Adam Smith and Modern Sociology a Study in the Methodology of the Social Sciences

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Adam Smith and Modern Sociology a Study in the Methodology of the Social Sciences Adam Smith and Modern Sociology A Study in the Methodology of the Social Sciences Albion W. Small [1907] Kitchener 2001 First Edition 1907 (Chicago) This Edition 2001 Batoche Books 52 Eby Street South Kitchener, Ontario N2G 3L1 Canada email: [email protected] Table of Contents Preface............................................................... 5 I. Introduction.......................................................... 6 II. The Sources. ....................................................... 15 III The Economics and Sociology of Labor ................................. 37 IV: The Economics and Sociology of Capital................................. 66 V. Economic vs. Sociological Interpretation of History. ........................ 76 VI: The Problems of Economic and of Sociological Science..................... 79 VII: The Relation of Economic Technology to Other Social Technologies, and to Sociology............................................... 86 VIII Conclusion ....................................................... 96 Notes ............................................................... 97 bb Albion Small, Adam Smith and Modern Sociology, 5 Preface This book is a fragment which I hope will some time find its place in a more complete study of the relations between nineteenth-century social sciences and sociology. The larger investigation is in progress in my seminar, and results are already in sight which justify belief that the work will not be without value. On the purely methodological side, this investigation was stimulated, if not originally suggested, by experiences in connection with the St. Louis Congress of Arts and Science. In all departments of progressive knowledge, the second half of the nineteenth century was unique in its intensive development of scientific analysis. It is not probable that scholars will ever permanently appraise the importance of analysis below their present estimates, but it is certain that we are entering an era of relatively higher appreciation of synthesis. The most distinctive trait of present scholarship is its striving for correlation with all other scholarship. Segregated sciences are becoming discredited sciences. The sociologists are aware that sterility must be the fate of every celibate social science. Cross fertilization of the social sciences occurs in spite of the most obstinate programs of non-intercourse. Commerce of the social sciences with one another should be deliberate, and it should make the policy of isolation disreputable. An objective science of economics without an objective sociology is as impossible as grammar without language. The present essay attempts to enforce this axiom by using Adam Smith as a concrete illustration. On the purely human side, unintelligence or misintelligence about the part that falls respectively to economic and to sociological theory in the conduct of life is a moral misfortune. However quixotic it might be to hope that either of these forms of theory might be popularized to any great extent in the near future, ambition to make economists and sociologists understand each other a little better is not altogether indefensible. Incidentally this book does what it can to offset the harm, more costly to the misled than to the misrepresented, that ill-report has done to economics and economists. The economists who have been written down as procurers to men’s most sordid lusts have been, as a rule, high-minded lovers of their kind. The most abused of them) Smith, Malthus, Ricardo, Mill) devoted themselves to economics partly because they were genuine philanthropists. They set themselves the task of blazing out the path that leads to material prosperity, and of warning as fully as possible against side-tracks that would end in a fool’s paradise. If economic theory has at times tended to take on the character of a shopkeeper’s catechism, and at other times to become a mere calculus of hypothetical conditions, the general fact is not changed, that intelligent conduct of life must always presuppose an adequate science of economics. The economists and the sociologists are studying the real conditions of life from different angles of approach. They are already learning to make use of each other’s methods and results. The investigation of which this book is a partial report is in the interest of a more Albion Small, Adam Smith and Modern Sociology, 6 conscious and systematic partnership. The study in which the book is an initial step starts out with the perception that nineteenth-century economic theory was at bottom an attempt to discover the principles of honorable prudence, not to codify a policy of predatory greed. Economic theory became socially sterile through paresis of its conviction that morality is more than prudence. When we shall have learned to reckon with the accredited results of economic analysis, in genuine correlation with equally reputable results of psychological and sociological analysis, we shall have advanced a stadium of intelligence similar to that which was covered in assimilating the discovery that physical science is not atheism. If we can begin to interpret the progress of the social sciences since Adam Smith as, on the whole, an enlargement and enrichment of the entire area of moral philosophy, in which the preserve of economic theory was the most intensively cultivated field, we shall have done a service for the next generation. We have been seeing these things out of their relations. It is possible to furnish our successors with more accurate clues. A comment upon the table of contents will partially explain the task which the book undertakes as a portion of a larger task to be reported upon in later volumes. Titles III–VII, inclusive, must not be understood as promises of systematic treatment of the material actually within their scope. On the contrary, they are merely formulas