Lecture 11 the GEI Model

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Lecture 11 the GEI Model Lecture 11 Market selection in general equilibrium models II: Example when markets are incomplete. The GEI model • General equilibrium and market selection when markets are incomplete • Example that irrational traders are not necessarily wiped out by the market in these models • Details on blackboard • Blume/Easley [5] If You're So Smart Why Aren't You Rich? NB: many(!) (annoying) typos in their example 1 Lecture 12+13 Noise traders and market selection. A detailed discussion References The early years (here we get historical): • De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann. “Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets,” Journal of Political Economy, 98, 703-738, 1990. • De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann. “The Survival of Noise Traders in Financial Markets,” Journal of Business, 64, 1-19, 1991. • Predecessors of agent-based models 2 MSH • Fama argued that irrational traders will be wiped out by market forces because they should lose money to the rational traders • Fisher Black (1986): excess returns comes from noise traders i.e. traders who trade on “information” that is, in fact, “noise” Model (OLG, investment decision only, 2 types) • 2 types: rational agents & noise traders • 2 assets: 1 risk-free ( supply), 1 risky (supply 1) both have same constant dividend r (genius at work!) • Agents maximize CARA utility fct [=>myopic mean-variance maximizers] • Rational = knowing true distribution of return • Noise traders = mis-perceive return (typically optimistic) • Additional volatility through noise traders = noise trader risk [in the paper’s parlance] • Noise traders take more risky positions for which they are compensated => Noise traders’ return can be higher! 3 Some more details • On blackboard Applications of this result (in the same paper): Volatility and Mean Reversion in Asset Prices Closed-end Mutual Funds Puzzle Equity Premium Puzzle Corporate Finance: Modigliani-Miller (the irrelevance theorem) Lecture 14 Complex adaptive systems: Trader types; Population and strategy choice dynamics; Price dynamics and stylized facts. 4 Main references • Cars Hommes. “Financial Markets as Nonlinear Adaptive Evolutionary Systems,” Quantitative Finance, 1, 149- 167, 2001. • Blake LeBaron. “A Builder's Guide to Agent-Based Financial Markets,” Quantitative Finance, 1, 254-261, 2001. • Both are survey-style papers with lots of references [the first is better IMHO]. • Thomas Lux. “Herd Behaviour, Bubbles and Crashes,” Economic Journal, 105, 881-896, 1995 • A lot of the work on this topic is computational Philosophy • View of financial markets as “evolutionary systems between different, competing trading strategies” (Cars Hommes) • Agents are boundedly rational: favor strategies that have done well in the past • In particular simple “technical” rules are permitted • Expectations or beliefs dynamics • Rational expectations eq. (REE) as benchmark • Heterogeneous population, difference of opinion, coexistence 5 Main ingredients • Rational traders: [why this term?] fundamentalists (smart money) • Noise traders: chartists, technical analysts (trend, pattern,…) • Belief dynamics (correlates with past performance) and/or trader type dynamics Adaptive belief systems • 1 riskless (infinite supply) & 1 risky asset (zero supply) • Myopic mean-variance maximizers with heterogeneous ‘beliefs’ about expected returns • Forecasting of tomorrow’s price [point estimate, e.g. trend (momentum, mean-reversion), fundamentalists (fund. value)] • Performance indicators: realized/risk-adjusted return • MAIN FOCUS: price dynamics and stylized facts • Minor role played by wealth dynamics (bankruptcy prevalent but not monitored) • Borrow