Detecting the Proportion of Traders in the Stock Market: an Agent-Based Approach
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Investors' Awareness of Fundamental and Technical Analysis For
International Journal of Innovative Technology and Exploring Engineering (IJITEE) ISSN: 2278-3075, Volume-8 Issue-9, July 2019 Investors’ Awareness of fundamental and Technical Analysis for Investments in Securities Market Jayalakshmi. R, N. Lakshmi Abstract: The role of investors in the securities market reveals the rising prominence of financial savings and also the II. REVIEW OF LITERATURE growth of industry and the economy. The focal point is to survey the investors’ awareness of the fundamental and technical Wiwik Utami (2017) conducted a case study on investors’ analysis for investment in the securities market. The study stock investment decisions in Indonesia. The result showed identified an analysis of the economy, industries and companies that the period of investment and experience influenced the as the three fundamental components that influence and affect method of security analysis adopted before investment the investors’ investment in the securities market. decisions. Technical analysis was mostly preferred by Keywords: securities market, investors, rising prominence, regular tradinginvestors for quick decision-making. financial savings & technical analysis. Prasaanna Prakash (2016) found that the retail investors were less aware of the various investment options and the I. INTRODUCTION protective measures taken by the government. A majority of Investment in the securities market needs analysis to the retail investors chose investments for a short duration. identify and select the right instruments and right time to The researcher suggested that the retail investors be given invest to reap high returns, which in turn, can increase the proper attention. Investors’ decisions were based on investors’ wealth. Based on the analysis, the investment psychological, emotional and behavioral factors. -
Fundamental Analysis to Access the Fair Value Based on Price Earning
International Conference on Education For Economics, ISSN (Print) 2540-8372 Business, and Finance (ICEEBF) 2016 ISSN (Online) 2540-7481 Fundamental Analysis to Access the Fair Value Based on Price Earning Ratio (PER) and Dividend Discount Model (DDM) Approach as the basis for Investment Decision Making (A Study on the Insurance Sub Sector Listing in Indonesia Stock Exchange Period 2013-2015) Lisa Rahayu Ningsih Faculty of Economics, Universitas Negeri Malang, Indonesia Email: [email protected] Abstract This research aims to give explanation to assess and determine the reasonableness stock price of comparing fair value with market price. Assessing the reasonableness of stock price by Price Earning Ratio and Dividend Discount Model approaches in insurance companies listed in Indonesia Stock Exchange 2013-2015 to make investment decision. The research use descriptive research with quantitative approach. The population in this study is 12 insurance companies and the sampling technique is purposive sampling which 7 companies taken as sample with ticker stock code ABDA, AMAG, ASBI, ASDM, LPGI, MREI, ASRM. Fundamental ratio used in this research is Return On Equity (ROE), Earning Per Share (EPS), Dividend Per Share (DPS), and Dividend Payout Ratio (DPR). The result of this research showed one company that the price of its share which are undervalued and six companies that the price of overvalued condition when it measured with Price Earning Ratio method. Beside that comparing final result by using Dividend Discount Model showed that three companies is an undervalued position and four companies is an overvalued position. The decision that can be taken by investor based on undervalued condition is to buy or hold the shares whereas overvalued condition is to sell. -
Kochmeister Awards Ceremony at the Budapest Stock Exchange
Kochmeister awards ceremony at the Budapest Stock Exchange Budapest, 14 June 2010 Kochmeister award is handed over today for the seventh time at the Budapest Stock Exchange. The Budapest Stock Exchange founded the Kochmeister Award in 2004 to reward talented young people who submit the best paper(s) on predetermined topics related to the Stock Exchange. The award is named after Baron Frigyes Kochmeister, who played a leading role in 1864, in establishing the Budapest Commodity and Stock Exchange, and, as the first chairman of the Exchange, managed the institution for years. BSE Chief Executive Officer György Mohai handed over the prizes. Zsolt Kelemen, Deputy CEO of Finance of CIG Pannónia Life Insurance Plc. handed over the special prize offered by the company. Eighteen essays that arrived from eight national and transborder higher education institutions were in competition in the contest dedicated to the memory of Frigyes Kochmeister in 2011. The professional jury is awarded the following winners: First place: Zita-Klára Málnási - student of Babes-Bolyai University, Cluj-Napoca Title: Fundamental Analysis of the E-Star Alternative Plc. Second place: Viktor Vajda - student of Corvinus University, Budapest Title: New types of security trading platforms in the European Union Third place: Gábor Szentirmai - student of Corvinus University of Budapest Title: Fundamental Analysis of the E-Star Alternative Plc. Special prize offered by CIG Pannónia Life Insurance Plc.: Péter Szentirmai – student of Corvinus University of Budapest Title: Testing the technical trading rules of forecastability at the Budapest Stock Exchange About the Budapest Stock Exchange The CEE Stock Exchange Group (CEESEG), which comprises of the stock exchanges of Budapest, Ljubljana, Prague and Vienna, is the largest stock exchange group in the region. -