for classifying those materials in the parallel portions of The Wealth of Nations, in which the problems of economics and sociology are intertwined. The titles indicate in a general way the large problems of methodology which the corresponding portions of Smith’s treatise implicitly, but not explicitly, raise. The very fact that the discussion under those titles, on the basis of Smith’s own analysis, contains hardly more than a hint of the whole range of problems which the titles now suggest, serves to carry the argument that economic technology, abstracted from the rest of social science, leaves yawning hiatuses in our knowledge. A. W. S. June 10, 1907 I. Introduction. If one were to come upon The Wealth of Nations for the first time, with a knowledge of the general sociological way of looking at society, but with no knowledge of economic literature, there would be not the slightest difficulty nor hesitation about classifying the book as an inquiry in a special field of sociology. Under those circumstances there would be no doubt that the author of the book had a fairly well-defined view, though not in detail the modern view, of the general relations of human society, and of the subordinate place occupied objectively, if not in conventional theory, by the economic section of activities to which the book was devoted. On its first page the reader would get hints of the outlook in the mind of the author, and it would not be hard to construct from those hints a perspective which would contrast very directly with certain points in the view that afterward stole into vogue among classical Albion Small, Adam Smith and Modern Sociology, 7 economists and working capitalists. Sombart1 has made a very strong statement of the fact that the era of modern capitalism differs from earlier industrial epochs in something far deeper than mere methods of doing business. He points out that the dominant motive for doing business has changed. The controlling purpose of modern business is to increase the volume and enlarge the power of capital. Capital for its own sake, and for the social power it confers, is the standard of modern economic life. On the other hand, capital has never been to any great degree an end in itself until the last three centuries, and particularly since the industrial revolution at the end of the eighteenth century. Previous to that time the idea of wealth, in the minds of rich and poor alike, was that it was worth having only to spend. Men wanted wealth because they wanted to consume it, not because they wanted to capitalize it. In other words, their whole philosophy of life, whether it was expressed in their economic actions or in abstract theory, was to the effect that the life was more than the things; that people and their needs were the end-end, while wealth was merely a means-end. Whatever the influence of Adam Smith’s work may have been, one cannot study his philosophy as a whole, even in the fragment of it that has come down to us, without being certain that his basic positions were clearly and positively the human rather than the capitalistic principles. The author of The Wealth of Nations did not assume that the service of capital was the goal of economic activity. On the contrary, he assumed that all economic activity was, as a matter of course, a means of putting people in possession of the means of life.2 Furthermore, to state the same fact in a little different way, Smith assumed that the whole value of economic activities was to be decided by their effects on consumption. That is, instead of putting the production of wealth in the forefront, as the most significant measure of economic processes, he evidently, at least in his fundamental theory, regarded the production of wealth as merely incidental to the consumption of wealth. His whole moral philosophy — or, as we should say today, his sociology — was the ultimate evaluator of all production and consumption; that is, the human process, as it was analyzed and synthesized by moral philosophy, was judged to be the tribunal of last resort for verdict upon the economic process. This has most certainly not been the perspective of nineteenth-century political economy as a whole, so far as England is concerned.
Recommended publications
  • Opportunism in Corporate Management
    Folia Oeconomica Acta Universitatis Lodziensis ISSN 0208-6018 e-ISSN 2353-7663 www.czasopisma.uni.lodz.pl/foe/ 6(345) 2019 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.18778/0208-6018.345.04 Stanisław Rudolf WSB University in Gdańsk, Institute of Management and Finance, Department of Management [email protected] Opportunism in Corporate Management Abstract: A growing interest in the phenomenon of economic opportunism can be mainly explained by new institutional economics (NIE). It has changed the limitation of that phenomenon into the main method of increasing the efficiency of business entities. Opportunistic attitudes and behaviour can be particularly observed in a business entity. A tendency towards opportunism should be considered both while entering contracts and while developing a strategy for a company. The article is aimed at presenting the essence of opportunism and at defining its place in new institutional economics. It is also aimed at identifying opportunistic attitudes in corporate operation and at indicating the ways to limit such attitudes. While analysing the role of opportunism in corporate management, the main focus shall be set on op‑ portunistic interdependencies in corporate governance. Opportunistic attitudes may be presented not only by the management board of a company but also by its other stakeholders. They may use incompleteness of agreements that have been entered into or asymmetry of information in order to increase their gain at the expense of others. The article provides a more detailed analysis of op‑ portunistic attitudes presented by employee organisations in highly developed countries as well as in post‑communist countries, where opportunism is manifested in demanding attitudes or in pro‑ tection of monopolist positions.
