Chapter 9 Monopoly
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Microeconomics Exam Review Chapters 8 Through 12, 16, 17 and 19
MICROECONOMICS EXAM REVIEW CHAPTERS 8 THROUGH 12, 16, 17 AND 19 Key Terms and Concepts to Know CHAPTER 8 - PERFECT COMPETITION I. An Introduction to Perfect Competition A. Perfectly Competitive Market Structure: • Has many buyers and sellers. • Sells a commodity or standardized product. • Has buyers and sellers who are fully informed. • Has firms and resources that are freely mobile. • Perfectly competitive firm is a price taker; one firm has no control over price. B. Demand Under Perfect Competition: Horizontal line at the market price II. Short-Run Profit Maximization A. Total Revenue Minus Total Cost: The firm maximizes economic profit by finding the quantity at which total revenue exceeds total cost by the greatest amount. B. Marginal Revenue Equals Marginal Cost in Equilibrium • Marginal Revenue: The change in total revenue from selling another unit of output: • MR = ΔTR/Δq • In perfect competition, marginal revenue equals market price. • Market price = Marginal revenue = Average revenue • The firm increases output as long as marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost. • Golden rule of profit maximization. The firm maximizes profit by producing where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. C. Economic Profit in Short-Run: Because the marginal revenue curve is horizontal at the market price, it is also the firm’s demand curve. The firm can sell any quantity at this price. III. Minimizing Short-Run Losses The short run is defined as a period too short to allow existing firms to leave the industry. The following is a summary of short-run behavior: A. Fixed Costs and Minimizing Losses: If a firm shuts down, it must still pay fixed costs. -
1 Bertrand Model
ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1 Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition Both the monopoly and the perfectly competitive market structure has in common is that neither has to concern itself with the strategic choices of its competition. In the former, this is trivially true since there isn't any competition. While the latter is so insignificant that the single firm has no effect. In an oligopoly where there is more than one firm, and yet because the number of firms are small, they each have to consider what the other does. Consider the product launch decision, and pricing decision of Apple in relation to the IPOD models. If the features of the models it has in the line up is similar to Creative Technology's, it would have to be concerned with the pricing decision, and the timing of its announcement in relation to that of the other firm. We will now begin the exposition of Oligopolistic Competition. 1 Bertrand Model Firms can compete on several variables, and levels, for example, they can compete based on their choices of prices, quantity, and quality. The most basic and funda- mental competition pertains to pricing choices. The Bertrand Model is examines the interdependence between rivals' decisions in terms of pricing decisions. The assumptions of the model are: 1. 2 firms in the market, i 2 f1; 2g. 2. Goods produced are homogenous, ) products are perfect substitutes. 3. Firms set prices simultaneously. 4. Each firm has the same constant marginal cost of c. What is the equilibrium, or best strategy of each firm? The answer is that both firms will set the same prices, p1 = p2 = p, and that it will be equal to the marginal ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 2 cost, in other words, the perfectly competitive outcome. -
Amazon's Antitrust Paradox
LINA M. KHAN Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox abstract. Amazon is the titan of twenty-first century commerce. In addition to being a re- tailer, it is now a marketing platform, a delivery and logistics network, a payment service, a credit lender, an auction house, a major book publisher, a producer of television and films, a fashion designer, a hardware manufacturer, and a leading host of cloud server space. Although Amazon has clocked staggering growth, it generates meager profits, choosing to price below-cost and ex- pand widely instead. Through this strategy, the company has positioned itself at the center of e- commerce and now serves as essential infrastructure for a host of other businesses that depend upon it. Elements of the firm’s structure and conduct pose anticompetitive concerns—yet it has escaped antitrust scrutiny. This Note argues that the current framework in antitrust—specifically its pegging competi- tion to “consumer welfare,” defined as short-term price effects—is unequipped to capture the ar- chitecture of market power in the modern economy. We cannot cognize the potential harms to competition posed by Amazon’s dominance if we measure competition primarily through price and output. Specifically, current doctrine underappreciates the risk of predatory pricing and how integration across distinct business lines may prove anticompetitive. These concerns are height- ened in the context of online platforms for two reasons. First, the economics of platform markets create incentives for a company to pursue growth over profits, a strategy that investors have re- warded. Under these conditions, predatory pricing becomes highly rational—even as existing doctrine treats it as irrational and therefore implausible. -
