The Taxing Power, the Sixteenth Amendment, and the Meaning of ‘Incomes,’

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Taxing Power, the Sixteenth Amendment, and the Meaning of ‘Incomes,’ Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons Faculty Publications 2006 The Taxing Power, the Sixteenth Amendment, and the Meaning of ‘Incomes,’ Erik M. Jensen Case Western University School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/faculty_publications Part of the Constitutional Law Commons, and the Tax Law Commons Repository Citation Jensen, Erik M., "The Taxing Power, the Sixteenth Amendment, and the Meaning of ‘Incomes,’" (2006). Faculty Publications. 219. https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/faculty_publications/219 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=336740 THE TAXING POWER, THE SIXTEENTH AMENDMENT, AND THE MEANING OF "INCOMES" ErikM. Jensen* I. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 1058 IT. THE CONSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK AND PLENARY POWER ............... 1064 A. The Uniformity Clause ................................................................. 1065 B. The Direct-Tax Apportionment Clauses ....................................... 1066 1. Mechanics of the Apportionment Rule .................................. 1067 2. Intended Effect of the Rule .................................................... 1067 3. Meaning of"Direct Taxes": The Historical Background ....... 1069 4. Meaning of"Direct Taxes": Making Sense of Text and Constitutional Structure .......................................................... 1073 5. Why a Broad Interpretation of "Direct Taxes" Is Consistent with Original Understanding ................................ 1077 6. A Final Point on Direct Taxation ........................................... 1079 Ill. SETTING THE STAGE FOR "TAXES ON INCOMES": CONSUMPTION TAXES AND INCOME TAXES ................................................................ 1080 A. Income Taxes and Consumption Taxes: A Primer ...................... 1080 1. Income Tax............................................................................. 1081 2. Cash-Flow Consumption Tax. ................................................ 1081 3. Wage Tax ..................................................................... ;......... 1082 B. Assumptions ................................................................................. 1083 IV. THE MEANING OF "TAXES ON INCOMES" ............................................ 1085 A. The Nature of the Constitution and "Inherent Malleability" ........ 1087 B. The Income Tax as a Reaction to the Perceived Inadequacies of Consumption Taxes ............................................ 1091 1. The 1894 Income Tax and Its Predecessor ............................ 1093 2. On to the Sixteenth Amendment ............................................ 1107 3. A Wealth Tax Isn't an Income Tax ........................................ 1128 C. Consumption Taxes and Income Taxes Today ............................. 1129 * David L. Brennan Professor of Law, Case Western Reserve University. The author thanks Professors Henry P. Monaghan, Jr., Jonathan Entin, Deborah Geier, and Andrew Morriss, and participants in a faculty colloquium at the University of Florida College of Law, for very helpful comments on an earlier draft. 1058 ARIZONA STATE LAW JOURNAL [Ariz. St. L.J. D. The Supreme Court and the Meaning of "Incomes" .................... 1131 1. The Notion of a Fixed Concept oflncome ......... ~ ................... 1133 2. Defer to Understanding of "Incomes" at Time of Ratification ............................................................................. 1146 3. Accounting Conventions and the Constitution ....................... 114 7 E. The Assumptions Behind Congressional Power to Define "Incomes" ..................................................................................... 1152 V. CONSTITUTIONALITY BY ACCRETION AND THE "GOTCHA" READING OF THE SIXTEENTH AMENDMENT ........................................ 1154 VI. CONCLUSION ....................................................................................... 