a LOT form the noise trader approach discuss earlier 6 Adaptive belief systems: std model Dynamics between types • Performance of types induces flow between trader types (discrete-choice model with intensities) • Forecasting rules (for time lag =1) forecast * h h * h pt+1 − pt+1 = ft+1 = α ( pt − pt ) + β e.g. fundamentalist α = β = 0 trend follower α > 0, β = 0 biased belief α = 0, β ≠ 0 7 Dynamics of adaptive belief systems (Hommes, p.157+) Here forecasting depends on (discounted) past prices 8 Comparison with noise trader approach and criticism • Covers the standard noise trader model! • REE as benchmark [Is that reasonable?] • Restriction of trading strategy “universe”: too restrictive as lacks e.g. log-optimum investment 9 More comments • LeBaron’s “builder’s guide” survey • Market maker etc. • Price impact • Short-selling (“unrealistic” wealth dynamics) Contagion model for financial markets by Lux [only if time permits] Motivation • Self-organized process of ‘moods of the market’ • Optimism and pessimism as an infectious ‘disease’ [aka herd behavior] • Rooted in ‘psychologist’s attack’ on EMH 10 Model equations • 2N speculative traders • A trader is either optimist (n+) or pessimist (n-) n − n • Average opinion x = + − ∈[−1,+1] 2N • Change of mood probabilities p+− (x) [− → +], p−+ (x) [+ → −] • Change of average opinion dx = (1− x) p (x) + (1+ x) p (x) dt +− −+ Specification of functions p+− (x) = v exp(ax), p−+ (x) = vexp(−ax) • Resulting differential eq. for average opinion has the following fixed points (steady states) If a ≤ 1, x=0 (stable) If a > 1, x=0 (unstable) and two stable x- < 0, x+ 0 [ = - x-] > 0 • Graph on next slide 11 Graph Prices via demand and supply • Net excess demand of traders (each can trade tN units) DN = n+tN − n−tN = x(2NtN ) =: xTN • Only zero (i.e. market clears) if x=0! • Add additional actors(!): Fundamentalists DF = TF ( p f − p) • “Market-maker” induces price adjustment process (though not market clearing in any point in time) dp = β (D + D ) = β[xT +T ( p − p)] dt N F N F f 12 Final model • “Combining the contagion and price dynamics it seems reasonable to include a feedback effect from the price change on the disposition of speculators” (Lux, p.887) p+− (x) = vexp(a1(dp / dt) / v + a2 x), p−+ (x) = v exp(−a1(dp / dt) / v − a2 x) • Now we have a 2-dimensional system Graphs 13 Bear/Bull switching model • Add ‘basic mood’ of the market a0 p+− (x) = v exp(a0 + a1(dp / dt) / v + a2 x), p−+ (x) = vexp(−a0 − a1(dp / dt) / v − a2 x) da 0 =τ[(r +τ −1(dp / dt)) / p − r / p ] dt f • plus instantaneous market clearing dp = (T /T ) dx / dt dt N F 14 Lecture 15 An evolutionary stock market model I: Model. Model basics • I investors/strategies [‘fund’ remark] • K long-lived assets (stocks), each in supply 1 • Payoff is perishable consumption good [Lucas 1978] K A (s) > 0 Ak (s) ≥ 0, k=1 k • Strategies (simple) in simplex of dimension K-1 • Time is discrete • S states of nature (i.i.d. for simplicity) • Common savings rate [consumption rate 1- ] 15 Evolutionary Finance - understanding the dynamics of financial markets - K i i wt+1 = (Ak (st+1 ) + pt+1,k )θt,k k =1 i i I λt,k wt p = ρ λ j w j t+1,k j=1 t+1,k t+1 pt,k Similarities and differences to short-lived asset model • Investment strategy = budget shares • K+1 markets (K assets, 1 consumption good) • Short-term (temporary) equilibrium • Main innovation Resale value => capital gains • Asset market applications are now within reach • Role of consumption (not needed previously) 16 Solving the model On blackboard Steps • Account for consumption • Determine total wealth => relative wealth (wealth shares) • Dealing with the equilibrium problem => map with state [random dividend] • Verifying that everything is correct Lecture 16 An evolutionary stock market model II: Results. 