    [Show full text]
  • Can Government Think?
    Can Government Think? Climate change, fi nancial crises, and other issues of global scale no longer concern only the developed world. The binding power of globalization has placed these challenges at the doorstep of almost every country, testing the evolutionary capacity of monolithic governance systems burdened by institutional legacy and administrative stagnation. This book locates the concept of adaptive governance, used primarily in environmental management, within the context of economic policy. Introducing fl exible economic opportunism, it argues that a particular style of institutional and administrative versatility enables innovative, evidence- based policy development. This book mines institutional economics, public administration, and research theory and practice for complementary elements that can inform an emerging governance paradigm based on fl exible economic opportunism. Through an eclectic suite of cases from the developing and developed worlds, including Asia and North America, this book reveals how patterns of institutional and adminis- trative change impact the effi cacy of public policy. Flexibility may be this century’s most critical dimension of global competitiveness, and systems confi gured to quickly and comprehensively capture economic opportunities will win the mar- ketplace of development ideas. This book advances that discussion. Kris Hartley is a Singapore-based researcher and consultant focusing on eco- nomic development, public policy, and urbanization. With a decade of public and private sector experience, he has consulted on a variety of topics, including earth- quake recovery, fi nancial regulation, infrastructure asset management, and nuclear energy policy. Working on solutions with high economic and social impact, Kris is currently conducting research about urban revitalization and water resource management in Singapore and Hong Kong, provincial governance and economic competitiveness in Vietnam, and industrial estate development in Thailand.
    [Show full text]
  • Impacts of Market Policy on the Structure of Agriculture 1
    IMPACTS OF MARKET POLICY ON THE STRUCTURE OF AGRICULTURE 1 Dennis R. Henderson Associate Professor and Extension Economist Department of AgriculturalEconomics and Rural Sociology Ohio State University Reasonably astute observers by now are certainly aware that, how agriculture is structured does make a difference. To appease those with the "if it isn't broken, don't fix it" mentality, I will not suggest that it is equally clear how agriculture ought to be struc- tured if (or when) structural modification becomes a public policy objective. I do not propose to discuss the desirability of structural change. Rather, my purpose is to examine the impacts of market policy upon structural change; that is, the relationships between market policy and the structure or organization of agriculture. My emphasis is mainly at the farm level, focusing on market policies for farm products and the structure of the farming industries. The intellectual underpinnings of market policy rest primarily upon industrial organization theory. This theory holds that the way in which industries are structured affects the behavior of firms in their markets, and vice versa, and that both structure and conduct influence performance which is the end result of economic activity by those firms. Market policies can be directed toward both structure and con- duct. However, the direction of causality is not always clear, that is, whether market policy influences, or responds to, market struc- ture and behavior. Probably both. This does not obscure the fact that market policy and industry structure are inexorably inter- related. Structural goals cannot be achieved in the absence of com- patible market policy - otherwise, the marketing system will evolve unguided in response to economic opportunism, technological development, and economic and social power rather than toward a specific target or idealized objective.