1158 I. INTRODUCTION The taxing power-the "Power To lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Imposts and Excises, to pay the Debts and provide for the common Defence and general Welfare of the United States" 1-is plenary, or so we're often told, and "plenary" means without significant limits. 2 It's the conventional wisdom that a necessarily expansive power to raise revenue shouldn't be­ indeed can't be-subject to serious constitutional restraints. It's also the conventional wisdom that the ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment in 1913 did nothing more than remove a temporary, illegitimate impediment to the plenary taxing power. In the 1895 Income Tax Cases (Pollock v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Co.), 3 the Supreme Court struck down an 1894 income tax on the ground that it was a direct tax required, under Article I of the Constitution, to be apportioned among the states on the basis of population. 4 The Sixteenth Amendment, exempting 1. U.S. CONST. art. I, § 8, cl. 1. 2. See, e.g., LoRENP. BETH, THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE AMERICAN CONSTITUTION 1877- 1917, at 154 (HenryS. Commager & Richard B. Morris eds., 1971) (describing clause as "so sweeping that it has seldom been construed as an interference with any tax measure"). 3. 157 U.S. 429 (1895) (holding unapportioned tax on income from real estate unconstitutional); 158 U.S. 601 (1895) (extending principle to income from personal property and rejecting entire 1894 tax). 4. See U.S. CONST. art. I, § 9, cl. 4 (''No Capitation, or other direct, Tax shall be laid, unless in Proportion to the Census or Enumeration herein before directed to be taken."); U.S. CONST. art. I, § 2, cl. 3: Representatives and direct Taxes shall be apportioned among the several States which may be included within this Union, according to their respective Numbers, which shall be determined by adding to the whole Number of free Persons, including those bound to Service for a Term of Years, and excluding Indians not taxed, three fifths of all other Persons. 33: 1057] TAXING POWER 1059 "taxes on incomes" from the apportionment requirement, 5 corrected that mistake, reestablishing the plenary taxing power. This Article attacks the conventional wisdom in a couple of respects. Building on earlier work, this Article continues my challenge to the notion that the taxing power is plenary (if by "plenary" we mean without significant restrictions): the specific limitations on the taxing power in the Constitution weren't intended to be trivial.6 Furthermore, this Article focuses on the Sixteenth Amendment and challenges the generally held notion that the Amendment supports an unlimited taxing power. Hardly anyone these days believes that the Sixteenth Amendment imposes a substantive limitation on congressional power, and the Amendment reads as if it were a grant of, not a restriction on, power: "The Congress shall have power to lay and collect taxes on incomes, from whatever source derived, without apportionment among the several States, and without regard to any eensus or enumeration."7 In the words of Professor Daniel Shaviro, "[I]t is generally agreed that the amendment does not significantly constrain how taxable income can be defined by Congress and the courts."8 The conventional syllogism goes like this: Congress can define what "income" is, and 1t can therefore define what a "tax on incomes" is. If Congress says a tax is on income, that ends the discussion: no apportionment is required. Like "general welfare"9 or "public use," 10 the term "taxes on incomes" imposes no serious limitations on Congress, and it's not a judicially enforceable concept. II Victor Thuronyi has put the argument this way: "Because people have different views of tax equity, there is no 'true' concept of income.''I2 5. U.S. CONST. amend. XVI; see infra text accompanying note 7. 6. See Erik M. Jensen, The Apportionment of "Direct Taxes": Are Consumption Taxes Constitutional?, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 2334 (1997). 7. U.S. CONST. amend. XVI. 8. Daniel N. Shaviro, Psychic Income Revisited: Response to Professors Johnson and Dodge, 45 TAXL. REv. 707,711 n.17 (1990). 9. U.S. CONST. art. I,§ 8, cl. 1; supra text accompanying note 1. 