17 Assumptions Stationarity relative dividends and strategies stationary Definition λ∗-market is evolutionary stable if • no strategy can gain against incumbent λ∗ • any µ ≠ λ∗ loses against some mutant strategy I = 2: Inverse matrix tractable! (Note: similar to Evol Game Th.) Local Stability - linearization and the variational equation - Growth rate at fixed point (1,0) » K 1 t+1 ÿ i (1− ρ) Rk (st+1 ) + ρ λk (s ) i t i rt+1 ≈ …ƒ 1 t λk (s )Ÿ rt k =1 λk (s ) ⁄ » K t+1 (1− ρ ) Rk (st+1 ) + ρ λk (s ) t g(µ,λ) = E ln…ƒ t µk (s ) k =1 λk (s ) Growth rate of investor )‘s share at investor *s prices 18 Question Is there a λ * ( s t ) such that for allµ ≠ λ* (1) g λ * ( µ ) < 0 and for some t ? (2) gµ (λ) > 0 λ(s ) » K t+1 (1− ρ ) Rk (st+1 ) + ρ λk (s ) t gλ (µ) = E ln…ƒ t µk (s ) k =1 λk (s ) Result (finitely many states) IID case * t * λk (s ) =λk = ERk Markov case 1− ρ ∞ [λ* (s)]s = ρ m[π m R] k k ƒ ρ m=1 19 0ketch of Proof: IID case 1/4 (1) Why is * stable? λk = ERk ~ 0 gλ* (µ) = — g(...) dP *))))))S Ν +)))))), » K * ρ λk + (1− ρ) Rk (s) 0 ƒπ s ln…ƒ * µk (s ) s∈S k=1 λk Sketch of Proof: IID case 2/4 » K ≈ ’ ÿ ∆ Rk (s) ÷ 0 = ƒπ s ln…ƒ ∆ ρ + (1− ρ) ÷ µk (s )Ÿ s∈S k =1 « ERk ◊ ⁄ 0 K (Strictly) concave inµ(s ) ∈∆ Maximum at µ ( s 0 ) = λ * , and value = 0 there 20 0ketch of Proof: IID case 3/4 (2) Why is µ ≠ λ * unstable? * ~ 0 gµ (λ ) = — g(...) dP *))))))+S Ν)))))), » K ρ µ (s0 , s) + (1− ρ) R (s) ƒπ ln…ƒ k k λ* s µ (s0 ) k &)s∈)S ))' k =)1 )))( k &))'))( K » 0 ÿ ≥ 0, and > 0 if (s0 ) ≠ * 0 * µk (s ) —...dP ≥ ρ Eƒλk ln… 0 Ÿ = 0 k=1 µk (s , s)⁄ 0ketch of Proof: IID case 4/4 » K 0 ÿ » K * * µk (s ) λk ρƒπ s ln…ƒ λk 0 Ÿ + (1− ρ)ƒπ s ln…ƒ Rk (s) 0 s∈S k=1 µk (s , s) ⁄ s∈S k=1 µk (s ) &))))'))))( &))'))( ≥ 0, and > 0 if (s0 ) ≠ * K » 0 ÿ 0 * µk (s ) —...dP ≥ ρ Eƒλk ln… 0 Ÿ = 0 k=1 µk (s , s)⁄ 21 Findings 8nly a λ *-market is evolutionary stable In this stationary market assets are priced at “fundamental values“ (relative dividends) Market selection favors value investors Only λ * strategy is growth-optimal @ own prices Kelly rule for assets instead of states Fundamental value without short sales Global selection results • Evstigneev/Hens/Schenk-Hoppé Working paper NCCR 09/2005 i.i.d.
Recommended publications
  • INSTITUTIONAL FINANCE Lecture 07: Liquidity, Limits to Arbitrage – Margins + Bubbles DEBRIEFING - MARGINS
    INSTITUTIONAL FINANCE Lecture 07: Liquidity, Limits to Arbitrage – Margins + Bubbles DEBRIEFING - MARGINS $ • No constraints Initial Margin (50%) Reg. T 50 % • Can’t add to your position; • Not received a margin call. Maintenance Margin (35%) NYSE/NASD 25% long 30% short • Fixed amount of time to get to a specified point above the maintenance level before your position is liquidated. • Failure to return to the initial margin requirements within the specified period of time results in forced liquidation. Minimum Margin (25%) • Position is always immediately liquidated MARGINS – VALUE AT RISK (VAR) Margins give incentive to hold well diversified portfolio How are margins set by brokers/exchanges? Value at Risk: Pr (-(pt+1 – pt)¸ m) = 1 % 1% Value at Risk LEVERAGE AND MARGINS j+ j Financing a long position of x t>0 shares at price p t=100: Borrow $90$ dollar per share; j+ Margin/haircut: m t=100-90=10 j+ Capital use: $10 x t j- Financing a short position of x t>0 shares: Borrow securities, and lend collateral of 110 dollar per share Short-sell securities at price of 100 j- Margin/haircut: m t=110-100=10 j- Capital use: $10 x t Positions frequently marked to market j j j payment of x t(p t-p t-1) plus interest margins potentially adjusted – more later on this Margins/haircuts must be financed with capital: j+ j+ j- j- j j+ j- j ( x t m t+ x t m t ) · Wt , where x =xt -xt 1 J with perfect cross-margining: Mt ( xt , …,xt ) · Wt 3.