“Single” Monopoly Profit Theory and Its' Exceptions
“Single” Monopoly Profit Theory and its’ exceptions Liberty Mncube Chief Economist Competition Commission South Africa 27/04/2016 ICN Singapore 1 Example: Maintaining the monopoly in the tying product – “Single” Monopoly Profit Theory • Loosely based on a current case, awaiting for adjudication by the Tribunal • Two separate markets – one for embossing machines (the machine used to emboss a blank number plate) and one for blank number plates • To operate a number plate embossing shop, one – Necessary conditions for it to requires both products – the machine and blank hold include: number plates on which to emboss on 1. The monopolist has a durable and unregulated • AN Plates has a monopoly in manufacturing monopoly embossing machines 2. Products are consumed in • AN Plates was a small player (2009) in fixed proportions manufacturing blank number plates 3. Consumers have identical • The single monopoly profit theory suggests that preferences AN plates would have no incentive to tie its 4. No efficiencies of number plates to the embossing machines integration • AN Plates would simply extract its all the monopoly profits from selling embossing machines at a monopoly price 2 Example: Maintaining the monopoly in the tying product • The SMP theory assumes a durable monopoly in the • In 2009, AN Plates introduced exclusive manufacturing of embossing machines supply contracts to its customers • These contracts ensure that any customer • If this is not the case, tying then becomes a way to that purchases an embossing machine maintain the monopoly in the manufacturing of from AN Plates will procure all of their embossing machines blank number plate requirements exclusively from AN Plates • Without tying, firms that produce the blank number • Customers enter into these contracts for plates could use the entry as a foothold for entering five years. -
Apple and Amazon's Antitrust Antics
APPLE AND AMAZON’S ANTITRUST ANTICS: TWO WRONGS DON’T MAKE A RIGHT, BUT MAYBE THEY SHOULD Kerry Gutknecht‡ I. INTRODUCTION The exploding market for books of all kinds in the form of digital files (“e- books”), which can be read on mobile devices and personal computers, has attracted aggressive competition between the two leading online e-book retail- ers, Amazon, Inc. (“Amazon”) and Apple Inc. (“Apple”).1 While both Amazon and Apple have been accused by critics of engaging in anticompetitive practic- es with regard to e-book sales,2 the U.S. Department of Justice has focused on Apple. In 2012, federal prosecutors brought an antitrust suit against Apple and five of the nation’s largest book publishers—HarperCollins Publishers LLC (“HarperCollins”), Hachette Book Group, Inc. and Hachette Digital (“Hachette”); Holtzbrinck Publishers, LLC d/b/a Macmillan (“Macmillan”); Penguin Group (USA), Inc. (“Penguin”); and Simon & Schuster, Inc. and (“Simon & Schuster”) (collectively, the “Publisher Defendants”)3—for collud- ing in violation of the Sherman Act to raise the retail prices of e-books.4 Each ‡ J.D. Candidate, May 2014, The Catholic University of America, Columbus School of Law. The author would like to thank Calla Brown for her daily support and the CommLaw Conspectus staff for their diligent effort during the writing and editing process. Finally, a special thanks to Antonio F. Perez for providing expert advice during the writing of this paper. 1 Complaint at 2–3, United States v. Apple Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638 (S.D.N.Y. 2013) (No. 12 CV 2826) [hereinafter Complaint]. -
The Marginal Cost Controversy in Intellectual Property John F Duffyt
The Marginal Cost Controversy in Intellectual Property John F Duffyt In 1938, Harold Hotelling formally advanced the position that "the optimum of the general welfare corresponds to the sale of everything at marginal cost."' To reach this optimum, Hotelling argued, general gov- ernment revenues should "be applied to cover the fixed costs of electric power plants, waterworks, railroad, and other industries in which the fixed costs are large, so as to reduce to the level of marginal cost the prices charged for the services and products of these industries."2 Other major economists of the day subsequently endorsed Hotelling's view' and, in the late 1930s and early 1940s, it "aroused considerable interest and [had] al- ready found its way into some textbooks on public utility economics."' In his 1946 article, The MarginalCost Controversy,Ronald Coase set forth a detailed rejoinder to the Hotelling thesis, concluding that the social subsidies proposed by Hotelling "would bring about a maldistribu- tion of the factors of production, a maldistribution of income and proba- bly a loss similar to that which the scheme was designed to avoid."' The article, which Richard Posner would later hail as Coase's "most impor- tant" contribution to the field of public utility pricing,6 was part of a wave of literature debating the merits of the Hotelling proposal.' Yet the very success of the critique by Coase and others has led to the entire contro- t Professor of Law, George Washington University Law School. The author thanks Michael Abramowicz. Richard Hynes, Eric Kades. Doug Lichtman, Chip Lupu, Alan Meese, Richard Pierce, Anne Sprightley Ryan, and Joshua Schwartz for comments on earlier drafts. -