(Form ADV, Part 2A) Cavanal Hill
Item 1 – Cover Page Firm Brochure (Form ADV, Part 2A) Cavanal Hill Investment Management, Inc. One Williams Center 15th Floor Tulsa, Oklahoma 74172 (800) 958-2942 May 2020 This brochure (“B r o c h u r e”) provides information about the qualifications and business practices of Cavanal Hill Investment Management, Inc. If you have questions about the contents of this brochure, please contact us at (800) 955-2942 or www.cavanalhill.com. The information in this brochure has not been approved or verified by the United States Securities and Exchange Commission or by any state securities authority. Additional information about Cavanal Hill Investment Management, Inc. is available on the SEC’s website at www.adviserinfo.sec.gov. Note: While Cavanal Hill Investment Management, Inc. may refer to itself as a “registered investment adviser” or “RIA” you should be aware that registration itself does not imply any level of skill or training. 1 Item 2 – Material Changes Annual Update The Material Changes section of this brochure is updated to report any material changes to the previous version of Form ADV, Part 2A (the Firm Brochure). The section bellows provides a summary of material changes since the last update. Summary of Material Changes since the Last Update The U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission requires that each Investment Adviser provide its new clients with a copy of its Form ADV, Part 2A. The rule requires completion of specific mandatory sections and those sections are to be organized in the order specified by the rule. Investment adviser must update the information in their Form ADV, Part 2A, when a material change has occurred. -
Download Download
International Business & Economics Research Journal – November/December 2014 Volume 13, Number 6 The Random Walk Theory And Stock Prices: Evidence From Johannesburg Stock Exchange Tafadzwa T. Chitenderu, University of Fort Hare, South Africa Andrew Maredza, North West University, South Africa Kin Sibanda, University of Fort Hare, South Africa ABSTRACT In this paper, we test the Johannesburg Stock Exchange market for the existence of the random walk hypothesis using monthly time series of the All Share Index (ALSI) covering the period 2000 – 2011. Traditional methods, such as unit root tests and autocorrelation test, were employed first and they all confirmed that during the period under consideration, the JSE price index followed the random walk process. In addition, the ARIMA model was constructed and it was found that the ARIMA (1, 1, 1) was the model that most excellently fitted the data in question. Furthermore, residual tests were performed to determine whether the residuals of the estimated equation followed a random walk process in the series. The authors found that the ALSI resembles a series that follow random walk hypothesis with strong evidence of a wide variance between forecasted and actual values, indicating little or no forecasting strength in the series. To further validate the findings in this research, the variance ratio test was conducted under heteroscedasticity and resulted in non-rejection of the random walk hypothesis. It was concluded that since the returns follow the random walk hypothesis, it can be said that JSE, in terms of efficiency, is on the weak form level and therefore opportunities of making excess returns based on out-performing the market is ruled out and is merely a game of chance. -
INSTITUTIONAL FINANCE Lecture 07: Liquidity, Limits to Arbitrage – Margins + Bubbles DEBRIEFING - MARGINS
INSTITUTIONAL FINANCE Lecture 07: Liquidity, Limits to Arbitrage – Margins + Bubbles DEBRIEFING - MARGINS $ • No constraints Initial Margin (50%) Reg. T 50 % • Can’t add to your position; • Not received a margin call. Maintenance Margin (35%) NYSE/NASD 25% long 30% short • Fixed amount of time to get to a specified point above the maintenance level before your position is liquidated. • Failure to return to the initial margin requirements within the specified period of time results in forced liquidation. Minimum Margin (25%) • Position is always immediately liquidated MARGINS – VALUE AT RISK (VAR) Margins give incentive to hold well diversified portfolio How are margins set by brokers/exchanges? Value at Risk: Pr (-(pt+1 – pt)¸ m) = 1 % 1% Value at Risk LEVERAGE AND MARGINS j+ j Financing a long position of x t>0 shares at price p t=100: Borrow $90$ dollar per share; j+ Margin/haircut: m t=100-90=10 j+ Capital use: $10 x t j- Financing a short position of x t>0 shares: Borrow securities, and lend collateral of 110 dollar per share Short-sell securities at price of 100 j- Margin/haircut: m t=110-100=10 j- Capital use: $10 x t Positions frequently marked to market j j j payment of x t(p t-p t-1) plus interest margins potentially adjusted – more later on this Margins/haircuts must be financed with capital: j+ j+ j- j- j j+ j- j ( x t m t+ x t m t ) · Wt , where x =xt -xt 1 J with perfect cross-margining: Mt ( xt , …,xt ) · Wt 3. -
