of industry, business, individuals, and other parts of government, are called A) regulations B) licensing C) business laws D) bureaucratic law 7. What is the authorization process that gives a company, an individual, or an organization permission to carry out a specific task? A) regulations B) licensing C) business laws D) bureaucratic law 8. The carrying out of rules by an agency or commission within the bureaucracy, is called A) implementation B) rule-making C) licensing D) enforcement 9.
    [Show full text]
  • A Crash Course on the Euro Crisis∗
    A crash course on the euro crisis∗ Markus K. Brunnermeier Ricardo Reis Princeton University LSE August 2019 Abstract The financial crises of the last twenty years brought new economic concepts into classroom discussions. This article introduces undergraduate students and teachers to seven of these models: (i) misallocation of capital inflows, (ii) modern and shadow banks, (iii) strategic complementarities and amplification, (iv) debt contracts and the distinction between solvency and liquidity, (v) the diabolic loop, (vi) regional flights to safety, and (vii) unconventional monetary policy. We apply each of them to provide a full account of the euro crisis of 2010-12. ∗Contact: [email protected] and [email protected]. We are grateful to Luis Garicano, Philip Lane, Sam Langfield, Marco Pagano, Tano Santos, David Thesmar, Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh, and Dimitri Vayanos for shaping our initial views on the crisis, to Kaman Lyu for excellent research assistance throughout, and to generations of students at Columbia, the LSE, and Princeton to whom we taught this material over the years, and who gave us comments on different drafts of slides and text. 1 Contents 1 Introduction3 2 Capital inflows and their allocation4 2.1 A model of misallocation..............................5 2.2 The seeds of the Euro crisis: the investment boom in Portugal........8 3 Channels of funding and the role of (shadow) banks 10 3.1 Modern and shadow banks............................ 11 3.2 The buildup towards the crisis: Spanish credit boom and the Cajas..... 13 4 The financial crash and systemic risk 16 4.1 Strategic complementarities, amplification, multiplicity, and pecuniary ex- ternalities......................................
    [Show full text]
  • JP Morgan and the Money Trust
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS ECONOMIC EDUCATION The Panic of 1907: J.P. Morgan and the Money Trust Lesson Author Mary Fuchs Standards and Benchmarks (see page 47) Lesson Description The Panic of 1907 was a financial crisis set off by a series of bad banking decisions and a frenzy of withdrawals caused by public distrust of the banking system. J.P. Morgan, along with other wealthy Wall Street bankers, loaned their own funds to save the coun- try from a severe financial crisis. But what happens when a single man, or small group of men, have the power to control the finances of a country? In this lesson, students will learn about the Panic of 1907 and the measures Morgan used to finance and save the major banks and trust companies. Students will also practice close reading to analyze texts from the Pujo hearings, newspapers, and reactionary articles to develop an evidence- based argument about whether or not a money trust—a Morgan-led cartel—existed. Grade Level 10-12 Concepts Bank run Bank panic Cartel Central bank Liquidity Money trust Monopoly Sherman Antitrust Act Trust ©2015, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Permission is granted to reprint or photocopy this lesson in its entirety for educational purposes, provided the user credits the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, www.stlouisfed.org/education. 1 Lesson Plan The Panic of 1907: J.P. Morgan and the Money Trust Time Required 100-120 minutes Compelling Question What did J.P. Morgan have to do with the founding of the Federal Reserve? Objectives Students will • define bank run, bank panic, monopoly, central bank, cartel, and liquidity; • explain the Panic of 1907 and the events leading up to the panic; • analyze the Sherman Antitrust Act; • explain how monopolies worked in the early 20th-century banking industry; • develop an evidence-based argument about whether or not a money trust—a Morgan-led cartel—existed • explain how J.P.
