Can Government Think?

Climate change, fi nancial crises, and other issues of global scale no longer concern only the developed world. The binding power of globalization has placed these challenges at the doorstep of almost every country, testing the evolutionary capacity of monolithic governance systems burdened by institutional legacy and administrative stagnation. This book locates the concept of adaptive governance, used primarily in environmental management, within the context of economic policy. Introducing fl exible economic , it argues that a particular style of institutional and administrative versatility enables innovative, evidence- based policy development. This book mines , public administration, and research theory and practice for complementary elements that can inform an emerging governance paradigm based on fl exible economic opportunism. Through an eclectic suite of cases from the developing and developed worlds, including Asia and North America, this book reveals how patterns of institutional and adminis- trative change impact the effi cacy of public policy. Flexibility may be this century’s most critical dimension of global competitiveness, and systems confi gured to quickly and comprehensively capture economic opportunities will win the mar- ketplace of development ideas. This book advances that discussion.

Kris Hartley is a Singapore-based researcher and consultant focusing on eco- nomic development, public policy, and urbanization. With a decade of public and private sector experience, he has consulted on a variety of topics, including earth- quake recovery, fi nancial regulation, infrastructure asset management, and nuclear energy policy. Working on solutions with high economic and social impact, Kris is currently conducting research about urban revitalization and water resource management in Singapore and Hong Kong, provincial governance and economic competitiveness in Vietnam, and industrial estate development in Thailand. This page intentionally left blank Can Government Think? Flexible economic opportunism and the pursuit of global competitiveness

Kris Hartley First published 2015 by Routledge 2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN and by Routledge 711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017 Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business © 2015 Kris Hartley The right of Kris Hartley to be identifi ed as author of this work has been asserted by him in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patent Act 1988. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilized in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers. Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered trademarks, and are used only for identifi cation and explanation without intent to infringe. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Hartley, Kris. Can government think? : fl exible economic opportunism and the pursuit of global competitiveness / Kris Hartley. pages cm Includes bibliographical references and index. 1. Economic policy. 2. Economic development—Planning. 3. Institutional economics. 4. Public administration. I. Title. HD87.H367 2015 338.6′048—dc23 2014019285 ISBN: 978-1-138-78275-4 (hbk) ISBN: 978-1-315-74467-4 (ebk)

Typeset in Galliard by Apex CoVantage, LLC Contents

Introduction 1

PART I Institutions

1 Understanding institutions 15 2 Institutions in research and practice 26 3 Institutions and economic development 36 4 Institutions and political power 51 5 Institutions and global urbanization 64

PART II Public administration

6 Contrasting administration paradigms: traditional bureaucracy and collaborative governance 81 7 Emerging administration paradigms: from neoclassical to postmodern 94 8 Local and national administration 108

PART III Evidence-based policy

9 Foundational thinkers in epistemology 123 10 Research methods and empirical validity 134 vi Contents 11 Use of evidence in environmental regulation 144 12 Nationalizing benefi ts and localizing costs in industrial development 161 13 Evidence-based intervention for housing markets 174