    [Show full text]
  • Noise Traders - Detailed Derivation
    University of California, Berkeley Summer 2010 ECON 138 Noise Traders - Detailed Derivation A common response to the behavioral anomalies we have discussed in this course is that they have little impact on the long run, because investors with such anomalies are not maximizing optimally, and would thus be driven out of the market. We shall show, however, that noise traders—traders who are not maximizing—can indeed survive even in a very simple market setting. The model is taken out of De Long et al, "Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets," The Journal of Political Economy, Aug. 1990. I. Setting . Two-period model. Invest in the first period, consume in the second . CARA utility . One risk-free asset with return r and infinite supply . One risky asset with price and pays a dividend of r. Supply is fixed to 1. noise traders and rational traders, . Noise traders misperceive the expected price of the risky asset in the second period by II. Derivation 1. Utility Function We start off with CARA utility Where is the rate of absolute risk aversion and is wealth in dollars.1 If the return of the risky asset is normally distributed, is also normally distributed, and thus utility is log-normally distributed. As we did in the first lecture, we can take log of the utility function and use to get Dividing the above by gives us . 1 This is a bit different from the CARA utility we have seen before, as we are not having a as the numerator. This is alright because is a positive constant as long as the investors are risk averse.
    [Show full text]
  • Time-Varying Noise Trader Risk and Asset Prices∗
    Time-varying Noise Trader Risk and Asset Prices∗ Dylan C. Thomasy and Qingwei Wangz Abstract By introducing time varying noise trader risk in De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Wald- mann (1990) model, we predict that noise trader risk significantly affects time variations in the small-stock premium. Consistent with the theoretical predictions, we find that when noise trader risk is high, small stocks earn lower contemporaneous returns and higher subsequent re- turns relative to large stocks. In addition, noise trader risk has a positive effect on the volatility of the small-stock premium. After accounting for macroeconomic uncertainty and controlling for time variation in conditional market betas, we demonstrate that systematic risk provides an incomplete explanation for our results. Noise trader risk has a similar impact on the distress premium. Keywords: Noise trader risk; Small-stock premium; Investor sentiment JEL Classification: G10; G12; G14 ∗We thank Mark Tippett for helpful discussions. Errors and omissions remain the responsibility of the author. ySchool of Business, Swansea University, U.K.. E-mail: [email protected] zBangor Business School. E-mail: [email protected] 1 Introduction In this paper we explore the theoretical and empirical time series relationship between noise trader risk and asset prices. We extend the De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990) model to allow noise trader risk to vary over time, and predict its impact on both the returns and volatility of risky assets. Using monthly U.S. data since 1960s, we provide empirical evidence consistent with the model. Our paper contributes to the debate on whether noise trader risk is priced.
    [Show full text]
  • Arbitrage, Noise-Trader Risk, and the Cross Section of Closed-End Fund Returns
    Arbitrage, Noise-trader Risk, and the Cross Section of Closed-end Fund Returns Sean Masaki Flynn¤ This version: April 18, 2005 ABSTRACT I find that despite active arbitrage activity, the discounts of individual closed-end funds are not driven to be consistent with their respective fundamentals. In addition, arbitrage portfolios created by sorting funds by discount level show excess returns not only for the three Fama and French (1992) risk factors but when a measure of average discount movements across all funds is included as well. Because the inclusion of this later variable soaks up volatility common to all funds, the observed inverse relationship between the magnitude of excess returns in the cross section and the ability of these variables to explain overall volatility leads me to suspect that fund-specific risk factors exist which, were they measurable, would justify what otherwise appear to be excess returns. I propose that fund-specific noise-trader risk of the type described by Black (1986) may be the missing risk factor. ¤Department of Economics, Vassar College, 124 Raymond Ave. #424, Poughkeepsie, NY 12604. fl[email protected] I would like to thank Steve Ross for inspiration, and Osaka University’s Institute for Social and Economic Studies for research support while I completed the final drafts of this paper. I also gratefully acknowledge the diligent and tireless research assistance of Rebecca Forster. All errors are my own. Closed-end mutual funds have been closely studied because they offer the chance to examine asset pricing in a situation in which all market participants have common knowledge about fundamental valuations.