10. U.S. CONST. amend. V ("nor shall private property be taken for public' use without just compensation"). 11. See South Dakota v. Dole, 483 U.S. 203, 207 n.2 (1987) ("The level of deference to the congressional decision is such that the Court has more recently questioned whether 'general welfare' is a judicially enforceable restriction at all." (citing Buckley v. Valeo, 424 U.S. 1, 90- 91 (1976))); Hawaii Housing Auth. v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229, 239 (1984) ("When the legislature has spoken [in defining 'public use'], the public interest has been declared in terms well-nigh conclusive." (quoting Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26, 31 (1954))). 12. Victor Thuronyi, The Concept of Income, 46 TAX L. REv. 45, 53 (1990). "[I]ncome could mean the same thing as consumption or wealth, or something else, depending on the criteria we choose for determining tax equity." Id. at 54. 1060 ARIZONA STATE LAW JOURNAL [Ariz. St. L.J. Instead, the concept "is by its nature highly practical, flexible and ad hoc," 13 and that flexibility has constitutional implications: [T]he Constitution allows Congress to provide
Recommended publications
  • RESTORING the LOST ANTI-INJUNCTION ACT Kristin E
    COPYRIGHT © 2017 VIRGINIA LAW REVIEW ASSOCIATION RESTORING THE LOST ANTI-INJUNCTION ACT Kristin E. Hickman* & Gerald Kerska† Should Treasury regulations and IRS guidance documents be eligible for pre-enforcement judicial review? The D.C. Circuit’s 2015 decision in Florida Bankers Ass’n v. U.S. Department of the Treasury puts its interpretation of the Anti-Injunction Act at odds with both general administrative law norms in favor of pre-enforcement review of final agency action and also the Supreme Court’s interpretation of the nearly identical Tax Injunction Act. A 2017 federal district court decision in Chamber of Commerce v. IRS, appealable to the Fifth Circuit, interprets the Anti-Injunction Act differently and could lead to a circuit split regarding pre-enforcement judicial review of Treasury regulations and IRS guidance documents. Other cases interpreting the Anti-Injunction Act more generally are fragmented and inconsistent. In an effort to gain greater understanding of the Anti-Injunction Act and its role in tax administration, this Article looks back to the Anti- Injunction Act’s origin in 1867 as part of Civil War–era revenue legislation and the evolution of both tax administrative practices and Anti-Injunction Act jurisprudence since that time. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 1684 I. A JURISPRUDENTIAL MESS, AND WHY IT MATTERS ...................... 1688 A. Exploring the Doctrinal Tensions.......................................... 1690 1. Confused Anti-Injunction Act Jurisprudence .................. 1691 2. The Administrative Procedure Act’s Presumption of Reviewability ................................................................... 1704 3. The Tax Injunction Act .................................................... 1707 B. Why the Conflict Matters ....................................................... 1712 * Distinguished McKnight University Professor and Harlan Albert Rogers Professor in Law, University of Minnesota Law School.
    [Show full text]
  • The Progressive Movement and the Reforming of the United States of America, from 1890 to 1921
    2014 Democratic and Popular Republic of Algeria. Ministry of Higher Education and Scientific Research. University of Oran. Faculty of Letters, Languages, and Arts. Department of English. Research Paper Submitted for a Doctorate Thesis in American Civilisation Entitled: The Progressive Movement and the Reforming of the United States of America, from 1890 to 1921. Presented by: Benketaf, Abdel Hafid. Jury Members Designation University Pr. Bouhadiba, Zoulikha President Oran Pr. Borsali, Fewzi Supervisor Adrar Pr. Bedjaoui, Fouzia Examiner 1 Sidi-Belabes Dr. Moulfi, Leila Examiner 2 Oran Dr. Belmeki, Belkacem Examiner 3 Oran Dr. Afkir, Mohamed Examiner 4 Laghouat Academic Year: 2013-2014. 1 Acknowledgements Acknowledgments are gratefully made for the assistance of numerous friends and acquaintances. The largest debt is to Professor Borsali, Fewzi because his patience, sound advice, and pertinent remarks were of capital importance in the accomplishment of this thesis. I would not close this note of appreciation without alluding to the great aid provided by my wife Fatima Zohra Melki. 