Conclusion 189 Bibliography 197 Index 217 Introduction

Government is back, for now. The “great recession” has exposed the weaknesses of a free-market purism that trivializes the role of the state. However, economic cyclicality guarantees that the private sector will eventually regain its swagger – presumably until the next crisis. Political quarrels about public-private balance can be productive but are also increasingly destructive. For example, the American government shutdown of 2013 showed how costly domestic policy stalemates can be, especially when ideological tribalism outshouts evidence. Is there a better way? Can economic policy respond to opportunity by shifting orientation from market to state, and back, without the political noise? Can a new governance model accommodate divergent ideologies without being destructively revolution- ary or rigidly orthodox? Innovative and pragmatic governance has the potential to transcend these costly battles. Interactions among government bodies, institutions, the private sector, and civil society can be structured to avoid slow and even counterproduc- tive policy processes. To that end, this book introduces the concept of fl exible economic opportunism, a governance model for theory and practice that empha- sizes adaptability and pragmatism over ideology and patronage. It advocates timely accommodation of global economic trends, enabled by a structural orien- tation towards economic competitiveness and policy pragmatism. The model’s fundamental proposition is that supportive institutional and administrative condi- tions can nurture an environment where evidence guides policy and innovation drives governance. As such, fl exible economic opportunism is not a belief system or a normative philosophy but a systemic architecture that most effi ciently accom- modates the will of the state – as expressed through any number of different political systems – while maximizing competitive potential. Globalization has brought the tug-of-war between market and state to all cor- ners of the world. At the doorstep of any liberalizing economy now lies a Pan- dora’s box of mutually confl icting policy challenges concerning corporate infl uence, social welfare, and ecological sustainability. Narratives that emphasize statist models fi ercely compete against those advocating free markets for the pol- icy attention of governments in both developing and developed countries. Failure of market or state – a recession or a government debt crisis – is often accompanied by a cacophony of interest-driven punditry and pseudo-scientifi c fl imfl am about 2 Introduction which model to embrace. In many cases, alarmed impulsiveness compels govern- ments to jerk the steering wheel left or right to avoid political fallout of further economic damage, resulting in a momentary policy shift towards the subdomi- nant model. However, the new policy may be reversed soon thereafter, often during the next crisis or administration, and the result is a near-permanent state of policy disequilibrium as economic and political cycles rarely overlap. This inces- sant push and pull – resembling a dog watching tennis – destabilizes markets and creates investor uncertainty that in turn magnifi es crises, generating an economi- cally fatal feedback loop. The post-partisan approach of fl exible economic oppor- tunism does not prescribe a universal policy or model. Rather, it establishes the conditions for existing governance structures to adapt more quickly to economic cycles that are becoming shorter and more severe. This pragmatic, reform-minded approach values institutional fl exibility, innovative governance, and a robust focus on evidence. The value of the concept is its neutrality; embracing the spectrum of political and economic systems, it remains silent about seemingly irreconcilable debates over representation, wealth distribution, and the appropriate scope of government authority. Flexible economic opportunism has academic roots in common-pool resource management and institutional economics. Adaptive governance has typically addressed issues such as agricultural sustainability and water scarcity. Flexible eco- nomic opportunism imports adaptive governance into administrative design and applies it to a broad range of economic, political, and social issues. The connec- tion between fl exible economic opportunism and adaptive governance rests on the argument that the economic opportunities generated by globalization exhibit some characteristics of a common-pool resource—namely, the diffi culty of exclud- ing users and the zero-sum outcome. For example, many countries have access to borderless consumer markets through globalization, but internal structural con- straints often impede the development or implementation of innovative strategies to exploit economic opportunities. Furthermore, countries must compete in a global market for capital that is almost always growing but nonetheless fi nite and subject to wide fl uctuations in price. The competitive environment can therefore be described as a collective “free-for-all,” something to which all parties aspire but fewer succeed. States pursue their own interest within an implicitly coordinated if ineffi cient global capitalist system, generating economic outcomes that benefi t the prepared. Adaptive governance applies to environmental systems that are complex, multi-faceted, and highly sensitive; fl exible economic opportunism is a form of adaptive governance for the rest of society. It manages economic, politi- cal, and social uncertainty through governance structures that not only withstand change but leverage it. The concept of fl exible economic opportunism stands on its own foundation as a contribution to the study and practice of governance and public administra- tion. Specifi cally, the model carries its application of adaptive governance towards theoretical frontiers in three ways. First, its models are applicable in a variety of governance environments, from multi-level to central. Adaptive governance largely addresses problems of environmental complexity, uncertainty, and change Introduction 3 within governance structures that are highly fragmented and often informal and weakly institutionalized. Highly centralized governments that lack the fragmenta- tion of more democratized societies must nevertheless cope with emerging global economic forces and may actually be better suited to capture growth opportuni- ties from them. Flexible economic opportunism is therefore more universally applicable because it focuses on restructuring economic policy development pro- cesses without regard to incumbent political or social structures. This extends the discussion beyond institutional reform prescriptions and into the realm of evidence-based policymaking and administrative capacity and fl exibility. Second, while the nature of the issues addressed by fl exible economic opportunism and adaptive governance are similar, the critical difference lies in the “laws” governing the operating arena. They are observable and somewhat predictable in one (the natural environment) but often imperceptible and unpredictable in the other (international economic and diplomatic relationships). The rate of change is also greater in the latter, necessitating a rapid fl exibility often labeled “footloose” in reference to private enterprises. This distinction allows fl exible economic oppor- tunism to explore uncharted theoretical space in proposing a new logic for gov- ernance strategy and institutional design. In this manner, it argues that governance models should be equipped to manage the paradoxical combination of predict- able and irrational behavior found in capital markets, central banks, and diplo- matic ministries. Finally, the very terms describing adaptive governance and fl exible economic opportunism underscore their fundamental differences. Adap- tive is reactive. Environmental management prescriptions rightly argue that sys- tems should be sensitive to the emerging impacts of climate change at both the global and the local levels. A tone of preparation and defense fl avors discussions about and applications of adaptive governance principles. In contrast, opportun- ism is proactive. It surveys the landscape of economic possibilities and fl exibly calibrates strategies based on varying appetites for risk and return, at the indi- vidual or governmental level. Flexible economic opportunism is not defensive, and its practitioners would not operate as though hopelessly besieged by uncon- trollable forces such as globalization, climate change, and socio-political transfor- mation. A spirit of self-determinism pervades the model, and this entrepreneurial tone can speak meaningfully to the world’s most successful investors and icono- clastic thinkers. Governments sharing this spirit are not enslaved to philosophies of protective isolationism but liberated by those of measured, prudent economic enterprise. This attitude suits the challenges of managing of rapidly growing economies. In addition to extending the concept of adaptive governance, fl exible economic opportunism is built on a novel application of post-Fordist fl exible specialization, applying the fi rm-level concept to systems for public provision, governance, and management. In academia, fl exible specialization emerged from critiques about post-WWII industrial systems based on mass production and com- modifi cation. The new model emphasized differentiation, adaptive capacity, and institutionalized innovation within fi rms, all hallmarks of fl exible economic opportunism through its embodiment in governance systems. Economic plan- ning initiatives targeting and coordinating these types of industries at the policy 4 Introduction level must be equally fl exible in their own right. Distinctions between adaptive governance and fl exible economic opportunism have methodological implica- tions for how economic policymaking processes are studied, particularly with reference to the ambitions and cognitive processes of leaders, administrators, and collaborators. In an applied sense, this paradigmatic novelty represents an evolu- tion in the strategy of adaptability from defensive to opportunistic, shield to bayonet. While fl exible economic opportunism attempts to make robust, defensible claims about the benefi ts of adaptive economic governance systems, it is careful not to embrace universality. Indeed, the concept of one-size approach is antitheti- cal to the spirit of adaptability. Nevertheless, universality is as alluring to scholars and practitioners as it was for the ancient Greek politicians who came to the Oracle at Delphi for predictions about matters such as the outcomes of military campaigns or the fortunes of commercial ventures. The allure of the Oracle is understandable. Defi nitive answers invite a comfortable resignation to fate. They are also frequently wrong. Indeed, both positive and normative research approaches are beholden to the pursuit of universality. The former assumes an objective and attainable truth; the latter, a “proper” way of using truth to achieve agenda-specifi c outcomes. While recent global political and economic punditry blends these approaches through corkscrew logic and self-evident rhetoric to sup- port ideologies, the chase for silver-bullet answers continues to occupy the world’s most brilliant minds. Yet the global situation seems to be more uncertain and inscrutable than ever, especially with regard to economic, social, and political stability. Has universality failed the realm of governance reform? The most critical aspect of fl exible economic opportunism is its avoidance of a prescriptive tone, eluding the rigidity of theoretical models that claim universality. The fi eld of policy studies continues to wrestle with a variety of philosophical approaches and practical models to address governance failures. The scholarly grist in the mill has yielded many groundbreaking fi ndings, but the lure of appli- cative universality has often cheapened them by understating their context- specifi city or diluting fundamental elements of their conceptual novelty. Research in the fi elds of economics, sociology, and philosophy also occasionally surrenders to the temptation of universality. Such research often produces conclusions that are useful in discrete cases but disjointed in aggregate, as they often incompletely explain the root causes of policy and governance failures. In short, universality and its economic cousin, catch-all neoliberal systemic reform, provide solutions that lack either effi cacy or feasibility. Therefore, the study and practice of policy sciences, like other social sciences, must settle for theoretical gains that are incre- mental and for policy outcomes that are diffi cult to measure and often attributable only to a serendipitous convergence of circumstances in which policymakers have – as often by accident as by design – “gotten it right.” Cases of dumb luck fre- quently form the basis of studies that are either too contextualized or too general to be of much value and are rarely replicable. Perhaps social science has too often borrowed the wrench of hard science when the problem fails to resemble a bolt. Perhaps universal laws are more appropriate for the medical laboratory than the Introduction 5 urban slum. If social science can be measured by its ability to generate progress in basic human development such as social mobility and poverty alleviation, then the current state of the fi eld bears some much-needed contemplation. Universality is failing because such models neither explain nor predict systems whose origins are incompletely understood. Applications of universality rely to some degree on the assumption that systems share initial characteristics, but in explaining complex social and economic issues this assumption rarely holds. For example, the neoliberal research agenda points to an increase in the overall global standard of living, insisting that comparisons of median wealth to those of the super-elite are irrelevant because a rising tide has lifted all ships. However, the tide, by some measurements, has experienced increasingly wide fl uctuations with a net slackening for a majority of ships. It also harbors lethal environmental patho- gens. Does policy research have the tools to isolate the causes of this problem, and the credibility to peddle sustainable, context-based solutions? In regard to the former, the valuable but controversial research of economists like Thomas Piketty is bringing discussions about the socio-political impact of wealth accumulation out of the academic ivory tower and into the media, government, and living rooms. Nevertheless, the credibility of unorthodox, iconoclastic research has room to develop. Isolated examples of dartboard policymaking informed either by prevailing ideological forces or by falsely urgent circumstantial mandates (e.g., fi scal cliffs) are not a sound basis for the next generation of policy science and economic research. The concept of fl exible economic opportunism, while acknowledging its own limitations, is an attempt to dislodge old patterns of think- ing and foment a minor revolution in how government and the academy approach persistent policy challenges regarding governance systems, global markets, and individual economic opportunity. Given the irreplicability of dartboard economic success stories, a comprehen- sive understanding of what constitutes effective policy can emerge only from systematic, disciplined, and ideologically neutral research. The way forward can include either a continuation of the lumpy and incidental “progress” resulting from a cacophony of incompatible scholarly proposals or a radical redefi nition and remediation of the problem based on the diagnostic power of a new model. This book proposes the latter. At its heart, fl exible economic opportunism is predi- cated on the notion that an unpredictable and wildly un-modelable global econ- omy embodies the characteristics of fallible, irrational individuals. This is not intended to highlight the role of organizational psychology and related fi elds, although they have peripheral value in this discussion. This instead is a call to researchers, analysts, public intellectuals, and policymakers to end the counter- productive obsession with universality. Even the most robustly tested economic models often fail to explain or generate anticipated outcomes, with the blame conveniently ascribed to faulty implementation. One universal model cannot sim- ply be replaced with another, and such a strategy would miss the point regardless. This book serves only to support the case that modern governance should reject failed patterns of thinking that have often captivated academia and practice with disappointing results. Flexibility and adaptability are the hearthstone of this 6 Introduction model, not as momentary strategies, but as fundamental characteristics of good governance. Flexible economic opportunism – with or without the label – is emerging as a coherent development model in some government bodies, both local and trans- national in scale. The most illustrative examples are in cities that have endured both external economic shock events and systemic restructuring. Size and diver- sifi cation do not necessarily defi ne these cases. With large and complex economic bases, cities like New York, Tokyo, and London are predictably fl exible. It is within the world’s “secondary” cities – those that exist in the shadow of their boisterous older siblings – that fl exible economic opportunism can truly be observed while controlling for size and diversifi cation. Cities such as Austin, Bris- bane, and Chongqing are asserting themselves in the global economic environ- ment through creative opportunism liberated from the shackles of administrative rigidity. In short, these players are fast and footloose. However, studying such dimensions of governance is not without challenges. The impacts of innovative policy must be isolated from those of path dependence, situational advantages, or happy accident, especially when considering the (currently) few cases that seem to best exhibit the concept. Many studies document how diversifi ed and fl exible certain urban economies are and abundantly describe their many fortuitous his- toric turns. However, studying fl exible economic opportunism requires an under- standing of how institutions – principally those built and supported by government – have enabled such paths. The approach can therefore be thought of as “planned path dependence,” with multiple forks anticipated and evaluated by broad-reaching and visionary policies. In studying fl exible