    [Show full text]
  • The Flawed Economics of the Dormant Commerce Clause
    William & Mary Law Review Volume 39 (1997-1998) Issue 4 Article 5 April 1998 The Flawed Economics of the Dormant Commerce Clause Paul E. McGreal Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmlr Part of the Constitutional Law Commons Repository Citation Paul E. McGreal, The Flawed Economics of the Dormant Commerce Clause, 39 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 1191 (1998), https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmlr/vol39/iss4/5 Copyright c 1998 by the authors. This article is brought to you by the William & Mary Law School Scholarship Repository. https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmlr THE FLAWED ECONOMICS OF THE DORMANT COMMERCE CLAUSE PAUL E. MCGREAL" Shhh! If you keep very, very quiet, and listen really, really carefully, you just might hear it rustling around underneath the Constitution. Like the sound of a tree falling in a deserted for- est, constitutional law commentators are never sure if it truly exists. And, like people who claim to have seen UFOs, state gov- ernments swear that it exists and is here to conquer them. What is this lurking presence that so perplexes the mind? It is the doctrine of the dormant Commerce Clause, perhaps the Supreme Court's best known invocation of constitutional silence.' And, to continue mxang metaphors, that unseen constitutional doctrine acts like a colorless, odorless toxic gas: a silent killer of state laws affecting interstate commerce. Exactly what is this hideous thing? In short, the dormant Commerce Clause is a constitutional law doctrine that says Congress's power to "regulate Commerce among the several States"2 implicitly restricts state power over the same area.' In * Assistant Professor, Texas A&M Umversity Law Center; LL.M.
    [Show full text]
  • Governing the Patent Commons Dirk Auer and Julian Morris ICLE
    Governing the Patent Commons Dirk Auer and Julian Morris ICLE Intellectual Property & Licensing Research Program White Paper 2019-No. 1 ICLE | 2117 NE Oregon St. Suite 501 | Portland, OR 97232 | 503.770.0076 [email protected] | @laweconcenter | www.laweconcenter.org GOVERNING THE PATENT COMMONS PAGE 2 OF 81 Contents: I. Introduction ..................................................................................................... - 4 - II. The emergence of standards and standards developing organizations................. - 7 - A. Interoperability standards v. quality standards ............................................ - 7 - B. De facto v. de jure standardization ............................................................... - 12 - 1. Competition, network effects and de facto standards ............................ - 13 - 2. De jure standards ................................................................................. - 14 - C. Open v. closed standards ............................................................................ - 16 - D. Incentive compatible institutions and the standard setting process ......... - 18 - III. The case against patent holdup and royalty stacking ........................................ - 20 - A. Holdup theory: from positive to normative economics ............................ - 23 - B. Empirical evidence of holdup and royalty stacking? ................................. - 25 - C. Potential explanations ................................................................................ - 29 - 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Downloaded Into Them
    The European Proceedings of Social and Behavioural Sciences EpSBS www.europeanproceedings.com e-ISSN: 2357-1330 DOI: 10.15405/epsbs.2020.08.128 WUT 2020 10th International Conference “Word, Utterance, Text: Cognitive, Pragmatic and Cultural Aspects” CONTEXT OF THE TERM “OPPORTUNISM” IN ECONOMIC SCIENCE Dmitri Pletnev (a)*, Elena Kozlova (b) *Corresponding author (a) Chelyabinsk State University, 129 Bratiev Kashirinykh St., Chelyabinsk, Russia, [email protected] (b) Chelyabinsk State University, 129 Bratiev Kashirinykh St., Chelyabinsk, Russia, [email protected] Abstract Starting with the breakthrough work of O. Williamson in 1975, opportunism becomes one of the basic concepts used to explain the behavior of individuals in institutional economic science. It defined as "self- interest seeking with guile." Such a vague definition has given rise to a variety of interpretations of opportunism in specific studies. Besides, this term widely used in other social sciences, and the methods for its application are different. The article presents the results of a comparative analysis of the context of the use of the term opportunism in economic science. The differences are justified and clarified just following personal interest and opportunism, taking into account the context of the use of these terms in economics, management, political science, sociology, social psychology, and medicine. Special attention paid to the analysis of the context of using this term in scientific articles in top-ranked journals. This analysis based on searching engines by Social Science Research Network, Web of Science Core Collection and Scopus, using simply and advanced search option. The necessity and possibility of a conventional interpretation of the concept of “opportunism” for a more precise and unambiguous interpretation of the results and the expansion of the possibilities of scientific dialogue justified.