    [Show full text]
  • 10.4 Excess Volatility in the Models of Financial Markets We
    David Romer July 2016 Preliminary – please do not circulate! 10.4 Excess Volatility In the models of financial markets we have considered so far – the partial-equilibrium models of consumers’ asset allocation and the determinants of investment in Sections 8.5 and 9.7, and the general-equilibrium model of Section 10.1 – asset prices equal their fundamental values. That is, they are the rational expectations, given agents’ information and their stochastic discount factors, of the present value of the assets’ payoffs. This case is the natural benchmark. It is generally a good idea to start by assuming rationality and no market imperfections. Moreover, many participants in financial markets are highly sophisticated and have vast resources at their disposal, so one might expect that any departures of asset prices from fundamentals would be small and quickly corrected. On the other hand, there are many movements in asset prices that, at least at first glance, cannot be easily explained by changes in fundamentals. And perfectly rational, risk neutral agents with unlimited resources standing ready to immediately correct any unwarranted movements in asset prices do not exist. Thus there is not an open-and-shut theoretical case that asset prices can never differ from fundamentals. This section is therefore devoted to examining the possibility of such departures. We start by considering a model, due to DeLong, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990), that demonstrates what is perhaps the most economically interesting force making such departures 21 possible. DeLong et al. show departures of prices from fundamentals can be self-reinforcing: the very fact that there can be departures creates a source of risk, and so limits the willingness of rational investors to trade to correct the mispricings.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Survival of Overcon"Dent Traders in a Competitive Securities Marketଝ
    Journal of Financial Markets 4 (2001) 73}84 On the survival of overcon"dent traders in a competitive securities marketଝ David Hirshleifer!, Guo Ying Luo" * !The Ohio State University, College of Business, Department of Finance, 740A Fisher Hall, 2100 Neil Avenue, Columbus, OH 43210-1144, USA "Department of Finance, Faculty of Management, Rutgers University, 94 Rockafeller Rd., Piscataway, NJ 08854-8054, USA Abstract Recent research has proposed several ways in which overcon"dent traders can persist in competition with rational traders. This paper o!ers an additional reason: overcon"- dent traders do better than purely rational traders at exploiting mispricing caused by liquidity or noise traders. We examine both the static pro"tability of overcon"dent versus rational trading strategies, and the dynamic evolution of a population of overcon"dent, rational and noise traders. Replication of overcon"dent and rational types is assumed to be increasing in the recent pro"tability of their strategies. The main result is that the long-run steady-state equilibrium always involves overcon"dent traders as a substantial positive fraction of the population. ( 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classixcation: G00; G14 Keywords: Survivorship; Natural selection; Overcon"dent traders; Noise traders 1. Introduction Several recent papers have argued that investor overcon"dence or shifts in con"dence o!er a possible explanation for a range of anomalous empirical ଝWe are grateful to the anonymous referee, Ivan Brick, Kent Daniel, Sherry Gi!ord, Avanidhar Subrahmanyam and the seminar participants at the Northern Finance Association Annual Meeting in Calgary, 1999. for their helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Investor Sentiment and Short Selling: Do Animal Spirits Sell Stocks?
    Investor sentiment and short selling: do animal spirits sell stocks? A Thesis Presented to The Faculty of the Department of Financial Economics Radboud University In Partial Fulfilment Of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Science By Paul Reesink July, 2020 Abstract This paper examines the relationship between investor sentiment and short selling. This is done by calculating daily investor sentiment for every stock in the S&P 500 between January 1990 and December 2019 and group the stocks into four portfolios based on their investor sentiment. The effect of relative overpricing of stocks on their short interest ratio is compared for the different sentiment portfolios. Main result is that the relationship between relative overpricing and the short interest ratio is strongly positive for the highest investor sentiment portfolio and becomes less positive when relative investor sentiment declines. Taking economic recession periods into account does not seem to change the relationship between investor sentiment and short selling, although the effect of the relative overpricing on the short interest ratio becomes less positive for all sentiment portfolios. Keywords: Behavioural finance, firm-specific investor sentiment, short interest ratio, return anomalies 2 Table of contents Page Abstract 2 Table of contents 3 Chapter I. Introduction 4 II. Literature 5 III. Research method 12 IV. Results 17 V. Conclusion and discussion 20 References 23 3 I. Introduction In classical finance, with rational investors and full information, deviations from fundamental value would be immediately exploited by arbitrageurs who bring back the value to their fundamentals. However, episodes like the Great Depression, Black Monday and the dotcom-bubble make it unlikely that stock prices are entirely based on fundamentals.