economic opportunism, it is also useful to typologize cases that have embraced it. For example, the trade-driven cultural exchange in port cities often engenders an outward orientation and open social and economic environment that fosters creativity and network develop- ment. Teasing out the policy element of this phenomenon is one challenge con- fronted by this book in its efforts to reveal the critical elements of fl exible economic opportunism. This book is organized along the three fi elds of study that in combination pro- vide theoretical support for fl exible economic opportunism: institutional econom- ics, public administration, and evidence-based policymaking. This ordering funnels breadth of agency: the fi rst of norms defi ning civil society, the second of offi cial- dom, and the third of empirical research and democratization of information. This topical format allows lingering questions about the public-private balance in a post–Washington Consensus world to be visited in the many contexts where gov- ernance and society interoperate. It achieves this by situating the discussion of fl exibility among the mutually dependent layers of policymaking and execution whose contributions are each critical to effective economic governance. Institutions are a critical starting point for understanding fl exible economic opportunism. In determining formal and informal norms – often called “the rules of the game” – institutions provide a bedrock context on which theories of public administration and evidence-based policymaking can be enriched. Chapter 1 outlines the defi nition of institutions and their relevance to the concept of Introduction 7 fl exible economic opportunism, their role in generating economic outcomes, their inter-relationships in differing contexts, and their challenges as a unit of analysis. Comparing the contributions of institutional economists such as Ostrom, Coase, and North, this chapter explores the problem of defi nitional ambiguity in conceptualizing institutions and describes how scholars treat institutional func- tions such as market facilitation, actor agency, and policymaking. Both economic and social implications are examined. This chapter continues by critiquing varying issues of concern to institutional economics, including property rights, social con- tracts, and confl icts of interest. It also applies an analytical framework from clas- sical music (Schoenbergian Grundgestalt ) to analyze the historic development of market-facilitating institutions. economics is also applied to insti- tutional studies in a way that underscores the value of fl exible economic opportunism. Chapter 2 begins by comparing institutional analysis methodologies, with a special focus on their application to fl exible economic opportunism. It explores scholarly contributions that illuminate useful approaches for studying institutions and applies some of the more salient concepts to economic growth in Asia’s devel- oping countries. Next, complementarities among several major institutional ana- lytical approaches are identifi ed, including a critique of the logic, methodology, and conceptualization of institutions that underlie each. The contributions of these approaches to fl exible economic opportunism are outlined and provide the basis for later discussions in this book about the broader role of institutions in economic governance. The concept of analytic narratives as a research methodol- ogy is then explored through an applied example of international relations between the United States and China. The chapter concludes with a brief explora- tion of other institutional frameworks, drawing applied comparisons using the governance dynamics of infrastructure development in New Zealand. Themes from this comparison of research methodologies reappear in subsequent chapters and inform the book’s approach to analyzing fl exible economic opportunism. Chapter 3 is the fi rst in a series of three examining the applied dimension of institutions and fl exible economic opportunism through case studies. It fi rst establishes a scholarly context for economic clustering, institutional relation- ships, and management structures. The chapter then applies theory to explain the development and performance of industrial estates, why clustering occurs where it does, and what accounts for successful economic growth. This includes institutional factors, political priorities, geographical endowments, and social dynamics. The chapter continues with an analysis of actor relationships, focusing on how formal and informal structures facilitate or obstruct clustering; a multi- plicity of actors is considered, including social and business networks. Finally, the chapter addresses institutionalized management structures in industrial estates, exploring models of fl exible operational control involving a mix of public and private actors collaborating through partnerships. The illustrative case is an industrial estate in Thailand whose successes and failures present opportunities to examine and evaluate institutional structures within the context of fl exible economic opportunism. 8 Introduction Chapter 4 examines social housing in New Zealand as a stage for institutional dynamics and political power. It begins with a background of the current and projected state of social housing demand in New Zealand and situates emerging challenges in their historic, economic, social, and institutional contexts. Exploring policy evolution, demographics, and urban growth imperatives, this chapter then describes the degree to which challenges are recognized and addressed within a multi-layered and ideologically fragmented governance environment, giving effect to the principles of fl exible economic opportunism outlined in this book. Next, the chapter reviews the strategic priorities of relevant actors, including the national social housing provider and its complicated relationship with both local and central government. The chapter concludes with an analysis of political and operational constraints to policy implementation, with recommendations relating to both urban spatial planning and governance design. Chapter 5 examines the institutional dimension of cities, providing a context for how fl exible economic opportunism can inform policies at sub-national, regional, and local levels of governance. It begins with a brief account of how urban policy has been an instrument of colonial settlement, with examples from ancient Rome, British India, and French Africa. The argument is that urban plan- ning has supported political efforts throughout history and continues to do so, with a modern example being Kabul, Afghanistan. The chapter proceeds by addressing the impact of technological and economic forces on urban transforma- tion, with a focus on the institutional aspects of communications infrastructure and property development. Next, neoliberalism is critiqued for its association with economic inequality in emerging “global” cities. This includes an analysis of theoretical critiques related to urban redevelopment and its socio-spatial implica- tions, underscoring how fl exible economic opportunism, as a tool rather than an ideology, can be used for purposes that do not always serve the greater societal interest. The chapter integrates a broad realm of literature, including institutional economics, urban sociology, and public administration, organized around the forces of globalization and competitiveness, their impacts on social welfare, and the reinterpretation of neoliberal reform movements in Asian cities. Chapter 6 is the fi rst of two chapters outlining the principal concepts of public administration and their relationship to fl exible economic opportunism, a critical exercise in supporting the argument that fl exible economic opportunism is appli- cable across governance models. This chapter compares two paradigms at oppo- site ends of the democratic continuum. The fi rst of these is traditional public administration, which this chapter explores through the works of and Woodrow Wilson. Dichotomies within the traditional public administration paradigm are examined, including bureaucratic motivation and the politics- administration divide. Next, theories about human behavior and meritocratic governance are briefl y outlined. The fi rst part of this chapter concludes by analyz- ing debates about traditional public administration, identifying its relevance to economic governance and critiquing how the paradigm has interacted with rival schools of thought. The second part of this chapter examines literature about collaborative management. It begins with a review of salient theories, including Introduction 9 responsiveness, partnership, and managerial practice. The chapter continues with a critique and identifi es potential conceptual directions. It concludes with a com- parative analysis of both paradigms, deriving theoretical insights from their con- trasts that enhance the understanding of fl exible economic opportunism. Chapter 7 outlines, critiques, and compares three salient public administra- tion paradigms that exhibit characteristics of larger social and economic move- ments. The fi rst section explores New Public Management, describing its characteristics, reform frameworks, and relevance to fl exible economic oppor- tunism. The chapter continues with an examination of International Public Management, outlining its traits and establishing its conceptual distinction from New Public Management. Identifying the role of International Public Manage- ment in globalization, this chapter describes the emergence of private sector and non-government actors in global governance processes. The chapter then exam- ines Postmodern Public Administration, its inherent logic, and its conceptual and methodological themes including individualism and power relations. This chapter concludes, as did the previous, by comparing paradigms and anticipat- ing future trends. With the previous chapters having established the critical link between fl exible economic opportunism and public administration, Chapter 8 examines a group of cases illustrating the complexity of conceptualizing and implementing public administration paradigms. The fi rst part examines the local context. Cases include an industrial estate development in Thailand where a bureaucratic administrative structure is used to manage pollution, a community redevelopment initiative in California that involves government and grassroots advocacy groups, and a col- laborative crisis management program for New Zealand’s earthquake recovery effort. Each is treated in a way that highlights characteristics of fl exible economic opportunism proposed in this book. The second part of the chapter focuses on national-level economic development, examining how market-enabling adminis- tration paradigms have been adapted to accommodate contextual variations and support developmental objectives in Taiwan, Japan, China, and Myanmar. Each case embodies a specifi c paradigm, and a summary section derives common les- sons for fl exible economic opportunism. Chapter 9, the fi rst of fi ve examining evidence-based policy, establishes a theo- retical foundation to identify the critical role of research and creation of new knowledge to fl exible economic opportunism. It begins by outlining the contribu- tions of major epistemological thinkers on issues including positive and normative economic research, application of research methodologies, the value of economic models, and interactive epistemology. The chapter then traces the development of economic research through the twentieth century and concludes with critiques about epistemic approaches and their application to modern research topics and challenges. The second part of the chapter addresses research design, including the bridge between theoretical and practical elements. It also describes the fundamen- tal characteristics of quantitative and qualitative research, reviewing debates about their comparative usefulness in both isolation and combination. This chapter con- cludes by underscoring the importance of contextual familiarity and the benefi ts 10 Introduction of using mixed-methods research approaches to the type of evidence-based poli- cymaking that informs fl exible economic opportunism. Chapter 10 synthesizes a variety of approaches to research methods and exam- ines measures to ensure the legitimacy and defensibility of empirical claims. It describes three salient issues in research methods – model design, variable selec- tion, and interpretation – and examines each through a comparative analysis of how selected authors treat them. The chapter continues with a general critique of two methods in practice: Belich’s study of frontier development and Bound and Solon’s study of monozygotic twins. The second part of the chapter focuses on methods to address empirical validity and reliability, including testing and verifi ca- tion. The chapter concludes with a brief illustration of validity and reliability issues in comparative research about Thailand and Indonesia. The fi rst of three remaining chapters addressing the applied use of evidence and research in policymaking, Chapter 11 begins with an elementary description of the technical aspects of hydraulic fracturing (fracking), including a brief history, evolution of mechanical techniques, geographical patterns of practice, and antici- pated developments. Next, it outlines common debates about fracking, including environmental and public health concerns such as water table and surface con- tamination, air quality reduction, and waste management. This chapter concludes with an analysis of evidence-based fracking policy development, including an overview of various approaches around the world, the infl uence of public action on fracking policy, a comparative analysis from the United States and New Zea- land, and a synthesis of lessons with broader energy policy relevance. The fi ndings illustrate the aspects of evidence-based policymaking that can be broadly applied to issues of economic development. Chapter 12 examines how economic research and associated practical knowl- edge can inform industrial management systems and development policies with a focus on fl exible economic opportunism. This chapter argues that the socio-spatial imbalance of benefi ts and costs resulting from industrial growth in many developing countries is not adequately remediated by either the private or the public sector, constituting a tripartite failure of market, government, and infor- mation. It is at the intersection of these three that fl exible economic opportunism makes its principal contribution. The chapter describes specifi c failures relevant to the case of Thailand industrial estates and describes how research can both explain and help remediate these failures. It concludes with policy recommendations based on evidence and best practices. Chapter 13 examines housing affordability, with a focus on institutional expla- nations and policy interventions. It exhibits how fl exible economic opportunism is a concept applicable not only to external opportunities but to domestic policy challenges. The chapter fi rst reviews inclusionary zoning from a perspective, identifying the prevalence of free-market strategies in innovative intervention models. Next, the chapter examines public housing as a merit good, tracing the rise and demise of affordability programs and analyzing policy changes that refl ect political sensitivity and institutional change. Examples from the United States, Singapore, and Hong Kong are compared. The chapter continues with a Introduction 11 study of housing subsidies in America and advocates for institutional and regula- tory reform in the mortgage market. The chapter concludes with several policy recommendations that relate to institutional reform and fl exible governance, arguing that nationalizing the brokerage industry is crucial for fi nancial sector stability and housing market recovery. This chapter exhibits the potential of fl ex- ible economic opportunism to respond to market failures as well as global forces. Synthesizing the salient points of the book, the conclusion focuses on how adaptable institutional design and public administration create an environment where innovative capacity and evidence-based policymaking enhance a country’s global competitiveness. Introducing the concept of a constraint theory of gover- nance, the conclusion argues that fl exible economic opportunism is the vehicle through which this process is actualized. It proposes a systematic structure for conceptualizing fl exible economic opportunism and focuses in detail on how institutional, administrative, and empirical dimensions are operationalized. Situat- ing the book’s claims within the context of current global economic, political, and social trends, the conclusion draws to a close by calling for more assertive reform action from government, society, and academia. This book aims to contribute to the continuing dialogue among scholars, prac- titioners, and students about the effi cacy of economic governance models, meth- ods of analyzing them, and innovative and productive approaches to reforming them. This book also expects to generate a new dialogue about post-partisan governance systems focusing on institutional adaptability, administrative pragma- tism, and evidence-based policymaking. It presents fl exible economic opportun- ism as an illuminative but accessible model through which to interpret the complexity of public-private interaction and situates governance challenges within the context of transformative and often disruptive social, economic, and informa- tion revolutions. Universality is not the solution. This book seeks to reframe the debate and shift the paradigm from absolutism to fl exibility. The fi ttest may sur- vive, but only during the moment that circumstances value a unique combination of characteristics. It is the most adaptable that position themselves for sustainable success. Flexible economic opportunism embraces this logic in a way that applies to the current multiplicity of political and economic structures. Flexible economic opportunism represents a broader way of conceptualizing creative and pragmatic economic governance, a topic that is unjustifi ably overlooked and incompletely implemented due perhaps to its theoretical obscurity, empirical ambiguity, and cross-disciplinary challenges. This book aims to address all three in a manner that is contributory but by no means defi nitive. Indeed, this work marks the beginning of a larger research program to understand and improve local and national gov- ernance for the new global economy.