ECON 301 Notes 10
Intermediate Microeconomics MONOPOLY BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY Price making A monopoly seller in a goods market is the conceptual opposite from perfectly competitive firms. ◦ The monopolist does not face competition from other firms because he is the only seller. ◦ He is still constrained in his behavior, however, by consumers’ willingness to pay for his output, i.e., by the demand curve. A monopolist faces the entire market demand for his good, though, so when he chooses an output level, he implicitly determines the price. ◦ Thus the term “price maker”. Competitive firm’s demand curve Monopolist’s demand curve Total revenue Competitive firms get the same price for all units sold, so: = . ∗ If a monopolist wants to sell more, he has to cut the price on all units sold. TR is still equal to , but P* is now a function of Q. ◦ Note: Q as market quantity∗ as distinct from q for firm’s quantity. Specifically the demand curve tells you P* as a function of Q. Example Say that market demand is given by: 1 = 10 20 2 . and the inverse demand you see− on Marshall’s diagram: = 200– 20 . 1 2 = , where P is given by the inverse demand function. = 200 20 . 1 = – 20 2. − 3 2 Taking the partial derivative 200 to get MR: = 200 30 . 1 2 − MR is below the price q* The product rule in calculus The basic reason that < for a firm facing downward- sloping demand has to do with the product rule in calculus. The product rule is as follows: when you multiply two functions of the same variable together, the differential of the product is: ( ) ( ) ( ) = ℎ ≡ +∗ ℎ � � The product rule in calculus So if ( ) = , and ( ) = [ ] = ( ), = , and = = ∗ + . -
Imperfect Competition: Monopoly
Imperfect Competition: Monopoly New Topic: Monopoly Q: What is a monopoly? A monopoly is a firm that faces a downward sloping demand, and has a choice about what price to charge – an increase in price doesn’t send most or all of the customers away to rivals. A Monopolistic Market consists of a single seller facing many buyers. Monopoly Q: What are examples of monopolies? There is one producer of aircraft carriers, but there few pure monopolies in the world - US postal mail faces competition from Fed-ex - Microsoft faces competition from Apple or Linux - Google faces competition from Yahoo and Bing - Facebook faces competition from Twitter, IG, Google+ But many firms have some market power- can increase prices above marginal costs for a long period of time, without driving away consumers. Monopoly’s problem 3 Example: A monopolist faces demand given by p(q) 12 q There are no variable costs and all fixed costs are sunk. How many units should the monopoly produce and what price should it charge? By increasing quantity from 2 units to 5 units, the monopolist reduces the price from $10 to $7. The revenue gained is area III, the revenue lost is area I. The slope of the demand curve determines the optimal quantity and price. Monopoly’s problem 4 The monopoly faces a downward sloping demand curve and chooses both prices and quantity to maximize profits. We let the monopoly choose quantity q and the demand determine the price p(q) because it is more convenient. TR(q) p(q) MR [ p(q)q] q p(q) q q q • The monopoly’s chooses q to maximize profit: max (q) TR(q) TC(q) p(q)q TC(q) q The FONC gives: Marginal revenue 5 TR(q) p(q) The marginal revenue MR(q) p(q) q q q p Key property: The marginal revenue is below the demand curve: MR(q) p(q) Example: demand is p(q) =12-q. -
3. Labor Demand 3A. Labor Demand Model 3B. Short-Run Labor Demand 3B. Short-Run (Cont.)
3. Labor Demand 3A. Labor Demand Model E151A: C.Cameron n What happens when wage changes? 1. Firms maximize profit (rev - cost). In short-run? Implies produce where marginal profit = zero. In long-run? Maintained assumption throughout course. n What happens if markets are not 2. Two homogeneous factors of competitive due to monopoly or production: labor and capital. monopsony? Q = f(K, L) (Relaxed later) n What is effect of payroll tax? a. Short-run (capital is fixed) b. Long-run (capital may vary) 3A. Model (cont.) 3A. Model (cont.) 3. Price of labor = hourly wage rate. 4. Firms are price-takers in input and output markets. Implies no fringe benefits and no distinction Then marginal cost equals price between increasing labor by increasing the and marginal revenue equals price. number of workers and increasing labor by having current workers work more. Relax to allow: Monopoly: Price-maker in output good market Relax this assumption in ch. 5. Monopsony: Price-maker in input good market 3B. Short-Run (cont.) 3B. Short-Run Labor Demand n Price-taker in labor market: n MRP = Marginal Revenue Product of L L Then always MEL = w = Increase in Revenue due to So hire until MRPL = w one unit increase in Labor So MRPL curve is labor demand curve. = MR x P (P is price) n Price-taker in output market n ME = Marginal Revenue Product of L L Then always MRPL = MPLxP = Increase in Expenses due to n So in competitive markets hire until one unit increase in Labor MPLxP = w or MPL= w/P n L L Profit-maximizer hires until MRPL = MEL n MPL slopes down Þ DL slopes down 1 MRPL IS LABOR DEMAND CURVE 3C. -