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Pricing Under Asymmetric Information Bubbles & Limits To
    Asset Pricing under Asym. Information Limits to Arbitrage Historical Bubbles Symmetric Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information Information Pricing Equation Bubbles & Limits to Arbitrage Ruling out Asymmetric Information Expected/Strong Bubble Markus K. Brunnermeier Necessary Conditions Limits to Princeton University Arbitrage Noise Trader Risk Synchronization August 17, 2007 Risk Asset Pricing under Asym. Information Limits to Overview Arbitrage Historical Bubbles Symmetric Information Pricing Equation • All agents are rational Ruling out Asymmetric • Bubbles under symmetric information Information • Bubbles under asymmetric information Expected/Strong Bubble Necessary Conditions • Interaction between rational arbitrageurs and behavioral Limits to traders - Limits to Arbitrage Arbitrage Noise Trader • Fundamental risk Risk Synchronization • Risk Noise trader risk + Endogenous short horizons of arbs • Synchronization risk Asset Pricing under Asym. Information Limits to Historical Bubbles Arbitrage Historical Bubbles Symmetric Information Pricing Equation Ruling out • 1634-1637 Dutch Tulip Mania (Netherlands) Asymmetric Information • Expected/Strong 1719-1720 Mississippi Bubble (France) Bubble Necessary • Conditions 1720 South Sea Bubble (England) Limits to • 1990 Japan Bubble Arbitrage Noise Trader Risk • 1999 Internet/Technology Bubble Synchronization Risk Asset Pricing under Asym. Information Limits to A Technology Company Arbitrage Historical Bubbles Symmetric Information Pricing Equation • Company X introduced a revolutionary wireless Ruling out communication technology. Asymmetric Information • It not only provided support for such a technology but also Expected/Strong Bubble Necessary provided the informational content itself. Conditions Limits to • It’s IPO price was $1.50 per share. Six years later it was Arbitrage Noise Trader traded at $ 85.50 and in the seventh year it hit $ 114.00. Risk Synchronization • Risk The P/E ratio got as high as 73.
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Pricing Implications of Value-Weighted Indexing
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TRACKING BIASED WEIGHTS: ASSET PRICING IMPLICATIONS OF VALUE-WEIGHTED INDEXING Hao Jiang Dimitri Vayanos Lu Zheng Working Paper 28253 http://www.nber.org/papers/w28253 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2020 We thank seminar participants at the Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance for helpful comments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2020 by Hao Jiang, Dimitri Vayanos, and Lu Zheng. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Tracking Biased Weights: Asset Pricing Implications of Value-Weighted Indexing Hao Jiang, Dimitri Vayanos, and Lu Zheng NBER Working Paper No. 28253 December 2020 JEL No. G1,G2 ABSTRACT We show theoretically and empirically that flows into index funds raise the prices of large stocks in the index disproportionately more than the prices of small stocks. Conversely, flows predict a high future return of the small-minus-large index portfolio. This finding runs counter to the CAPM, and arises when noise traders distort prices, biasing index weights. When funds tracking value-weighted indices experience inflows, they buy mainly stocks in high noise-trader demand, exacerbating the distortion. During our sample period 2000-2019, a small-minus-large portfolio of S&P500 stocks earns ten percent per year, while no size effect exists for non-index stocks.