    [Show full text]
  • The Relational Economics of Commercial Contract
    Texas A&M Law Review Volume 3 Issue 1 2015 The Relational Economics of Commercial Contract Chapin F. Cimino Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/lawreview Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Chapin F. Cimino, The Relational Economics of Commercial Contract, 3 Tex. A&M L. Rev. 91 (2015). Available at: https://doi.org/10.37419/LR.V3.I1.4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Texas A&M Law Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Texas A&M Law Review by an authorized editor of Texas A&M Law Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE RELATIONAL ECONOMICS OF COMMERCIAL CONTRACT By: Chapin F. Cimino* TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION .......................................... 91 II. THE DISTINCTIVE PLACE OF RELATIONAL CONTRACT THEORY ................................................ 96 A. Relational Contract Theory’s Grounding in Sociology ........................................... 96 B. Relational Contract Theory Accounts for Both Competition and Cooperation in Exchange.......... 101 III. RELATIONAL BEHAVIORS OPERATIONALIZED .......... 103 A. Transaction Cost Economics and Its Home in the New Institutional Economics ........................ 104 B. Modeling Cooperative Norms and Their Effects on Opportunism ........................................ 108 C. Modeling for Background Social Context of Trust and Prior Relational Ties ........................... 115 IV. RESEARCH IMPLICATIONS ............................... 119 A. Taking the Institutional
    [Show full text]
  • Lexical Opportunism and the Limits of Contract Theory
    University of Cincinnati Law Review Volume 84 Issue 1 Article 5 April 2018 Lexical Opportunism and the Limits of Contract Theory Jeffrey M. Lipshaw Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.uc.edu/uclr Recommended Citation Jeffrey M. Lipshaw, Lexical Opportunism and the Limits of Contract Theory, 84 U. Cin. L. Rev. (2018) Available at: https://scholarship.law.uc.edu/uclr/vol84/iss1/5 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by University of Cincinnati College of Law Scholarship and Publications. It has been accepted for inclusion in University of Cincinnati Law Review by an authorized editor of University of Cincinnati College of Law Scholarship and Publications. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Lipshaw: Lexical Opportunism and the Limits of Contract Theory LEXICAL OPPORTUNISM AND THE LIMITS OF CONTRACT THEORY* Jeffrey M Lipshaw Abstract This essay is a reflection on the gap between the real- life practice of contract law and some of the academic theory that tries to explain it. I describe "lexical opportunism," an aspect of contract practice having three elements. First, the parties must have reduced a complex business arrangement to contractual text, portions of which text are as devoid of thoughtful drafting or close negotiation as the boilerplate in a consumer contract. Second, an adversary cleverly develops a legal theory based upon a colorable interpretationof that text. Third, this interpretation creates a potential for staggeringliability beyond all common sense. A multi-billion
    [Show full text]
  • The Inevitability of the Transition from a Surveillance-Society to a Veillance-Society: Moral and Economic Grounding for Sousveillance
    The inevitability of the transition from a surveillance-society to a veillance-society: Moral and economic grounding for sousveillance Mir Adnan Ali and Steve Mann Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering University of Toronto, 10 Kings College Rd, Toronto, ON, CANADA Abstract—Surveillance is a French word that means “to watch C. Specific definition of surveillance and sousveillance in the from above” (e.g. guards watching prisoners, police watching context of this work citizens, etc.). Another form of veillance (watching) is sousveil- lance, which means “to watch from below”. Whereas surveillance In the present analysis, we select a particular meaning to often means cameras on large entities (e.g. buildings and land), focus on the social, and consequently informational, asymme- sousveillance often means cameras on small entities (e.g. indi- tries of parties involved in veillance. As adjectives, these words vidual people). The importance of sousveillance has come to the are indicative of the properties of the object they describe. forefront recently with advancements in wearable computing and However, the use of the adjective does not imply that the AR (augmented or augmediated reality). We characterize sousveillance from both an economic and object so described can only be used to accomplish the action moral perspective. We argue that societies that reject sousveil- indicated by the verbal form – in other words, a “surveillance lance will be impoverished, relative to those accepting sousveil- camera” can be used for sousveillance, and vice versa. The lance. We further argue that sousveillance as a form of social meaning of interest here is the verbal form, where veillance action has positive survival characteristics, so that in the long is conscious action.