2 Dedication To my family, I dedicate this thesis. Pages Contents 3 List of Tables. ........................................................................................................................................................................ vi List of Abbreviations......................................................................................................................................................... vii Introduction. ........................................................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Legal Status of Capital Gains
    LEGAL STATUS OF CAPITAL GAINS PREPARED BY THE STAFF OF THE JOINT COMMITTEE ON INTERNAL REVENUE TAXATION DECEMBER 4, 1959 UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 48572 WASHINGTON : 1959 J0810-59 LEGAL STATUS OF CAPITAL GAINS HISTORICAL PERIOD PRIOR TO THE 16TH AMENDMENT The power of the CQngress to subject capital gains to an income tax is now fully established by decisions of the Suprenle Court. Even in our first inconle tax statute (act of 1861, 12 Stat. 292) Congress used language broad enough to warrant the taxation of "annual cap­ ital gains." This first act levied on income tax to be paid upon the "annual income" deriyecl fronl certain sources, including income "deriyed from an:r kind of property" and contained a catchall provi­ sion s,,~eeping in "income derived fronl any other source whatever" with certain exceptions having no relation to capital gains. This act was neYer put into effect and was superseded by- the act of 1862 (12 Stat. 432), ,,~hich was similar in this respect to the 1861 act except that the basis of the tax was changed fronl "annual income" to the longer nhrase "annual gains, profits, or income." It \vas not until the act of 1864 (13 Stat. 223) that income derived fronl sales of prop­ erty was specifically mentioned. This last act contained the same general definition of income referred to in the prior acts, with an additional proviso- that net profits realized by sales of real estate purchased within the year for which income is estimated, shall be chargeable as income; and losses on sales of real estate purchased within the year for which income is estimated, shall be deducted from the income of such year.
    [Show full text]
  • The Revenue Act of 1934
    March, 1935 THE REVENUE ACT OF 1934 GEORGE GRAYSON TYLER t AND JOHN P. OHL X Congress, probably inspired by the disclosures of the investigations of the Banking and Currency Committee, passed House Resolution 183, on June 9, 1933, thereby authorizing the Ways and Means Committee to in- vestigate methods of preventing the evasion and avoidance of taxes, means of simplifying the revenue laws and possible new sources of revenue. Pur- suant to this Resolution, a Subcommittee of the Committee on \Ways and Means conducted an inquiry prior to the convening of the second session of the 73d Congress. The Subcommittee filed "A Preliminary Report" ' on December 4, 1933, upon the subjects, of tax avoidance, evasion and sim- plification. In response to the Subcommittee's recommendations, the then Acting Secretary of the Treasury, Henry Morgenthau, Jr., issued a state- ment 2 differing in many important particulars from the conclusions reached by the Subcommittee. As a result of the above investigations, H. R. 7835 was introduced in the House and referred to the Committee on Ways and Means. After extensive hearings 3 the bill was reported out with amendments by the Com- 4 mittee and a report was submitted thereon. On February 21, 1934, the House passed the bill with minor committee amendments. 5 Then, having been introduced in the Senate, the bill was referred to the Finance Com- mittee, which, after further hearings,0 reported it 7 with substantial amend- ments. Further material changes were made on the floor of the Senate s before passage. Thereafter, the Conference Committee on the disagreeing votes of the two Houses made its recommendations reconciling the differ- j- Formerly assistant to Professor Roswell Magill, former assistant to the Secretary of the Treasury; member of the New York Bar.