    [Show full text]
  • Detecting the Proportion of Traders in the Stock Market: an Agent-Based Approach
    mathematics Article Detecting the Proportion of Traders in the Stock Market: An Agent-Based Approach Minh Tran 1,2,* ID , Thanh Duong 3, Duc Pham-Hi 1,4 and Marc Bui 2 1 John von Neumann Institute, Vietnam National University Ho Chi Minh City, Ho Chi Minh City 70000, Vietnam; [email protected] 2 CHArt Laboratory EA 4004, EPHE, PSL Research University, 75014 Paris, France; [email protected] 3 CEO at QT-Data Inc., Saskatoon, SK S7K 2P7, Canada; [email protected] 4 Financial Engineering Department, ECE Paris Graduate School of Engineering, Paris 75015, France; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Received: 31 December 2019; Accepted: 29 January 2020; Published: 5 February 2020 Abstract: In this research, an agent-based model (ABM) of the stock market is constructed to detect the proportion of different types of traders. We model a simple stock market which has three different types of traders: noise traders, fundamental traders, and technical traders, trading a single asset. Bayesian optimization is used to tune the hyperparameters of the strategies of traders as well as of the stock market. The experimental results on Bayesian calibration with the Kolmogorov–Smirnov (KS) test demonstrated that the proposed separate calibrations reduced simulation error, with plausible estimated parameters. With empirical data of the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) index, we found that fundamental traders account for 9%–11% of all traders in the stock market. The statistical analysis of simulated data can produce the important stylized facts in real stock markets, such as the leptokurtosis, the heavy tail of the returns, and volatility clustering.
    [Show full text]
  • Identifying Noise Traders Entering the Market with Google and Twitter
    An action – identifying noise traders entering the market with Google and Twitter Carolin Hartmann *, Hans-Peter Burghof* and Marc Mehlhorn ** ABSTRACT In this paper we measure and compare the impact of changes in Google search volume (GSV) and Twitter volume (TV) on financial markets. We find that information investors access via Google and Twitter have an impact on financial markets and predictive power. The impact of TV is more important. First, changes in GSV and TV have a positive impact on changes in turnover. Traders enter the market (Easley et al. 1996). Second, we show that changes in TV increase the share of noise traders on the market (De Long et al. 1990), while changes in GSV have no significant impact. Our results suggest that we are able to measure investor sentiment with TV. Further, we expect that the different impact of GSV and TV lies in the different use of Google and Twitter by investors. Key words: forecasting, investor behavior, noise trader, search engine data, social media, investor sentiment JEL: G10, G14, G17 1 Introduction Google and Twitter have users worldwide 1. They are indicators for the public mood (Bollen et al. 2011). In July 2018 Twitter had 335 million monthly users and 76 percent of search engine users choose Google. Especially for financial markets Twitter becomes more and more important. U.S. president Donald Trump uses Twitter as his direct medium of communication 2. Elon Musk’s tweet on 7 August 2018 about taking TESLA private led to an increase of the share by 11 percent. Short sellers lost approximately 1.3 bn USD.
    [Show full text]
  • Noise Traders, Fintech, and Equity Market Volatility
    Georgia Southern University Digital Commons@Georgia Southern University Honors Program Theses 2020 Noise Traders, Fintech, and Equity Market Volatility William T. Collins Georgia Southern University Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.georgiasouthern.edu/honors-theses Part of the Finance and Financial Management Commons Recommended Citation Collins, William T., "Noise Traders, Fintech, and Equity Market Volatility" (2020). University Honors Program Theses. 544. https://digitalcommons.georgiasouthern.edu/honors-theses/544 This thesis (open access) is brought to you for free and open access by Digital Commons@Georgia Southern. It has been accepted for inclusion in University Honors Program Theses by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons@Georgia Southern. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Noise Traders, Fintech, and Equity Market Volatility An Honors Thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for Honors in Parker College of Business By William T. Collins Under the advice of Dr. Axel Grossmann Noise Traders, Fintech and Equity Market Volatility Abstract The literature provides ample evidence that the last decades have seen an increase in noise trader activities, in part driven by the development of fintech. This paper strives to educate readers on the term noise traders as well as fintech. Moreover, it argues that the evolvement of noise trader activities accompanied with fintech has increased equity market volatility over time. The study finds that equity market volatility has indeed increased over time and is not driven by periods of crisis. Furthermore, this increase in volatility is more severe for small stocks versus large stocks, which is in line with the stated hypothesis that low volume stocks (small stocks) are more impacted by noise trades.
    [Show full text]