This page intentionally left blank Bibliography

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson (2005). “Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf, 386–472. Amsterdam: North Holland. —— (2001). “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91 (5): 1369–1401. Adams, David, and Michael Hess (2002). “Knowing and Skilling on Contemporary Public Administration.” Conference Proceedings from the International Political Science Association Committee, Structure and Organization of Government Research. June 3–5, 2002. AFL–CIO (2012). Public Protests Feb 16 Special Legislative Session. 28 February. http://afl cionc.org/public-protests-feb-16-special-legislative-session/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). Allison, Graham T. (2007). “Public and Private Management: Are They Alike in All the Unimportant Respects?” In Classics of Public Administration, edited by Jay M. Shafritz, Albert C. Hyde, and Sandra J. Parkes, 283–298. Belmont, CA: Wad- sworth/Thomson Learning. American Oil & Gas Historical Society [AOGHS] (2012). Shooters – A Fracking His- tory. http://aoghs.org/technology/shooters-well-fracking-history/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). Ammukutty, K.T. (1980). “Problems and Prospects of Mini Industrial Estates.” Social Scientist 8 (9): 53–64. Andersson, Susanne, and Eva Amundsdotter (2012). “Developing Innovative Organ- isations.” In Promoting Innovation: Policies, Practices and Procedures, edited by Susanne Andersson, Karin Berglund, Ewa Gunnarsson, and Elisabeth Sundin, 310– 327. Stockholm: Vinnova. —— (2008). “Public Provision for Urban Water: Getting Prices and Governance Right.” Governance 24 (4): 527–549. —— (2009). “What Explains Collective Action in the Commons: Theory and Evi- dence from the Philippines.” World Development 37 (3): 687–697. Araral, Eduardo (2012a). “Health Politics and Policy: Synthesis and Econometric Evidence from 170 Countries (1975–2010).” Working paper. —— (2012b). “The trust factor in US-China ties.” The Straits Times, 4 June. Araral, Eduardo, and David Yu (2012). “Water Governance: Critique, Theory and Evidence from Asia.” Working paper. Arrow, Kenneth J. (1963). “Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care.” American Economic Review 53 (5): 941–973. 198 Bibliography Asia News Monitor (2012). “Thailand: Environmental Group Executive Says Govern- ment Pushes for Industrial Growth while Ignoring the Environment.” Asia News Monitor, 29 June. Atkison, Glen (1990). “Airspace Regulation: Redefi ning the Public Domain.” Journal of Economic Issues 24 (2): 473–480. Auckland Council (2012). Auckland Council’s Submission to the Productivity Commis- sion’s Draft Report on Housing Affordability. Auckland: Auckland Council. —— (2013a). Auckland’s Housing . http://theplan.theaucklandplan.govt.nz/ aucklands-housing/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). —— (2013b). Auckland’s Transport . http://theplan.theaucklandplan.govt.nz/ aucklands-transport/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). —— (2013c). Auckland Plan . http://theplan.theaucklandplan.govt.nz/wp-content/ uploads/2012/07/Chapters-8-15.pdf (accessed 24 July, 2014). —— (2013d). Urban Auckland . http://theplan.theaucklandplan.govt.nz/urban- auckland (accessed 24 July, 2014). Auckland RGF (n.d.). Intensifi cation of Urban Areas. Auckland: Auckland Regional Growth Forum. Badcock, Blair (2004). Developing the New Zealand Housing Strategy. Toronto: Cen- tre for Urban and Community Studies, University of Toronto. Bale, J.R. (1977). “Industrial Estate Development and Location in Post-war Britain.” Geography 62 (2): 87–92. Bandaragoda, B.J. (2000). Institutional Analysis for Water Resources in a River Basin Context. Colombo: International Water Management Institute. Banerjee, Abhijit, and Esther Dufl o (2011). Poor Economics. London: Random House. Banerjee, Abhijit, and Lakshmi Iyer (2002). “History, Institutions and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India.” Working Paper No. 02–27, MIT Department of Economics, Cambridge, MA. Basurto, Xavier, Gordon Kingsley, Kelly McQueen, Mshadoni Smith, and Christopher Weible (2010). “A Systematic Approach to Institutional Analysis: Applying Craw- ford and Ostrom’s Grammar.” Political Research Quarterly 63 (3): 523–537. Bateman, Christopher (2010). “A Colossal Fracking Mess.” Vanity Fair, 21 June. Bates, Robert H., Avner Greif, Margaret Levi, and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal (1998). Analytic Narratives. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Baumgartner, Frank R., and Bryan D. Jones (1991). Agenda Dynamics and Policy Subsystems. Journal of Politics 53(4), 1044–1074. Becker, Jo, Sheryl Gay Stolberg, and Stephen Labaton (2008). “White House Phi- losophy Stoked Mortgage Bonfi re.” New York Times, 20 December. Beckwith, Robin (2010). “Hydraulic Fracturing: The Fuss, the Facts, the Future.” Journal of Petroleum Technology 63(12): 34–41. Beekmans, Jasper, Erwin van der Krabben, and Karel Martens (2011). An Indicator for Decline of Industrial Estates. Nijmegen, Netherlands: Radboud University Nijmegen Institute for Management Research. Beierle, Thomas (1998). Public Participation in Environmental Decisions: An Evalu- ation Framework Using Social Goals. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Belich, James (2010). “Exploding Wests: Boom and Bust in Nineteenth Century Set- tler Societies.” In Natural Experiments of History, edited by Jared Diamond and James A. Robinson, 53–87. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Bellandi, Marco, and Annalisa Caloffi (2008). “District Internationalisation and Trans- local Development.” Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 20 (6): 517–532. Bibliography 199 Beresford, P. (2002). “Participation and Social Policy: Transformation, Liberation or Regulation?” Social Policy Review 14: 265–287. Bertelli, Anthony M. (2005). “Law and Public Administration.” In Oxford Handbook of Public Management, edited by, Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christopher Pollitt. Oxford Handbooks Online. Biswas, Asit K., and Kris Hartley (2013). “Concerns for Secondary Cities.” China Daily, 12 November. Blakeley, Roger (2011). “Three Hot Issues for Aucklanders.” New Zealand Herald, 13 October. Blomgren, Lisa, Rosemary O’Leary, and Christine Carlson (2008). “Frameshifting: Lateral Thinking for Collaborative Public Management.” In Big Ideas in Collabora- tive Public Management, edited by Lisa Blomgren Bingham and Rosemary O’Leary, 3–16. New York: M.E. Sharpe. Bogason, Peter (2007). “Postmodern Public Administration.” In The Oxford Hand- book of Public Management, edited by Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christo- pher Pollitt, 3–16. Oxford Handbooks Online. Bona, Mark (n.d.). Mortgage Industry in Australia. http://www.articlesnatch.com/ Article/Mortgage-industry-in-Australia/569399 (accessed 2 May, 2014). Boschma, Ron, and Jan Lambooy (2002). “Knowledge, Market Structure, and Economic Coordination: Dynamics of Industrial Districts.” Growth and Change 33: 291–311. Bound, John, and Gary Solon (1999). “Double Trouble: On the Value of Twins-Based Estimation of the Return to Schooling.” Economics of Education Review 18: 169–182. Box, Richard C. (1999). “Running Government like a Business: Implications for Public Administration Theory and Practice.” American Review of Public Adminis- tration 29 (1): 19–43. Bradsher, Keith (2014). “China Takes on Big Risks in Its Push for Shale Gas.” New York Times, 11 April. Bramley, Glen, Murray Stewart, and Jacky Underwood (1979). “Local Economic Initiatives: A Review.” Town Planning Review 50 (2): 131–147. Brandenburger, Adam (2007). “The Power of Paradox: Some Recent Developments in Interactive Epistemology.” International Journal of Game Theory 35: 465–492. Broder, John M (2013). “New Fracking Rules Proposed for U.S. Land.” New York Times, 16 May. Brower, S. (2000). Good Neighborhoods: A Study of In-Town and Suburban Environ- ments. Westport, CT: Praeger. Brülhart, Marius (1998). “Economic Geography, Industry Location and Trade: The Evidence.” World Economy 21: 775–801. Bryner, Gary (2003). “Public Organisations and Public Policies.” In Handbook of Public Administration, edited by Guy Peters and J. Pierre, 189–198. London: Sage. Burgess, James (2012). Bulgaria Bans Fracking following Public Protests. 18 January. http://oilprice.com/Latest-Energy-News/World-News/Bulgaria-Bans-Fracking- Following-Public-Protests.html (accessed 2 May, 2014). Burritt, Roger, Tobias Hahn, and Stefan Schaltegger (2002). “Towards a Compre- hensive Framework for Environmental Management Accounting – Links between Business Actors and Environmental Management Accounting Tools.” Australian Accounting Review 12 (27): 39–50. Campbell, Scott (1996). “Green Cities, Growing Cities, Just Cities? Urban Planning and the Contradictions of Sustainable Development.” Journal of the American Planning Association 62 (3): 296–312. 200 Bibliography Carter, Richard, and Geoffrey M. Hodgson (2006). “The Impact of Empirical Tests of Transaction Cost Economics on the Debate on the Nature of the Firm.” Strategic Management Journal 27 (5): 461–476. Castells, Manuel (1996). The Rise of the Network Society. Oxford: Blackwell. Castells, Manuel, and Amelia Arsenault (2006). “Conquering the Minds, Conquering Iraq: The Social Production of Misinformation in the United States.” Information, Communication & Society 9 (3): 284–308. Chaddock, Gail Russell (2009). “Belat- edly, House Votes to Curb Predatory Lending.” Christian Science Monitor, 8 May. Chang, Ha-Joon (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective. New York: Anthem Press. Cheung, Anthony B.L., and Ian Scott (2003). “Governance and Public Sector Reforms in Asia: Paradigms, Paradoxes and Dilemmas.” In Governance and Public Sector Reform in Asia: Paradigm Shifts or Business as Usual?, edited by Anthony B.L. Cheung and Ian Scott, 1–24. London: Routledge Curzon. Chiappori, Pierre-Andre, Frank Durand, and Pierre-Yves Geoffard (1998). “Moral Hazard and the Demand for Physician Services: First Lessons from a French Natural Experiment.” European Economic Review 42: 499–511. Chinitz, Benjamin (1961). “Contrasts in Agglomeration: New York and Pittsburgh.” American Economic Review 51 (2): 279–289. Coase, Ronald H. (1937). “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 4 (16): 386–405. —— (1960). “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44. Comfort, Louise K., and Naim Kapucu (2006). “Inter-organizational Coordination in Extreme Events: The World Trade Center Attacks, September 11, 2001.” Natu- ral Hazards 39: 309–327. Commons, John R. (1931). “Institutional Economics.” American Economic Review 21 (4): 648–657. Cooley, Heather, and Kristina Donnelly (2012). Hydraulic Fracturing and Water Resources: Separating the Frack from the Friction. Seattle: Pacifi c Institute. Cooper, Malcolm (1976). “Government Infl uence on Industrial Location: Case Stud- ies in the North West and West Midlands of England.” Town Planning Review 47 (4): 384–397. Cullen, Alice Jane (2005). Urban Intensifi cation and Affordable Housing in Auck- land. Dunedin, New Zealand: University of Otago. D’Agostino, Mary J., and Helisse Levine (2011). Women in Public Administration: Theory and Practice. Sudbury, MA: Jones and Bartlett Learning. David, Robert J., and Shin-Kap Han (2004). “A Systematic Assessment of the Empiri- cal Support for Transaction Cost Economics.” Strategic Management Journal 25 (1): 39–58. Deboonme, Achara (2012). “Map Ta Phut Needs to Earn Public Confi dence.” Nation, 8 May. deLeon, Linda (2005). “Public Management, Democracy, and Politics.” In The Oxford Handbook of Public Management, edited by Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christopher Pollitt, 103–123. Oxford Handbooks Online. Demographia (2013). 