Monopoly Monopoly Definition a Firm Is Considered a Monopoly If . . . It Is the Sole Seller of Its Product. Its Product Does
Monopoly Monopoly Definition Herbert Stocker [email protected] A firm is considered a monopoly if . Institute of International Studies University of Ramkhamhaeng it is the sole seller of its product. & Department of Economics University of Innsbruck its product does not have close substitutes. Repetition Repetition Remember: Technological restrictions are the same for Remember: monopolies and for firms on perfectly Firms maximize their profits subject to the competitive markets. restrictions they face. These are embedded in the cost function: There are two kinds of restrictions: Remember that we did not need the price of Technological restrictions. output for the derivation of the cost function! Market restrictions. Only market restrictions differ between monopolies and firms on perfectly competitive markets. 1 Monopoly & Perfect Competition Monopoly & Perfect Competition Monopoly: A Monopolist is the only supplier and there are no close substitutes for his Perfect Competition: Every supplier product. Therefore he perceives that the perceives demand for his own product as demand for his product is falling when he perfectly elastic, he can sell every unit of increases price. output for the same price. Monopolistic firms are price-seekers; if they Therefore, marginal revenue is simply the price, want to sell more, they can do so only at a and firms are price-takers! lower price! This has important implications for the marginal revenue of a monopoly, e.g. marginal revenue no longer equals price! Perfect Competition vs. Monopoly Total and Marginal Revenue Perfect Competition: Monopoly: Example: P P ‘perceived’ ‘perceived’ Market Demand Market Demand Q = 6 − P Total Marginal Average Price Quantity Revenue Revenue Revenue PQ R = P × Q MR AR = P 6 0 0 – – 5 1 5 5 5 4 2 8 3 4 Q Q 3 3 9 1 3 Each producer perceives the Monopolist perceives demand 2 4 8 −1 2 to be less than perfectly demand for his product as 1 5 5 −3 1 elastic. -
The Revenue Functions of a Monopoly
SOLUTIONS 3 Microeconomics ACTIVITY 3-10 The Revenue Functions of a Monopoly At the opposite end of the market spectrum from perfect competition is monopoly. A monopoly exists when only one firm sells the good or service. This means the monopolist faces the market demand curve since it has no competition from other firms. If the monopolist wants to sell more of its product, it will have to lower its price. As a result, the price (P) at which an extra unit of output (Q) is sold will be greater than the marginal revenue (MR) from that unit. Student Alert: P is greater than MR for a monopolist. 1. Table 3-10.1 has information about the demand and revenue functions of the Moonglow Monopoly Company. Complete the table. Assume the monopoly charges each buyer the same P (i.e., there is no price discrimination). Enter the MR values at the higher of the two Q levels. For example, since total revenue (TR) increases by $37.50 when the firm increases Q from two to three units, put “+$37.50” in the MR column for Q = 3. Table 3-10.1 The Moonglow Monopoly Company Average revenue Q P TR MR (AR) 0 $100.00 $0.00 – – 1 $87.50 $87.50 +$87.50 $87.50 2 $75.00 $150.00 +$62.50 $75.00 3 $62.50 $187.50 +$37.50 $62.50 4 $50.00 $200.00 +$12.50 $50.00 5 $37.50 $187.50 –$12.50 $37.50 6 $25.00 $150.00 –$37.50 $25.00 7 $12.50 $87.50 –$62.50 $12.50 8 $0.00 $0.00 –$87.50 $0.00 2. -
Legal Restrictions on Exploitation of the Patent Monopoly: an Economic Analysis
The Yale Law Journal Volume 76, No. 2, December 1966 Legal Restrictions on Exploitation of the Patent Monopoly: An Economic Analysis William F. Baxter* I. A Frame of Reference The patent laws confer on a patentee power to exclude all others from making, using or selling his invention.' In furtherance of a con- stitutionally recognized goal-"To promote the Progress of Science and the useful Arts"-Congress has thus adopted a constitutionally authorized means--"securing... to Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective . Discoveries."2 The constitutional clause is re- markable in several respects. Its recognition of the possibility that invention might require encouragement implies not only that techno- logical innovation is desirable but also that, but for legal subsidization, the quantity of innovation forthcoming would or might be less than optimum. This recognition, coming on the morn of an era during which the tendency of a free market to achieve optimality in all activ- ities was greatly and religiously overestimated, 3 prompts brief inquiry into the soundness of the supposition. Several considerations support the view that the market would yield less than optimum innovative activity.4 Invention consists primarily of knowledge; and he whose research, experimentation and insight has * Professor of Law, Stanford University. A.B. 1951, LLB. 1956, Stanford University. 1. 35 U.S.C. § 154 (1964). 2. US. CoNsr. art.I, § 8. 3. Cf. JAFFE, A m mTr LAw, CASES AND MATERus 3-8 (1954). 4. See, e.g., Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources For Invention, in THE RATE AND DIRECTION or INVENTIVE Acrrvry: ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL FAcTOrtS 609 (1962); Machiup, An Economic Review of the Patent System, Study #15 of the Sub.