Noise Traders - Detailed Derivation
University of California, Berkeley Summer 2010 ECON 138 Noise Traders - Detailed Derivation A common response to the behavioral anomalies we have discussed in this course is that they have little impact on the long run, because investors with such anomalies are not maximizing optimally, and would thus be driven out of the market. We shall show, however, that noise traders—traders who are not maximizing—can indeed survive even in a very simple market setting. The model is taken out of De Long et al, "Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets," The Journal of Political Economy, Aug. 1990. I. Setting . Two-period model. Invest in the first period, consume in the second . CARA utility . One risk-free asset with return r and infinite supply . One risky asset with price and pays a dividend of r. Supply is fixed to 1. noise traders and rational traders, . Noise traders misperceive the expected price of the risky asset in the second period by II. Derivation 1. Utility Function We start off with CARA utility Where is the rate of absolute risk aversion and is wealth in dollars.1 If the return of the risky asset is normally distributed, is also normally distributed, and thus utility is log-normally distributed. As we did in the first lecture, we can take log of the utility function and use to get Dividing the above by gives us . 1 This is a bit different from the CARA utility we have seen before, as we are not having a as the numerator. This is alright because is a positive constant as long as the investors are risk averse. -
Time-Varying Noise Trader Risk and Asset Prices∗
Time-varying Noise Trader Risk and Asset Prices∗ Dylan C. Thomasy and Qingwei Wangz Abstract By introducing time varying noise trader risk in De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Wald- mann (1990) model, we predict that noise trader risk significantly affects time variations in the small-stock premium. Consistent with the theoretical predictions, we find that when noise trader risk is high, small stocks earn lower contemporaneous returns and higher subsequent re- turns relative to large stocks. In addition, noise trader risk has a positive effect on the volatility of the small-stock premium. After accounting for macroeconomic uncertainty and controlling for time variation in conditional market betas, we demonstrate that systematic risk provides an incomplete explanation for our results. Noise trader risk has a similar impact on the distress premium. Keywords: Noise trader risk; Small-stock premium; Investor sentiment JEL Classification: G10; G12; G14 ∗We thank Mark Tippett for helpful discussions. Errors and omissions remain the responsibility of the author. ySchool of Business, Swansea University, U.K.. E-mail: [email protected] zBangor Business School. E-mail: [email protected] 1 Introduction In this paper we explore the theoretical and empirical time series relationship between noise trader risk and asset prices. We extend the De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990) model to allow noise trader risk to vary over time, and predict its impact on both the returns and volatility of risky assets. Using monthly U.S. data since 1960s, we provide empirical evidence consistent with the model. Our paper contributes to the debate on whether noise trader risk is priced. -
How the Stock Market Works: a Beginner's
i ii iii iv If you speculate on the stock market, you do so at your own risk. Publisher’s note Every possible effort has been made to ensure that the information contained in this book is accurate at the time of going to press, and the publishers and authors cannot accept responsibility for any errors or omissions, however caused. No responsibility for loss or damage occasioned to any person acting, or refraining from action, as a result of the mate- rial in this publication can be accepted by the editor, the publisher or either of the authors. First published in 2002 Reprinted in 2002, 2003 Second edition, 2004 Reprinted in 2005, 2006, 2007 (twice), 2009 Third edition 2010 Apart from any fair dealing for the purposes of research or private study, or criticism or review, as permitted under the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, this publication may only be reproduced, stored or transmitted, in any form or by any means, with the prior permission in writing of the publishers, or in the case of reprographic reproduction in accordance with the terms and licences issued by the CLA. Enquiries concerning reproduction outside these terms should be sent to the publishers at the undermentioned addresses: 120 Pentonville Road 525 South 4th Street, #241 London N1 9JN Philadelphia PA 19147 United Kingdom USA www.koganpage.com © Michael Becket, 2002, 2004 © Michael Becket and Yvette Essen, 2010 The right of Michael Becket and Yvette Essen to be identified as the authors of this work has been asserted by them in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. -
Fundamental Analysis and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns: a Data-Mining Approach