    [Show full text]
  • (Urban and Regional Planning) in the University of Michigan 2015
    Risk, Rationality, and Regional Governance by Thomas S. Skuzinski A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy (Urban and Regional Planning) in the University of Michigan 2015 Doctoral Committee: Associate Professor Scott D. Campbell, Chair Professor Elisabeth R. Gerber Professor Jonathan Levine Associate Professor Richard K. Norton Acknowledgements As with any project completed over many years and hundreds of hours, a dissertation requires a great deal of practical assistance and an even greater measure of emotional support and patience. I was fortunate to have both from many people. First, I acknowledge the investments of my committee members. Elisabeth Gerber: I can say, without exaggeration, this dissertation would have never been written and my doctoral degree never earned without your constant support. Whatever positive reputation I have as a scholar and teacher in the future will be directly attributable to your confidence in my abilities, your sound advice, your probing questions and comments, and your own work ethic. You are truly a mentor. Scott Campbell, the chair of my committee, a constant presence in my academic life the last eight years, and an unfailingly genial man: You always knew how to push my thinking in new and better directions. I felt you always treated me as a colleague and not as a student, and that is a rare trait to find in a professor. Jonathan Levine: I remember almost a decade ago when your wife Noga, one of my law professors, suggested I consider graduate studies in planning. What a fortunate and impactful conversation! You were the first planning scholar I met and the first whose work I read, and despite never formally being a student in one of your classes the clarity and rigor of your scholarship has taught me a great deal already.
    [Show full text]
  • Shirking and Sharking: a Legal Theory of the Firm
    Shirking and Sharking: A Legal Theory of the Firm Eric W. Ortst Introduction ................................................................................................... 266 I. Agency Law and Agency Costs ............................................................... 270 A. Legal Agency: Authority, Power, and Hierarchy in the Firm ..... 271 B. Agency Costs: Classical Shirking .................................................... 275 II. Principal C osts .......................................................................................... 278 A. Sharking Defined: Opportunism of Principals Within Firms ...... 279 B. Agency Chains: Quasi-Principals and Superior Agents ............... 280 III. Firm s and M arkets ................................................................................. 282 A. The Paradox of Methodological Individualism ............................. 283 B. Consumer Markets and Organizational Metamarkets ................. 286 IV. Economic Theories of the Firm ........................................................... 289 A .Transaction Costs ............................................................................. 289 B . C ontracts ............................................................................................ 291 C . Property .............................................................................................. 295 D . Em ploym ent ...................................................................................... 296 V. A Legal Theory of the Firm and Its Boundaries .................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Prevention of White-Collar Crime in the Food Sector. an Interdisciplinary Applied Research Approach
    HUMBOLDT-UNIVERSITÄT ZU BERLIN Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften an der Landwirtschaftlich- Gärtnerischen Fakultät Nr. 76/2006 Norbert Hirschauer Stefan Zwoll Understanding and Managing Behavioural Risks – The Case of Food Risks Caused by Malpractice WORKING PAPER in Poultry Production Luisenstraße 56, D - 10099 Berlin (Mitte), Germany tel.:+(49)-30- 2093 6317; fax:+(49)-30- 2093 6474 Working Paper Nr. 76/2006: Department of Agricultural Economics and Social Sciences, Humboldt-University of Berlin Understanding and Managing Behavioural Risks – The Case of Food Risks Caused by Malpractice in Poultry Production1 Norbert Hirschauer* and Stefan Zwoll, Humboldt-University of Berlin Abstract: The probability that actors in economic relationships break rules increases with the profits they thus expect to earn. It decreases with the probability and level of short- and long- term losses resulting from disclosure. It also decreases with the level of social context factors and intrinsic values which shield actors from yielding to economic temptations. This paper assesses the relative merits of various scientific approaches concerned with risks in economic relationships and outlines their contribution to the study of opportunistic rule-breaking. Since the identification of (misdirected) economic incentives faced by firms and individuals repre- sents the starting point for a systematic analysis of opportunism in any field, we also outline a microeconomic approach that systematically provides this crucial information. The approach is applied to
    [Show full text]