    [Show full text]
  • WHAT ARE MINIMUM TAXES, and WHY MIGHT ONE FAVOR OR DISFAVOR THEM? Daniel Shaviro* June 9, 2020 Revised Draft All Rights Reserved
    WHAT ARE MINIMUM TAXES, AND WHY MIGHT ONE FAVOR OR DISFAVOR THEM? Daniel Shaviro* June 9, 2020 Revised Draft All Rights Reserved Table of Contents Introduction ......................................................................................................................... 2 I. Minimum Taxes Historically and Conceptually ......................................................... 4 II. The 1986 Alternative Minimum Tax ........................................................................ 22 A. From “Just One Cent” to a Preference Rationing Rule ............................................. 22 B. Post-1986 Decline and (Partial) Fall of the AMT ..................................................... 29 III. A Minimum or Other Tax on Corporate Financial Statement Income? ................... 37 A. Background ........................................................................................................... 37 B. Significance of the Main Rationales for Taxing Book Income ............................ 40 1. Optical Effects of Not Taxing Companies with Large Reported Profits ........... 40 2. Aim of Raising Overall Corporate Tax Burdens ............................................... 40 3. Suspected Underlying Corporate Tax Avoidance ............................................. 41 C. Empirical Issues Raised in the Debate Over Taxing (or Not) Book Income ........ 42 1. Effects on Managerial Agency Costs and the Quality of Information Supplied to Investors 42 2. Effects on Political Choice ...............................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • U.S. Tax Imperialism
    Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons Faculty Scholarship 2015 U.S. Tax Imperialism Diane Lourdes Dick Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/faculty Part of the Tax Law Commons Recommended Citation Diane Lourdes Dick, U.S. Tax Imperialism, 65 Am. U. L. Rev. 1 (2015). https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/faculty/729 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ARTICLES U.S. TAX IMPERIALISM IN PUERTO RICO DIANE LOURDES DICK* This Article uses historical and legal analysis to demonstrate how U.S. domination over Puerto Rico's tax and fiscal policies has been the centerpiece of a colonial system and an especially destructive form of economic imperialism. Specifically, this Article develops a novel theory of U.S. tax imperialism in Puerto Rico, chronicling the sundry ways in which the United States has used tax laws to exert economic dominance over its less developed island colony. During the colonial period, U.S. officials wrote and revised Puerto Rican tax laws to serve U.S. economic interests. In more recent years, U.S. tax laws have disadvantagedPuerto Ricans, who still lack voting rights and full democratic representation in Congress. A theory of tax imperialism may also have applicationfar beyond the U.S.-Puerto Rican experience. For instance, it may help us understand the relationships between the United States and its other possessions and territories throughout history, and between the United Kingdom and its British Crown dependencies, overseas territories, and newly-independent colonies.
    [Show full text]
  • Murphy V. Internal Revenue Service, the Meaning of Income, and Sky-Is-Falling Tax Commentary
    Case Western Reserve Law Review Volume 60 Issue 3 Article 17 2010 Murphy v. Internal Revenue Service, the Meaning of Income, and Sky-is-Falling Tax Commentary Erik M. Jensen Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/caselrev Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Erik M. Jensen, Murphy v. Internal Revenue Service, the Meaning of Income, and Sky-is-Falling Tax Commentary, 60 Case W. Rsrv. L. Rev. 751 (2010) Available at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/caselrev/vol60/iss3/17 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Journals at Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Case Western Reserve Law Review by an authorized administrator of Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. MURPHY V. INTERNAL REVENUE SERVICE, THE MEANING OF "INCOME," AND SKY-Is-FALLING TAx COMMENTARY Erik M. Jensent I. INTRODUCTION ...................................... 752 A. Murphy I and the Hyperventilating Blogosphere ....... 753 B. The Plan of Attack.......................... 758 II. MURPHY 1: THE BASICS ............................ 759 III. THE HOWLERS IN MURPHY I ............ ......... 761 IV. DIRECT TAXES AND THE SIXTEENTH AMENDMENT .......... 765 A. The ConstitutionalStructure .................. 765 B. Does Any of This Matter Anymore? ............. 771 C. What Is a Direct Tax? .............. .......... 776 1. Direct Taxes Are (Would You Believe It?) Not Indirect Taxes......................... 776 2. Pollock and a Tax on Earned Income Only ........... 779 D. The Constitution Matters in Murphy-and in Taxation Generally ................................ 783 V. SECTION 104(A)(2) AND NONPHYSICAL PERSONAL INJURIES ............................................ 783 A. The 1996 Amendment to Section 104(a)(2) ...............