    [Show full text]
  • Lloyd Bentsen Interview I
    LYNDON BAINES JOHNSON LIBRARY ORAL HISTORY COLLECTION The LBJ Library Oral History Collection is composed primarily of interviews conducted for the Library by the University of Texas Oral History Project and the LBJ Library Oral History Project. In addition, some interviews were done for the Library under the auspices of the National Archives and the White House during the Johnson administration. Some of the Library's many oral history transcripts are available on the INTERNET. Individuals whose interviews appear on the INTERNET may have other interviews available on paper at the LBJ Library. Transcripts of oral history interviews may be consulted at the Library or lending copies may be borrowed by writing to the Interlibrary Loan Archivist, LBJ Library, 2313 Red River Street, Austin, Texas, 78705. LLOYD BENTSEN ORAL HISTORY, INTERVIEW I PREFERRED CITATION For Internet Copy: Transcript, Lloyd Bentsen Oral History Interview I, 6/18/75, by Michael L. Gillette, Internet Copy, LBJ Library. For Electronic Copy on Diskette from the LBJ Library: Transcript, Lloyd Bentsen Oral History Interview I, 6/18/75, by Michael L. Gillette, Electronic Copy, LBJ Library. GENERAL SERVICES ADMINISTRATION NATIONAL ARCHIVES AND RECORDS SERVICE Gift of Personal Statement By LLOYD BENTSEN to the Lyndon Baines Johnson Library In accordance with Section 507 of the Federal Property and Administrative Services Act of 1949, as amended. (44 U.S.C. 397) and regulations issued thereunder (41 CFR 101-10), I, Lloyd Bentsen, hereinafter referred to as the donor, hereby give, donate, and convey to the United States of America for deposit in the Lyndon Baines Johnson Library, and for administration therein by the authorities thereof, a tape and a transcript of a personal statement approved by me and prepared for the purpose of deposit in the Lyndon Baines Johnson Library.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveries†
    Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveriesy Martin Beraja Christian K. Wolf MIT & NBER MIT & NBER September 17, 2021 Abstract: We argue that recoveries from demand-driven recessions with ex- penditure cuts concentrated in services or non-durables will tend to be weaker than recoveries from recessions more biased towards durables. Intuitively, the smaller the bias towards more durable goods, the less the recovery is buffeted by pent-up demand. We show that, in a standard multi-sector business-cycle model, this prediction holds if and only if, following an aggregate demand shock to all categories of spending (e.g., a monetary shock), expenditure on more durable goods reverts back faster. This testable condition receives ample support in U.S. data. We then use (i) a semi-structural shift-share and (ii) a structural model to quantify this effect of varying demand composition on recovery dynamics, and find it to be large. We also discuss implications for optimal stabilization policy. Keywords: durables, services, demand recessions, pent-up demand, shift-share design, recov- ery dynamics, COVID-19. JEL codes: E32, E52 yEmail: [email protected] and [email protected]. We received helpful comments from George-Marios Angeletos, Gadi Barlevy, Florin Bilbiie, Ricardo Caballero, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, Fran¸coisGourio, Basile Grassi, Erik Hurst, Greg Kaplan, Andrea Lanteri, Jennifer La'O, Alisdair McKay, Simon Mongey, Ernesto Pasten, Matt Rognlie, Alp Simsek, Ludwig Straub, Silvana Tenreyro, Nicholas Tra- chter, Gianluca Violante, Iv´anWerning, Johannes Wieland (our discussant), Tom Winberry, Nathan Zorzi and seminar participants at various venues, and we thank Isabel Di Tella for outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Interview Transcript
    Transcription: Richard Overton ________________________________________________________________ First of all good morning, and thank you for letting us be here today to interview you. It’s an honor for us and for our program. I want to start by letting folks listening or watching that today is Thursday, September 12th, 2013. My name is James Crabtree and you are Mr. Richard Overton, and we are at your home in Austin, Texas. So that way anybody listening to this knows when and where we did this interview. Sir, thank you again for letting us be here. The first question I always like to ask veterans is please tell us a little bit about your childhood and your life before you went into the military Richard Overton: Well, I’ll tell you I was out in the country then. Where were you born? Richard Overton: I was born out between Bastrop and Lockhart, at the same area Conn is. Did you grow up on a farm or did you grow up in town? Richard Overton: I started growing up in the country, and left there and went to Taylor. After that I went to Dallas. Did you come from a large family? Did you have a lot of siblings? Richard Overton: I had six sisters and four brothers. I was the fourth brother, and all dead except me. What was it like having that many siblings? Richard Overton: It was lovely, but I had to take care of ‘em. My daddy died way back in the 20s I think, somewhere back in there. But anyway, I had to take care of my mother and the other family.
    [Show full text]