9th Annual Demographia International Housing Affordability Survey. Belleville, IL: Demographia. Denhardt, J.V., and R.B. Denhardt (2010). Public Administration in Perspective: Theory and Practice through Multiple Lenses. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Denhardt, Robert (1993). Theories of Public Organization. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth. Bibliography 201 de Soto, Hernando (2001). “Dead Capital and the Poor.” Sais Review 21 (1): 13–44. Diamond, Jared, and James Robinson (Eds.) (2010). Natural Experiments of History. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University. Diamond, Larry (2010). “Liberation Technology.” Journal of Democracy 21 (3): 69–83. Dick, Howard W., and Peter J. Rimmer (1998). “Beyond the Third World City: The New Urban Geography of South-East Asia.” Urban Studies 35 (12): 2303–2321. Dickenson, J.P. (1970). “Industrial Estates in Brazil.” Geography 55 (3): 326–329. Di Tella, Rafael, Sebastian Galiani, and Ernesto Schargrodsky (2004). “Property Rights and Beliefs: Evidence from the Allocation of Land Titles to Squatters.” Working Paper 5, Ronald Coase Institute. Dobel, J. (2006). “Public Management as Ethics.” In The Oxford Handbook of Public Management, edited by Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christopher Pollitt, 161–181. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Douglass, Mike (2002). “Globalization, Inter-city Competition and the Rise of Civil Society: Toward Livable Cities in Pacifi c Asia.” In Critical Refl ections on Cities in Southeast Asia, edited by Tim Bunnell, Lisa Barbara Welch Drummond, Ho Kong Chong, 215–239, Singapore: Times Academic Press in association with Brill Aca- demic Publishers. Dunlap, Riley, and William Catton (1979). “Environmental Sociology.” American Review of Sociology 5: 243–273. Dupius, Ann, and Jenny Dixon (2012). A Decade of Urban Growth Management in Auckland: Issues of Acceptability and Delivery. Adelaide: 6th Australaisan Housing Researchers’ Conference. Duranton, Gilles, and Henry Overman (2002). Testing for Localisation Using Micro- geographic Data. London: London School of Economics. Ebenhöh, Eva (2007). “Designing Agent-Based Models of Water Management Regimes Using the IAD Framework.” In The Challenge of Self-Governance in Com- plex, Globalizing Economies, edited by Elinor Ostrom and Achim Schlüter, 81–98. Freiburg: Institute of Forest Economy. Egeberg, Morton (2007). “How Bureaucratic Structure Matters: An Organizational Perspective.” In The Handbook of Public Administration, edited by B. Guy Peters and John Pierre, 77–87. Beverly Hills: Sage. Elster, Jon (2000). “Rational Choice History: A Case of Excessive Ambition.” Ameri- can Political Science Review 94 (3): 685–695. http://www.jstor.org/stable/ 2585842. Erdenechuluun, Tumur, Wim Heijman, Agipar Bakey, and Nico Heerink (n.d.). The Characteristics of Current Rangeland Management in Mongolia. Wageningen; Ulaanbaatar: Wageningen University (Netherlands) and Mongolian State Univer- sity of Agriculture. Evans, Peter (2002). “Political Strategies for More Livable Cities: Lessons from Six Cases of Development and Political Transition.” In Livable Cities: Urban Struggles for Livelihood and Sustainability, edited by Peter Evans, 222–246. Berkeley: Uni- versity of California Press. Evans, Peter, and James T. Rauch (1999). “Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross- National Analysis of the Effects of ‘Weberian’ State Structures on Economic Growth.” American Sociological Review 64 (5): 748–765. 202 Bibliography Fainstein, Norman, and Susan Fainstein (2012). “The Changing Character of Urban Redevelopment.” In The Oxford Handbook of Urban Planning, edited by Rachel Weber and Randall Crane, 587–608. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Fainstein, Susan (2005). “Cities and Diversity: Should We Want It? Can We Plan For It?” Urban Affairs Review 41 (1): 3–19. —— (2001a). The City Builders: Property Development in New York and London, 1980–2000. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas. —— (2001b). “Inequality in Global City-Regions.” In Global City-Regions: Trends, Theory, Policy, edited by Allen Scott, 285–298. Oxford: Oxford University Press. —— (2001c). “Inequality in Global City-Regions.” Planning Review 37 (144): 20–25. —— (2010). The Just City. New York: Cornell University Press. Fainstein, Susan S., Norman I. Fainstein, Richard Child Hill, Dennis Judd, and Michael Peter Smith (1983). Restructuring the City: The Political Economy of Urban Redevelopment. Ithaca, NY: Longman. Fan, C. Cindy, and Allen J. Scott (2003). “Industrial Agglomeration and Develop- ment: A Survey of Spatial Economic Issues in East Asia and a Statistical Analysis of Chinese Regions.” Economic Geography 79 (3): 295–319. Farmer, David John (2010). Public Administration in Perspective: Theory and Practice through Multiple Lenses. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Fidler, Richard (2012). Major Victory for Quebec Students, Environmental Activists. 21 September. http://lifeonleft.blogspot.sg/2012/09/major-victory-for-quebec- students.html (accessed 2 May, 2014). Fisher, Ronald A. (1971). The Design of Experiments. New York: Hafner Publishing Company. Frederickson, H. George (2007). “Towards a New Public Administration.” In Classics of Public Administration, edited by Jay M. Shafritz, Albert C. Hyde, and Sandra J. Parkes, 294–305. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thomson Learning. Frederickson, H. George, and Kevin B. Smith (2003). The Public Administration Theory Primer. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Freeman, James (2009). “The Credit Crisis and Its Creation.” Wall Street Journal, 13 May. Friedman, Milton (1966). Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Friedmann, John (2007). “Refl ections on Place and Place-Making in the Cities of China.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 31 (2): 257–279. —— (1986). “The World City Hypothesis.” Development and Change 17 (1): 69–83. Fry, Matthew, David Hoeinghaus, Alexandra Ponette-Gonzales, Ruthann Thompson, and Thomas LaPoint (2012). Fracking vs. Faucets: Balancing Energy Needs and Water Sustainability at Urban Frontiers. Washington, DC: American Chemical Society. Fuglsang, L (1994). “The Baltic Region as an Industrial Estate: An Institutionalist Critique.” AI & Society 8 (2): 164–185. Fuller, Thomas (2009). “In Industrial Thailand, Health and Business Concerns Col- lide.” New York Times, 18 December. Galiani, Sebastian, and Ernesto Schargrodsky (2010). “Property Rights for the Poor: Effects of Land Titling.” Journal of Public Economics 94 (9–10): 700–729. Ghoshal, Sumantra, and Peter Moran (1996). “Bad for Practice: A Critique of the Transaction Cost Theory.” Academy of Management Review 21 (1): 13–47. Bibliography 203 Gibson, Anne (2011). “$1b Leaky Homes Aid Package Starts Today.” New Zealand Herald, 29 July. Gibson, Clark C., Krister Andersson, Elinor Ostrom, and Sujai Shivakumar (2008). The Samaritan’s Dilemma: The Political Economy of Development Aid. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Goldratt, Eliyahu (1984). The Goal. Great Barrington, MA: North River Press. Goodnow, Frank J. (1900). Politics and Administration: A Study in Government . London: Macmillan. Göransson, Anita (2006). Forces of Gender: Men and Women in the Swedish Power Elite in the 2000s. Nora, Sweden: Nya Doxa. Gordon, Ian (1999). “Internationalisation and Urban Competition.” Urban Studies 36 (5–6): 1001–1016. Graham, Stephen (2005). The Network Society: A New Context for Planning. London: Routledge. Graham, Stephen, and Simon Martin (2001). Splintering Urbanism: Networked Infra- structures, Technological Mobilities, and the Urban Condition. New York: Routledge. Granovetter, Mark (1985). “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91 (3): 481–510. Gray, John (1998). False Dawn: The Delusions of Global Capitalism. London: Granta. Green Party of New Zealand (n.d.). Frack No! http://www.greens.org.nz/fracking (accessed 2 May, 2014). Groat, Charles, and Thomas Grimshaw (2012). Fact Based Regulation for Environ- mental Protection in Shale Gas Development. Austin: The Energy Institute at the University of Texas at Austin. Gulick, Luther H. (1936). “Notes on the Theory of Organization.” In Papers on the Science of Administration , edited by Luther Gulick and Lyndall Urwick, 3–35. New York: Routledge. Gupta, Saibal Das (1998). “3-Tier Management for Gujarat Industrial Estates Planned.” Business Standard, 18 March. Hadfi eld, Gillian K. (2005). “The Many Legal Institutions That Support Contractual Commitments.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, edited by M. Shirley and C. Menard, 175–203. Berlin: Springer. Hajnal, Gyirgy (2004). “Cultural Determinants of New Public Management Reforms: A Comparative Study.” Society and Economy 26 (2–3): 223–246. Halliburton (2012). Hydraulic Fracturing 101. http://www.halliburton.com/ public/projects/pubsdata/hydraulic_fracturing/fracturing_101.html (accessed 2 May, 2014). Hannigan, John (2013). Fantasy City: Pleasure and Profi t in the Postmodern Metropo- lis. London: Routledge. Harrison, Bennett (1992). “Industrial Districts: Old Wine in New Bottles?” Regional Studies 26 (5): 107–121. Hartley, Kris (2009). Transforming the Housing Crisis in Richmond. Oakland, CA: Urban Habitat. Harvey, David (1985). The Urbanisation of Capital: Studies in the History and Theory of Capitalist Urbanisation. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Hayek, Friedrich A. (1945). “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” American Economic Review 35 (4): 519–530. 204 Bibliography Hebbert, Michael (1980). “The British New Towns: A Review Article.” Town Plan- ning Review 51 (4): 414–420. Heller, Agnes (n.d.). “What Is ‘Postmodernism’? A Quarter of a Century After.” http:// openjournals.library.usyd.edu.au/index.php/ART/article/download/5680/6353 (accessed 2 May, 2014). Henderson, David R. (2002). Japan and the Myth of MITI. http://www.econlib.org/ library/Enc1/JapanandtheMythofMITI.html (accessed 2 May, 2014). Henderson, J. Vernon, Zmarak Shalizi, and Anthony J. Venables (2001). “Geography and Development.” Journal of Economic Geography 1 (1): 81–105. Hill, Richard Child, and June Woo Kim (2000). “Global Cities and Developmental States: New York, Tokyo and Seoul.” Urban Studies 37 (12): 2167–2195. Hinshaw, Mark L. (2007). True Urbanism: Living In and Near the Center. Washing- ton DC: American Planning Association. Hirsch, Abraham (1980). “The ‘Assumptions’ Controversy in Historical Perspective.” Journal of Economic Issues 14 (1): 99–118. Hirschmann, David (1999). “Development Management versus Third World Bureau- cracies: A Brief History of Confl icting Interests.” Development and Change 30: 287–305. Holländer, Robert, Chunyou Wu, and Ning Duan (2009). “Sustainable Development of Industrial Parks.” Working Paper No. 81, University of Leipzig. Hood, Christopher (2007). “Public Management for All Seasons.” In Classics of Pub- lic Administration, edited by Jay M. Shafritz, Albert C. Hyde, and Sandra J. Parkes, 3–19. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thomson Learning. Housing New Zealand Corporation [HNZC] (2012a). Annual Report 2011/2012. Wellington: Housing New Zealand Corporation. —— (2013). Briefi ng for the Incoming Minister of Housing. Wellington: Housing New Zealand Corporation. —— (2012b). History of State Housing. 4 April. http://www.hnzc.co.nz/about-us/ history-of-state-housing (accessed 6 July, 2014). —— (2012c). Statement of Intent 2012–2015. Wellington: Housing New Zealand Corporation. —— (2010). Strategic Plan 2010–2015. Wellington: Housing New Zealand Corporation. Hudalah, Delik, and Tommy Firman (2012). “Beyond Property: Industrial Estates and Post-suburban Transformation in Jakarta Metropolitan Region.” Cities 29 (1): 40–48. Huxham, Chris, and Siv Vangen (2005). Managing to Collaborate: The Theory and Practice of Collaborative Advantage. New York: Routledge. Ibem, Eziyi Offi a (2010). “An Assessment of the Role of Government Agencies in Public-Private Partnerships in Housing Delivery in Nigeria.” Journal of Construc- tion in Developing Countries 15 (2): 23–48. Ingraham, Patricia W. (2005). “Striving for Balance: Reforms in Human Resource Management.” In The Oxford Handbook of Public Management, edited by Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christopher Pollitt, 521–536. Oxford Handbooks Online. Intarukumnerd, Patarapong, and Yveline Lecler (2010). Sustainability of Thailand’s Competitiveness: The Policy Challenges. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies. Bibliography 205 International Energy Agency (2012). Golden Rules for a Golden Age of Gas. Paris: International Energy Agency. Jababeka (2011). Jababeka History. http://www.jababeka.com/history (accessed 2 May, 2014). Jacob, Shine (2013). “ONGC to Put India on Shale Gas Exploration Map on Tues- day.” Business Standard, 24 November. Jacobs, Jane (1961). The Death and Life of Great American Cities. New York: Random House. Jepperson, Ronald L. (1991). “Institutions, Institutional Effects, and Institutional- ism.” In Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, edited by Walter W. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio, 143–163. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Jessop, Bob (2002). “Liberalism, Neoliberalism, and Urban Governance: A State– Theoretical Perspective.” Antipode 34 (3): 452–472. Jingjit, Rutaichanok, and Marianna Fotaki (2010). “Confucian Ethics and the Limited Impact of the New Public Management Reform in Thailand.” J Bus Ethics 97: 61–73. Johnson, Chalmers (1986, November 9). Interview by Peter Myers. How Western Financiers Caused the Asia Crisis. http://mailstar.net/johnson.html (accessed 3 September, 2014). —— (1982). MITI and the Japanese Miracle: Growth of Industrial Policy: 1925–1975. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press. Johnson, Tim, and Ben Bland (2011). “Burma Suspends $3.6Bn China Dam Proj- ect.” Financial Times, 30 September. Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky (1979). “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 47 (2): 263–91. Kantor, Paul, Christian Lefèvre, Asato Saito, Hank V. Savitch, and Andy Thornley (2012). Struggling Giants: City-Region Governance in London, New York, Paris, and Tokyo. Globalization and Community, vol. 20. Minneapolis: University of Min- nesota Press. Kaplowitz, Michael, Daniel V. Ortega-Pacheco, and Frank Lupi (2008). “Payment for Environmental Services and Other Institutions for Protecting Drinking Water in Eastern Costa Rica.” In Alternative Institutional Structures: Evolution and Impact, edited by Sandra S. Batie and Nicholas Mercuro, 380–401. London: Routledge. Karagiannis, Nikolaos, and Zagros Madjd-Sadjadi (2007). Modern State Intervention in the Era of Globalisation. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Kauzya, John-Mary (n.d.). Revisiting the Role of Public Administration in Africa’s Development: Strengthening the Human Resource Function for Effective Service Delivery in an Environment of Economic Crisis. New York: United Nations, Gover- nance and Public Administration Branch. Kay, John (2009). “How Economics Lost Sight Of Real World.” Financial Times, 22 April. Kent, T.J. (1963). City and Regional Planning for the Metropolitan San Francisco Bay Area. Berkeley: Institute of Governmental Studies, University of California. King, Gary, Robert O. Keohane, and Sydney Verba (1994). Designing Social Inquiry: Scientifi c Inference in Qualitative Research. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Kingdon, John W., and James A. Thurber (1984). Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies. Boston: Little, Brown. Kitson, Michael, Ron Martin, and Peter Tyler (2004). “Regional Competitiveness: An Elusive yet Key Concept?” Regional Studies 38 (9): 991–999. 206 Bibliography Koopmans, Tjalling C. (1957). Three Essays on the State of Economic Science. New York: McGraw Hill. Kovidhavanij, Weena (2012). “Map Ta Phut, Industry and Environment: Challenge of Sustainable Development.” AsiaNews, 5 October. Krugman, Paul (1994). “Competitiveness: A Dangerous Obsession.” Foreign Affairs 73 (2): 28–44. —— (1991). “Increasing Returns and Economic Geography.” Journal of Political Economy 99: 483–499. —— (1996). “Making Sense of the Competitiveness Debate.” Oxford Review of Eco- nomic Policy 12 (3): 17–25. Larbi, George A. (1999). The New Public Management Approach and Crisis States. New York: United National Research Institute for Social Development. LeCompte, M. D. (1987). “Bias in the Biography: Bias and Subjectivity in Ethno- graphic Research.” Anthropology & Education Quarterly 18(1), 43–52. Le Corbusier (2010). “The City of Tomorrow and Its Planning.” In The Blackwell City Reader, edited by[0] Gary Bridge and Sophie Watson, 345–354. Malden, MA: John Wiley & Sons. Lee, Eliza W., and M. Shamsul Haque (2006). “The New Public Management Reform and Governance in Asian NICs: A Comparison of Hong Kong and Singapore.” Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions 19 (4): 605–626. Lefebvre, Henri, and Enders, Michael J. (1976). “Refl ections on the Politics of Space.” Antipode 8(2), 30–37. Lewis, Carol W., and Stuart C. Gilman (2005). The Ethics Challenge in Public Service: A Problem-Solving Guide. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Li, Jinshan, and Tuo Ye (n.d.). Fragmented Government: Theories and Facts in China. Hangzhou: Zhejiang University. Lipietz, Alain (1997). “The Post-Fordist World: Labour Relations, International Hierarchy and Global Ecology.” Review of International Political Economy 4 (1): 1–41. Lipsky, Michael (2010). Street-Level Bureaucracy, 30th Ann. Ed.: Dilemmas of the Individual in Public Service . New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Lipton, Eric (2009). “Ex-Leaders of Countrywide Profi t from Bad Loans.” New York Times, 3 March. Logan, John (2011). The New Chinese City: Globalization and Market Reform. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers. Louw, Erik, Erwin van der Krabben, and Hans van Amsterdam (2011). “The Spatial Productivity of Industrial Land.” Regional Studies 46 (1): 137–147 . Lowe, Ernest (2001). “Eco-industrial Park Handbook.” http://indigodev.com/ ADBHBdownloads.html (accessed 3 September, 2014). Lynn, Laurence (2007). “Public Management: A Concise History of the Field.” In The Oxford Handbook of Public Management, edited by Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christopher Pollitt, 27–50. Oxford: Oxford University Press. MacRae, Michael (2012). Fracking: A Look Back. ASME, December. https://www. asme.org/engineering-topics/articles/fossil-power/fracking-a-look-back (accessed 6 July, 2014). Maetzig, Rob (2012). Fracking Essential, Says Todd Report. 8 November. http:// www.stuff.co.nz/business/industries/7920569/Fracking-essential-says-Todd- report (accessed 2 May, 2014). Bibliography 207 Manning, Nick (2001). “The Legacy of the New Public Management in Developing Countries.” International Review of Administrative Sciences 67: 297–312. Mano, Yukichi, and Keijiro Otsuka (2000). “Agglomeration Economies and Geo- graphical Concentration of Industries: A Case Study of Manufacturing Sectors in Postwar Japan.” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 14: 189–203. Map Ta Phut Industrial Estate [MTPIE]. (2004). Map Ta Phut Industrial Estate. http://www.mtpie.com/prfl /mn_prfl .htm (accessed 2 May, 2014). Markusen, Ann (1996). “Sticky Places in Slippery Space: A Typology of Industrial Districts.” Economic Geography 72 (3): 293–313. —— (2006). “Urban Development and the Politics of a Creative Class: Evidence from a Study of Artists.” Environment and Planning A 38 (10): 1921–1940. Marshall, Alfred (1920). Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan. Martens, Bertin, Uwe Mummert, Peter Murrell, and Paul Seabright (2001). The Insti- tutional Economics of Foreign Aid. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Martin, Edward J. (2003). “Liberation Theology, Sustainable Development, and Postmodern Public Administration.” Latin American Perspectives 30 (4): 69–91. Maslow, Abraham Harold (1943). “A Theory of Human Motivation.” Psychological Review 50 (4): 370–396. Mathew, P.T. (1990) “State Sector Enterprises in Kerala.” Economic and Political Weekly 25 (24/25): 1349–1351. Mathiasen, David (2007). “International Public Management.” In The Oxford Hand- book of Public Management, edited by Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christo- pher Pollitt, 643–670. Oxford Handbooks Online. Matsaert, Harriet (2002). Institutional Analysis in Natural Resources Research. Greenwich, UK: National Resources Institute. Mayda, Jaro (1985). “Environmental Legislation in Developing Countries: Some Parameters and Constraints.” Ecology Law Quarterly 12: 997–1024. McCloskey, Dierdre (1983). “The Rhetoric of Economics.” Journal of Economic Lit- erature 21 (2): 481–517. McCourt, Willy (2010). “The Future of Development Management: Introduction to the Special Issue.” Public Administration and Development 30: 81–90. McCourt, Willy, and Martin Minogue (2001). The Internationalisation of Public Management. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. McDonald, John F. (2007). Urban America: Growth, Crisis, and Rebirth. New York: M.E. Sharpe. McIntire, Mike (2009). “Tracking Loans through a Firm That Holds Millions.” New York Times, 23 April. McKinnon, Malcolm (2011). Asian Cities: Globalization, Urbanization and Nation- Building. Singapore: NAIS Press. Meier, Kenneth J., and Gregory C. Hill (2007). “Bureaucracy in the Twenty-First Century.” In The Oxford Handbook of Public Management, edited by Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christopher Pollitt, 51–71. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Meyers, Marcia K., and Susan Vorsanger (2007). “Street-Level Bureaucrats and the Implementation of Public Policy.” In The Handbook of Public Administration, edited by B. Guy Peters and John Pierre, 153–163. Beverly Hills: Sage. Miller, Hugh T., and Charles J. Fox (2007). Postmodern Public Administration. New York: M.E. Sharpe. 