Fundamental Analysis and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns: A Data-Mining Approach Abstract A key challenge to evaluate data-mining bias in stock return anomalies is that we do not observe all the variables considered by researchers. We overcome this challenge by constructing a “universe” of fundamental signals from financial statements and by using a bootstrap approach to measure the impact of data mining. We find that many fundamental signals are significant predictors of cross-sectional stock returns even after accounting for data mining. This predictive ability is more pronounced following high-sentiment periods, during earnings-announcement days, and among stocks with greater limits-to-arbitrage. Our evidence suggests that fundamental- based anomalies are not a product of data mining, and they are best explained by mispricing. Our approach is general and can be applied to other categories of anomaly variables. October 2015 “Economists place a premium on the discovery of puzzles, which in the context at hand amounts to finding apparent rejections of a widely accepted theory of stock market behavior.” Merton (1987, p. 104) 1. Introduction Finance researchers have devoted a considerable amount of time and effort to searching for stock return patterns that cannot be explained by traditional asset pricing models. As a result of these efforts, there is now a large body of literature reporting hundreds of cross-sectional return anomalies (Green, Hand, and Zhang (2013), Harvey, Liu, and Zhu (HLZ 2014), and McLean and Pontiff (2014)). An important debate in the literature is whether the abnormal returns documented in these studies are compensation for systematic risk, evidence of market inefficiency, or simply the result of extensive data mining. -
Arbitrage, Noise-Trader Risk, and the Cross Section of Closed-End Fund Returns
Arbitrage, Noise-trader Risk, and the Cross Section of Closed-end Fund Returns Sean Masaki Flynn¤ This version: April 18, 2005 ABSTRACT I find that despite active arbitrage activity, the discounts of individual closed-end funds are not driven to be consistent with their respective fundamentals. In addition, arbitrage portfolios created by sorting funds by discount level show excess returns not only for the three Fama and French (1992) risk factors but when a measure of average discount movements across all funds is included as well. Because the inclusion of this later variable soaks up volatility common to all funds, the observed inverse relationship between the magnitude of excess returns in the cross section and the ability of these variables to explain overall volatility leads me to suspect that fund-specific risk factors exist which, were they measurable, would justify what otherwise appear to be excess returns. I propose that fund-specific noise-trader risk of the type described by Black (1986) may be the missing risk factor. ¤Department of Economics, Vassar College, 124 Raymond Ave. #424, Poughkeepsie, NY 12604. fl[email protected] I would like to thank Steve Ross for inspiration, and Osaka University’s Institute for Social and Economic Studies for research support while I completed the final drafts of this paper. I also gratefully acknowledge the diligent and tireless research assistance of Rebecca Forster. All errors are my own. Closed-end mutual funds have been closely studied because they offer the chance to examine asset pricing in a situation in which all market participants have common knowledge about fundamental valuations. -
10.4 Excess Volatility in the Models of Financial Markets We
David Romer July 2016 Preliminary – please do not circulate! 10.4 Excess Volatility In the models of financial markets we have considered so far – the partial-equilibrium models of consumers’ asset allocation and the determinants of investment in Sections 8.5 and 9.7, and the general-equilibrium model of Section 10.1 – asset prices equal their fundamental values. That is, they are the rational expectations, given agents’ information and their stochastic discount factors, of the present value of the assets’ payoffs. This case is the natural benchmark. It is generally a good idea to start by assuming rationality and no market imperfections. Moreover, many participants in financial markets are highly sophisticated and have vast resources at their disposal, so one might expect that any departures of asset prices from fundamentals would be small and quickly corrected. On the other hand, there are many movements in asset prices that, at least at first glance, cannot be easily explained by changes in fundamentals. And perfectly rational, risk neutral agents with unlimited resources standing ready to immediately correct any unwarranted movements in asset prices do not exist. Thus there is not an open-and-shut theoretical case that asset prices can never differ from fundamentals. This section is therefore devoted to examining the possibility of such departures. We start by considering a model, due to DeLong, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990), that demonstrates what is perhaps the most economically interesting force making such departures 21 possible. DeLong et al. show departures of prices from fundamentals can be self-reinforcing: the very fact that there can be departures creates a source of risk, and so limits the willingness of rational investors to trade to correct the mispricings.