    [Show full text]
  • Federal Excise Taxes: an Introduction and General Analysis
    Federal Excise Taxes: An Introduction and General Analysis August 26, 2013 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R43189 Federal Excise Taxes: An Introduction and General Analysis Summary There are four common types of excise taxes: (1) sumptuary (or “sin”) taxes, (2) regulatory or environmental taxes, (3) benefit-based taxes (or user charges), and (4) luxury taxes. Sumptuary taxes were traditionally imposed for moral reasons, but are currently rationalized, in part, to discourage a specific activity that is thought to have negative spillover effects (or “externalities”) on society. Regulatory or environmental taxes are imposed to offset external costs associated with regulating public safety or to discourage consumption of a specific commodity that is thought to have negative externalities on society. Benefit-based taxes (which include user charges) are imposed to charge users of a particular public good for financing and maintenance of that public good. Lastly, luxury taxes are primarily imposed as one way to raise revenue, particularly from higher-income households. This report provides an introduction and general analysis of excise taxes. First, a brief history of U.S. excise tax policy is provided. Second, the various forms of excise taxes and their respective administrative advantages and disadvantages are described. Third, the effect of federal excise taxes on federal, state, and local tax revenue is discussed. Fourth, the economic effects of various types of excise taxes are analyzed. The effects on consumer behavior and equity among taxpayers could be important issues for assessment of current excise tax policy or for the design of new excise taxes. Lastly, a list of references to other CRS reports on specific excise taxes is presented.
    [Show full text]
  • U.S. Tax Imperialism in Puerto Rico
    American University Law Review Volume 65 Issue 1 Article 1 2015 U.S. Tax Imperialism in Puerto Rico Diane Lourdes Dick Seattle University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.wcl.american.edu/aulr Part of the Tax Law Commons Recommended Citation Dick, Diane Lourdes (2015) "U.S. Tax Imperialism in Puerto Rico," American University Law Review: Vol. 65 : Iss. 1 , Article 1. Available at: https://digitalcommons.wcl.american.edu/aulr/vol65/iss1/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Washington College of Law Journals & Law Reviews at Digital Commons @ American University Washington College of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in American University Law Review by an authorized editor of Digital Commons @ American University Washington College of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. U.S. Tax Imperialism in Puerto Rico This article is available in American University Law Review: https://digitalcommons.wcl.american.edu/aulr/vol65/ iss1/1 ARTICLES U.S. TAX IMPERIALISM IN PUERTO RICO DIANE LOURDES DICK* This Article uses historical and legal analysis to demonstrate how U.S. domination over Puerto Rico's tax and fiscal policies has been the centerpiece of a colonial system and an especially destructive form of economic imperialism. Specifically, this Article develops a novel theory of U.S. tax imperialism in Puerto Rico, chronicling the sundry ways in which the United States has used tax laws to exert economic dominance over its less developed island colony. During the colonial period, U.S. officials wrote and revised Puerto Rican tax laws to serve U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Looking to the Past in Planning for the Future: Does the Modern Estate Tax Fit Within the Ideals of the Founding Fathers?