208 Bibliography Min, Aung, and Toshihiro Kudo (2012). “Newly Emerging Industrial Development Nodes in Myanmar: Ports, Roads, Industrial Zones along Economic Corridors.” In Emerging Economic Corridors in the Mekong Region , Masami Ishida, 187–230. Bangkok: IDE-JETRO. Misra, S. (2000). “Collective Action: An Alternative Institutional Arrangement for Reducing Water Pollution in an Industrial Estate in India.” Natural Resources Forum 24 (4): 285–295. Mitchell, Don (2003). The Right to the City: Social Justice and the Fight for Public Space. New York: Guilford Press. Montgomery, Carl T., and Michael B. Smith (2010). Hydraulic Fracturing: History of an Enduring Technology. Tulsa, OK: NSI Technologies. Moynihan, Donald (2003). “Normative and Instrumental Perspectives on Public Par- ticipation: Citizen Summits in Washington D.C.” American Review of Public Administration 33 (2): 164–188. Mumford, Lewis (1956). “A Study of History.” Diogenes 4 (13): 11–28. Nabatchi, Tina, Holly T. Goerdel, and Shelly Peffer (2008). “Public Administration in Dark Times: Some Questions for the Future of the Field.” JPART 21: 129–143. Nation (2012). “Opposition Re-emerges to Map Ta Phut Projects.” Nation, 8 May. Natural Resources Defense Council [NRDC] (2012). In Fracking’s Wake: New Rules Are Needed to Protect Our Health and Environment from Contaminated Wastewater. New York: Natural Resources Defense Council. Needham, Barrie, and Erik Louw (2006). “Institutional Economics and Policies for Changing Land Markets: The Case of Industrial Estates in the Netherlands.” Jour- nal of Property Research 23 (1): 75–90. Negro, Sorell (2012). “Fracking Wars: Federal, State and Local Confl icts over the Regulation of Natural Gas Activities.” Zoning and Planning Law Report 35 (2): 1–13. Newman, Janet, Marian Barnes, Helen Sullivan, and Andrew Knops (2004). “Public Participation and Collaborative Governance.” Journal of Social Policy 33 (2): 203–223. Neuman, Scott (2014). USGS: Okla. At Increased Risk of “Damaging Quake.” National Public Radio News, Washington D.C. May 5. http://www.npr.org/ blogs/thetwo-way/2014/05/05/309888859/usgs-okla-fracking-has-increased-chance- of-damaging-quake (accessed 4 September, 2014). New York Times (2009a). “The Halliburton Loophole.” New York Times, 2 November. —— (2009b). “Predatory Brokers.” New York Times, 9 April. New Yorkers Against Fracking (n.d.). In Fracking Fight, Protests May Be Having an Impact. http://nyagainstfracking.org/in-fracking-fi ght-protests-may-be-having- an-impact/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). New Zealand Government (2012). Housing NZ Transforming Its Business. 31 August. http://www.beehive.govt.nz/release/housing-nz-transforming-its-business (accessed 2 May, 2014). Ni Peng-Fei, N. I. (2002). “An Emperical Test about Contribution of Infrastructure to Urban Competitiveness [J].” China Industrial Economy 5: 62–69. Nivatvongs, Pathitta (2012). Industrial Estates in Thailand. Bangkok: Industrial Estates Authority of Thailand. Bibliography 209 Noland, Marcus, Donghyun Park, and Gemma B. Estrada (2012). “Developing the Services Sector as Engine of Growth for Asia: An Overview.” Working Paper, Asian Development Bank Manila. North, Douglass (2005). “Institutions and the Performance of Economies over Time.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, edited by M. Shirley and C. Menard, 21–30. Berlin: Springer. —— (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cam- bridge: Cambridge University Press. —— (1955). “Location Theory and Regional Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 63 (3) (June 1): 243–258. North, Douglass, John Joseph Wallis, and Barry R. Weingast (2009). Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. O’Brien, Tova (2012). Fracking in Southland exposed. 27 June. http://www.3news. co.nz/Fracking-in-Southland-exposed/tabid/423/articleID/259325/Default. aspx (accessed 2 May, 2014). Orsman, Bernard (2013). “2016 Start to City Rail Link.” New Zealand Herald, 12 September. Osborne, David, and Ted Gaebler (1992). Reinventing Government. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Ostrom, Elinor (2007). “Institutional Rational Choice: An Assessment of the Institu- tional Analysis and Development Framework.” In Theories of the Policy Process, edited by Paul Sabatier, 21–64. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Ostrom, Elinor, Roy Gardner, and James Walker (1994). Rules, Games, and Common- Pool Resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Ostrom, Vincent, and Elinor Ostrom (1978). Public Goods and Public Choices. Bloom- ington: Indiana University, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. Ostrom, Vincent, Tiebout, Charles M., and Warren, Robert (1961). The Organiza- tion of Government in Metropolitan Areas: A Theoretical Inquiry. The American Political Science Review , 831–842. Ott, J.S. (1989). The Organizational Culture Perspective. Chicago: Dorsey Press. Paley, Amit R. (2009). “The Student Loan Industry Pushes Back.” Washington Post, 14 April. Pansuwan, Apisek (2010). “Industrial Decentralization Policies and Industrialization in Thailand.” Silpakorn University International Journal 9–10: 117–147. Park, Bae-Gyoon, Richard Child Hill, and Asato Saito (2012). Locating Neoliberalism in East Asia. Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell. Park, Sung Min (n.d.). “Of Alternating Waves and Shifting Shores: The Confi guration of Reform Values in the U.S. Federal Bureaucracy.” Working paper. Parliament of New Zealand (1991). Resource Management Act 1991. Wellington: New Zealand Parliamentary Counsel Offi ce. Peel, Deborah, Greg Lloyd, and Alex Lord (2009). “Business Improvement Districts and the Discourse of Contractualism.” European Planning Studies 17 (3): 401–422. Peluso, Marco, et al. (2010). “Malondialdehyde-Deoxyguanosine Adducts among Workers of a Thai Industrial Estate and Nearby Residents.” Environmental Health Perspectives 118 (1): 55–59. 210 Bibliography Perroux, Francois (1950). “Economic Space: Theory and Applications.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 64: 89–104. Perry, James L., and Wise, Lois R. (1990). “The Motivational Bases of Public Ser- vice.” Public Administration Review , 367–373. Peters, Kristal M. (2010). In Search of Symbioses: An Assessment of the Relationships between Two Industrial Estates and Their Adjacent Communities in Trinidad, West Indies. Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Phelps, N.A. (2004). “Archetype for an Archipelago? Batam as an Anti-model and Model of Industrialization in reformasi Indonesia.” Progress in Development Studies 4 (3): 206–229. Pollitt, Christopher (2001). “Clarifying Convergence: Striking Similarities and Dura- ble Differences in Public Management Reform.” Public Management Review 4 (1): 471–492. Pollitt, Christopher, and Geert Bouckaert (2011). Public Management Reform. New York: Oxford University Press. Pollitt, Christopher, and Sorin Dan (2011). “The Impacts of the New Public Manage- ment in Europe: A Meta-analysis.” Cocops Work Package 1 – Deliverable 1.1. Polski, Margaret, and Elinor Ostrom (1999). “An institutional framework for policy analysis and design.” In Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis Working Paper W98-27. Indiana University, Bloomington, IN. Poteete, Amy R., Marco A. Janssen, and Elinor Ostrom (2010). Working Together: Collective Action, the Commons, and Multiple Methods in Practice. Princeton: Princ- eton University Press. Puga, Diego (2009). “The Magnitude and Causes of Agglomeration Economies.” Journal of Regional Science 50 (1): 203–219. Redding, Stephen (2010). “The Empirics of the New Economic Geography.” Journal of Regional Science , 50(1): 297–311. Reuters (2012). “Bulgaria Eases Oil and Gas Fracking Ban.” Reuters, 14 June. http:// www.reuters.com/article/2012/06/14/bulgaria-shale-idUSL5E8HEAL720 120614 (accessed 2 May, 2014). Richardson, Richard (2004). “A Conceptual Framework for Comparisons of Higher Education Policy.” Working paper, AIHEPS. Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi (2004). “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Develop- ment.” Working paper. Rohr, John Anthony (1998). Public Service, Ethics, and Constitutional Practice. Law- rence: University Press of Kansas. Rosenthal, Stuart, and William Strange (1999). Geography, Industrial Organization, and Agglomeration. Syracuse: Center for Policy Research, Maxwell School, Syracuse University. Rosenzweig, Mark, and Kenneth Wolpin (2000). “Natural ‘Natural Experiments’ in Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 38: 827–874. Roznowski, JoAnn (2001). An Institutional and Behavioral Economics View of the Consumer Privacy Debate. East Lansing: Michigan State University. Rubin, Paul H. (2005). “Legal Systems as Frameworks for Market Exchanges.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, edited by M. Shirley and C. Menard, 205–228. Berlin: Springer. Rucker, Patrick, and Kevin Drawbaugh (2009). “Mortgage Investment Reform Wins US House Approval.” Reuters, 7 May. Bibliography 211 Rugge, Fabio (2007). “Administrative Traditions in Western Europe.” In The Hand- book of Public Administration, edited by B. Guy Peters and Jon Pierre, 177–191. Beverly Hills: Sage. Sabatier, Paul A. (1988). “An Advocacy Coalition Framework of Policy Change and the Role of Policy-Oriented Learning Therein.” Policy Sciences 21 (2–3): 129–168. Sacchetti, Silvia, and Philip Tomlinson (2009). “Globalization: The Case of Two Mature European Industrial Districts.” European Planning Studies 17 (12): 1837–1859. Saint-Martin, Denis (2007). “Management Consultancy.” In The Oxford Handbook of Public Management, edited by Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, and Christopher Pollitt, 671–694. Oxford: Oxford University Press. —— (2001). “When Industrial Policy Shapes Public Sector Reform: Total Qual- ity Management in Britain and France.” West European Politics 24 (4): 105–124. Sakoh, Katsuro (1984). “Japanese Economic Success: Industrial Policy or Free Mar- ket.” Cato Journal 4 (2): 521–543. Sarangi, Satinath, and Gary Cohen (1995). “A Tale of Two Industrial Estates.” Eco- nomic and Political Weekly 30 (24): 1419–1422. Sassen, Saskia (1994). Cities in a World Economy. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. —— (2001). The Global City: New York, London, Tokyo. Princeton: Princeton Univer- sity Press. Saxenian, AnnaLee (1994). Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. —— (2000). Silicon Valley’s New Immigrant Entrepreneurs. La Jolla, CA: The Center for Comparative Immigration Studies. Schachter, Hindy Lauer, and Akira Nakamura (2011). “MITI and the Japanese Mir- acle Revisited: Reevaluation of the Administrative-Centered Government.” Public Administration Review 71(6): 931–933. Schmid, Allan (2004). Confl ict and Cooperation: Institutional and Behavioral Eco- nomics. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell. Schmidt, Vivien A. (2008). “Discursive Institutionalism: The Explanatory Power of Ideas and Discourse.” Political Science 11 (1): 303–326. Schrader, Ben (2012). Timeline – State Housing in New Zealand. Ministry for Culture and Heritage. 