    LOOKING TO THE PAST IN PLANNING FOR THE FUTURE: DOES THE MODERN ESTATE TAX FIT WITHIN THE IDEALS OF THE FOUNDING FATHERS? Alica Lerud* I. INTRODUCTION In recent years, the federal estate tax has garnered a great deal of attention from lawmakers, the media, and the general public.' Dubbed the "death tax," the federal estate tax is levied upon estates that exceed a certain value.2 The estate tax has been attacked as being immoral and unfair by opponents.3 Sup- porters of the estate tax have argued that it is essential in the preservation of democracy.4 Regarding this debate, one commentator has said: Never in the course of human taxation has so much furor been generated by so many about a tax that affects so few. While only 2 percent of estates in this country are taxed and account for slightly more than 1 percent of all federal revenues, tempers over the estate tax continue to flare in a strange combustion of moral indignation and 5 economic erudition. Essentially, the estate tax debate has become one of inherent freedoms, societal obligations, and fundamental fairness. The federal estate tax finds its constitutional basis in Article I, Section 8 of the United States Constitution, which reads, "The Congress shall have Power To lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Imposts and Excises, to pay the Debts and provide for the common Defence and general Welfare of the United States."6 * J.D. candidate 2006, University of Nevada, Las Vegas, William S. Boyd School of Law. B.S., University of Nevada, Reno, 2003.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Hot Potato: How Closing Loopholes Can Get Policymakers Cooked Stephanie Mcmahon University of Cincinnati College of Law, [email protected]
    University of Cincinnati College of Law University of Cincinnati College of Law Scholarship and Publications Faculty Articles and Other Publications College of Law Faculty Scholarship 2012 Political Hot Potato: How Closing Loopholes Can Get Policymakers Cooked Stephanie McMahon University of Cincinnati College of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.uc.edu/fac_pubs Part of the Constitutional Law Commons, Law and Politics Commons, Legislation Commons, and the Tax Law Commons Recommended Citation Stephanie Hunter McMahon, Political Hot Potato: How Closing Loopholes Can Get Policymakers Cookd, 37 J. Legis. 141 (2012) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Law Faculty Scholarship at University of Cincinnati College of Law Scholarship and Publications. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Articles and Other Publications by an authorized administrator of University of Cincinnati College of Law Scholarship and Publications. For more information, please contact [email protected]. POLITICAL HOT POTATO: HOW CLOSING LOOPHOLES CAN GET POLICYMAKERS COOKED Stephanie HunterMcMahon* ABSTRACT Loopholes in the law are weaknesses that allow the law to be circumvented Once created, they prove hard to eliminate. A case study of the evolving tax unit used in the federal income tax explores policymakers' response to loopholes. The 1913 income tax created an opportunity for wealthy married couples to shift ownership of family income between spouses, then to file separately, and, as a result, to reduce their collective taxes. In 1948, Congress closed this loophole by extending the income-splitting benefit to all married taxpayers filing jointly.
    [Show full text]
  • James Couzens, Andrew Mellon, the “Greatest Tax Suit in the History of the World,” and Creation of the Joint Committee on Taxation and Its Staff
    NYU/UCLA TAX SYMPOSIUM THE INTERNAL REVENUE CODE AT 100 OCTOBER 19, 2012 James Couzens, Andrew Mellon, the “Greatest Tax Suit in the History of the World,” and Creation of the Joint Committee on Taxation and Its Staff George K. Yin University of Virginia School of Law September 27, 2012 DRAFT Abstract In early 1924, James Couzens was a Republican Senator from Michigan and reportedly the richest member of Congress. Andrew Mellon was beginning his fourth year as Secretary of the Treasury — a service that would eventually span 11 years under three Republican Administrations — and one of the wealthiest persons in the entire country. This article describes how a feud between these two men, an ensuing investigation led by Couzens of the Bureau of Internal Revenue (BIR) (predecessor to the modern‐day IRS), and a tax case against Couzens that was described as the “greatest tax suit in the history of the world,” helped lead to creation of the U.S. Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) and its staff. The events — filled with political intrigue, backstabbing (real or imagined), and unintended consequences — antagonized Congress’s relationship with the executive branch, but improved cooperation between the House and Senate, and both were instrumental in the JCT’s creation. The story also provides insight on the unique role the JCT has played in Congress for over 85 years. Finally, the article explains how creation of the JCT became entangled with two of the most contentious tax issues of the day — the publicity of tax return information and the depletion allowance for oil and gas production — and played a role in changing the law in both areas.
    [Show full text]