20 December. http://www.nzhistory.net.nz/culture/we-call-it- home/timeline (accessed 2 May, 2014). Schreiber, D.A. (2012) “On the Epistemology of Postmodern Spirituality.” Verbum et Ecclesia 33 (1): 1–8. Scott, Allen J., ed. (2001). Global City-Regions: Trends, Theory, Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Scott, James C. (1998). Seeing like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed. New Haven: Yale University Press. Segbers, Klaus, Simon Raiser, and Krister Volkmann (2007). The Making of Global City Regions: Johannesburg, Mumbai/Bombay, São Paulo, and Shanghai. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Serchuk, David (2009). “Revamping the Ratings Agencies.” Forbes, 21 April. Shalin, Dmitri N. (2012). “The Art of Dissent: Parody, Travesty and Irony in Late Soviet Culture.” Russian Culture: Paper 24. 212 Bibliography Shatkin, Gavin (2004). “Globalization and Local Leadership: Growth, Power and Politics in Thailand’s Eastern Seaboard.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 28 (1): 11–26. Shiller, Robert (2000). Irrational Exuberance. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Shirley, Mary (2008). Institutions and Development. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Sicsic, Henri-Paul (1993). Structural, Dynamic, and Stylistic Relationships in Proko- fi ev’s Sonatas No. 7 and No. 8. Doctoral thesis, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Simon, Herbert A. (1997). Administrative Behaviour: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organisations. New York: Free Press. —— (1991). “Bounded Rationality and Organizational Learning.” Organization Sci- ence 2 (1): 125–134. —— (1957). Models of Man: Social and Rational. New York: John Wiley & Sons. —— (1944). “Decision-making and administrative organization.” Public Administra- tion Review 4(1): 16–30. Sirota, David (2012). “Colorado’s Fracking Fight Gets Ugly.” Salon, 3 October. http://www.salon.com/2012/10/03/colorados_fracking_fight_gets_ugly/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). Smajgl, Alex, Anne Leitch, and Tim Lynam (2009). Outback Institutions: An Applica- tion of the Institutional Analysis and Development (IAD) Framework to Four Case Studies in Australia’s Outback. Report Number 31, Desert Knowledge CRC. Smith, Adam (1776). Wealth of Nations. London: Methuen. So, Man-shan, and Jianfa Shen (2004). “Measuring Urban Competitiveness in China.” Asian Geographer 23 (1–2): 71–91. Soja, Edward W. (1980). “The Socio-spatial Dialectic.” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 70 (2): 207–225. Sørensen, Eva, and Jacob Torfi ng (2012). “Introduction: Collaborative Innovation in the Public Sector.” Innovation Journal: The Public Sector Innovation Journal 17 (1): 1–14. Srinivasan, T.N. (2014). Convocation Remarks by Dr. T.N Srinivasan [IGIDR 11th Convocation] . April 7. http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=O8Oe3IP5hQ0 (accessed 2 May, 2014). Steinberg, Paul F. (2007). “Causal Assessment in Small-N Policy Studies.” Policy Studies Journal 35 (2): 181–204. Steup, Matthias (2005). Epistemology, Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. 14 Decem- ber. http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/epistemology/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). Stivers, Camilla (2007). “Toward a Feminist Perspective in Public Administration Theory.” In Classics of Public Administration, edited by Jay M. Shafritz, Albert C. Hyde, and Sandra J. Parkes, 49–65. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thomson Learning. Stone, Melissa M. (2012). “Challenges of Governing Partnerships: Collective (or Chaotic) Decision-Making in Complex Environments.” Nonprofi t Issues Forum, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, Atlanta. Straterra (n.d.). Fracking (Hydraulic Fracturing). http://archive-nz.com/nz/s/ straterra.co.nz/2013–07–31_2524100_3/Industry_Links_Straterra/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). Tang, Ching-Peng (2004). “When New Public Management Runs into Democratiza- tion: Taiwan’s Public Administration in Transition.” Issues and Studies 40 (3/4): 59–100. Bibliography 213 Taylor, Frederick (1911). The Principles of Scientifi c Management . London: Harper & Brothers. Tedeschi, Bob (2009). “Banks Bypassing Mortgage Brokers.” New York Times, 30 January. Thompson, Sarah, Mathew Dunckley, and Jamie Freed (2012). Fracking Moratorium for Victoria. 24 August. http://fw.farmonline.com.au/news/nationalrural/agri- business/general-news/fracking-moratorium-for-victoria/2620608.aspx (accessed 2 May, 2014). Thorns, David C. (2006). “The Remaking of Housing Policy: The New Zealand Housing Strategy for the 21st Century.” Housing Finance International 20 (4): 20–28. Thünen, Johann Heinrich von (1826). Der isolierte staat. Oxford: Pergamon Press. —— (1966). Isolated State: An English Edition of Der isolierte staat. Translated by Peter Hall. Oxford: Pergamon Press. Todd Energy (2012). Hydraulic Fracturing. Wellington: Todd Energy. Trefi s (2012). Chevron’s Fracking Plans for Romania Draw Heat Locally. 23 April. http://www.trefi s.com/stock/cvx/articles/115572/chevrons-fracking-plans-for- romania-draw-heat-locally/2012-04-23 (accessed November 23, 2012). Trembath, Alex, Jesse Jenkins, Ted Nordhaus, and Michael Shellenberger (2012). Where the Shale Gas Revolution Came From. Oakland, CA: Breakthrough Institute Energy and Climate Program. Tsuneishi, Takao (2007). “The Regional Development Policy of Thailand and Its Economic Cooperation with Neighboring Countries.” IDE Discussion Paper. No. 32. 2005.7. Turok, Ivan (2004). “Cities, Regions and Competitiveness.” Regional Studies 38 (9): 1069–1083. UK Offi ce of the Deputy Prime Minister (2004). The Social Exclusion Unit . London: UK Offi ce of the Deputy Prime Minister. United States Environmental Protection Agency [US EPA] (2012). Groundwater Investigation: Pavillion, Wyoming. Washington, DC: United States Environmental Protection Agency. US House of Representatives (2011). Chemicals Used in Hydraulic Fracturing . Wash- ington D.C.: US House of Representatives Committee on Energy and Commerce. Van Dijk, Meine Pieter, and Arni Sverrisson (2003). “Enterprise Clusters in Develop- ing Countries: Mechanisms of Transition and Stagnation.” Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 15: 183–206. Van Dooren, Wouter, Geert Bouckaert, and John Halligan (2010). Performance Man- agement. London: Routledge. Veblen, Thorstein (1919). The Place of Science in Modern Civilisation. New York: B.W. Huebsch. Vernon, Raymond (1960). Metropolis 1985: An Interpretation of the Findings of the New York Metropolitan Region Study. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Vigoda, Eran (2002). “From Responsiveness to Collaboration: Governance, Citizens, and the Next Generation of Public Administration.” Public Administration Review 62 (5): 527–540. Vorlaufer, Karl (1986). “Industrial Estates in Kenya – Instruments of Industrialization and Regional Development.” Erdkunde 40 (1): 45–62. 214 Bibliography Waghorn, Brenna (n.d.). Urban Intensifi cation in Auckland – Are We Growing Smarter? Auckland: Auckland Regional Council. Wahl, A.M. Eduards, C. Holgersson, P. Hook, S. Linghag, and M. Ronnblom (2008). Motstånd och fantasi: Historien om F. Lund, Sweden: Studentlitteratur. Waldo, Dwight (1948). The Administrative State: A Study of the Political Theory of American Public Administration. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers. Wang, Xiaocong (2012). “Environmental Frets as Frackers Move In. ” CaixinOnline . 20 November. http://english.caixin.com/2012-11-20/100462881.html (accessed 6 July, 2014). Wattanadumrong, Bhagaporn, Alan Collins, and Martin Snell (2012). “Still Big in Bangkok? An Empirical Analysis of the Regional Distribution of Foreign Direct Investment in Thailand.” International Journal of the Economics of Business 17 (3): 329–348. Weber, Alfred (1929). Theory of the Location of Industries. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Weber, Edward (2012). “Unleashing the Potential of Collaborative Governance Arrangements: Getting to Robust Durability in the Blackfoot Valley.” Journal of Sustainable Development 5 (7): 35–47. Weber, Edward, and Anne M. Khademian (2008a). “Managing Collaborative Pro- cesses: Common Practices, Uncommon Circumstances.” Administration and Soci- ety 40 (5): 431–464. —— (2008b). “Wicked Problems, Knowledge Challenges, and Collaborative Capac- ity Builders in Network Settings.” Public Administration Review 68 (2): 334–349. Weber, Max (1922). Economy and Society . Ed. Guenther Roth and Klaus Wittich . New York: Bedminster P (1968). —— (1949). The Methodology of the Social Sciences. New York: Free Press. Webster, Douglas (2002). On the Edge: Shaping the Future of Peri-urban East Asia. Palo Alto, CA: Asia-Pacifi c Research Center, Stanford University. Weimer, David, and Aidan R. Vining (2010). Policy Analysis: Concepts and Practice. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall. Weiwei, Zhang (2012). “Meritocracy versus Democracy.” New York Times, 9 November. Williamson, Oliver E. (1981). “The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach.” American Journal of Sociology 87: 548–577. —— (1979). “Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Rela- tions.” Journal of Law and Economics 22 (2): 233–261. Wilson, W. (1887). The Study of Administration. Political Science Quarterly , 2(2): 197–222. Wirutskulshai, Uma, Edsel Sajor, and Nowarat Coowanitwong (2011). “Importance of Context in Adoption and Progress in Application of Strategic Environmental Assessment.” Environmental Impact Assessment Review 31 (3): 352–359. Wise, Lois R. (2007). “Representative Bureaucracy.” In Handbook of Public Admin- istration: Concise Paperback Edition, edited B. Guy Peters and Jon Pierre, 223–233. Beverly Hills: Sage. World Bank (2002a). Building Institutions for Markets. Washington, DC: World Bank. —— (2012a). Data. http://data.worldbank.org/ (accessed 2 May, 2014). —— (2012b). Doing Business 2013: Smarter Regulations for Small and Medium-Size Enterprises. Washington, DC: World Bank International Finance Corporation. Bibliography 215 —— (2002b). World Development Report. Washington, DC: World Bank. Wu, Fulong, and Jingxing Zhang (2007). “Planning the Competitive City-Region: The Emergence of Strategic Development Plan in China.” Urban Affairs Review 42 (5): 714–740. Wu, Yu-Shan (2007). “Taiwan’s Developmental State: After the Economic and Politi- cal Turmoil.” Asian Survey 47 (6): 977–1001. Yeung, Henry Wai-chung (2005). “Institutional Capacity and Singapore’s Develop- mental State.” In Globalisation and Economic Security in East Asia: Governance and Institutions, edited by Helen Nesadurai, 85–106. London: Routledge. —— (2000). “Organizing ‘the Firm’ in Industrial Geography: Networks, Institutions, and Regional Development.” Progress in Human Geography 24 (2): 301–315. Yeung, Henry Wai-chung, and George Lin (2003). “Theorizing Economic Geogra- phies of Asia.” Economic Geography 79 (2): 107–128. Zhang, Hanyu (2011). “Studies on Tourism Destination Governance from the Per- spective of Institutional Economics: Retrospect and Prospect.” 3rd International Conference on Information and Financial Engineering, IPEDR, vol. 12.

This page intentionally left blank