Walking a Tightrope: the Neoclassical Synthesis in Action
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
KALDOR's WAR J.E. King*
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 1441-5429 DISCUSSION PAPER 25/07 KALDOR’S WAR * J.E. King * Department of Economics and Finance, La Trobe University, Victoria 3086, Australia Email: [email protected] © 2007 J.E. King All rights reserved. No part of this paper may be reproduced in any form, or stored in a retrieval system, without the prior written permission of the author. Introduction In the 1930s the young Nicholas Kaldor (1908-1986) established himself as one of the world’s leading economic theorists (King 2007). As with so many lives, Kaldor’s was turned around by the Second World War. This was not the result of enemy action. Although his family in Hungary suffered grievously at the hands of the Nazis, Nicky himself was not called to arms. While he had become a British citizen in 1934, and made enquiries about joining the Civil Service as an economic advisor, he was told that his Hungarian origins would disqualify him from anything other than menial duties in Whitehall. He therefore decided to stay in academia, and relocated to Cambridge with his remaining LSE colleagues in September 1939, when the Ministry of Works took over the School’s Aldwych site in central London .1 Now based at Peterhouse, Kaldor was able to deepen old friendships and develop new ones. A ‘war circus’ of economists began to operate, named by analogy with the ‘Cambridge circus’ of young theorists who had interrogated Keynes in 1930- 1 after the publication of the Treatise on Money and helped to focus his mind on the revolutionary breakthrough of the General Theory (Moggridge 1995, pp. -
Nicholas Kaldor
PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS 26 NICHOLAS KALDOR NICHOLAS KALDOR – ONE OF THE FIRST CRITICS OF MONETARISM doc. Ing. Ján Iša, DrSc. Known in economic circles as one of the thought in several fields, but it was his work founders of Post-Keynesianism, Nicholas on the theory of distribution and economic Kaldor (1908–1986) ranks among the worl- growth that stirred the greatest reaction. d's foremost economists of the second half Less well-known, however, is Kaldor's con- of the 20th century. Kaldor contributed to tribution to monetary theory, which has long the development of modern economic been standing quietly in the background. Nicholas Kaldor was born in Budapest on 12 May 1908. rous Third World countries, as well as an advisor to central His father was a lawyer and his mother came from wealthy banks and to the United Nations Economic Commission for business family. Although his father had wanted him to Latin America. Most significant, however, was his role as an study law, Kaldor opted for economics. He began his studi- advisor to Labour finance ministers from 1964 to 1968 and es at the University of Berlin in 1925 and then after two 1974 to 1976. After completing his two-year mission in years moved to the London School of Economics (LSE), Geneva in 1949, Kaldor began to work at Cambridge Uni- from which he graduated in 1930. He remained at the LSE versity and became, as John Maynard Keynes had been, a as lecturer until 1947, during which time his colleagues inc- fellow of King's College, Cambridge. -
Nobel Memoir
Memoir JOSEPH E. STIGLITZ I was born in Gary, Indiana, at the time, a major steel town on the southern shores of Lake Michigan, on February 9, 1943. Both of my parents were born within six miles of Gary, early in the century, and continued to live in the area until 1997. I sometimes thought that my perignations made up for their stability. There must have been something in the air of Gary that led one into economics: the first Nobel Prize winner, Paul Samuelson, was also from Gary, as were several other distinguished economists. (Paul allegedly once wrote a letter of recommendation for me which summarized my accomplishments by saying that I was the best economist from Gary, Indiana.) Certainly, the poverty, the discrimination, the episodic unemployment could not but strike an inquiring youngster: why did these exist, and what could we do about them. I grew up in a family in which political issues were often discussed, and debated intensely. My mother’s family were New Deal Democrats—they worshipped FDR; and though my uncle was a highly successful lawyer and real estate entrepreneur, he was staunchly pro-labor. My father, on the other hand, was probably more aptly described as a Jeffersonian democrat; a small businessman (an independent insurance agent) himself, he repeatedly spoke of the virtues of self-employment, of being one’s own boss, of self-reliance. He worried about big business, and valued our competition laws. I saw him, conservative by nature, buffeted by the marked changes in American society during the near-century of his life, and adapt to these changes. -
Welfare Goal in Antitrust Journals.Sagepub.Com/Home/Abx
The Antitrust Bulletin 1-39 ª The Author(s) 2018 The Unsound Theory Behind Article reuse guidelines: sagepub.com/journals-permissions the Consumer (and Total) DOI: 10.1177/0003603X18807802 Welfare Goal in Antitrust journals.sagepub.com/home/abx Mark Glick* Abstract This is the first installment of a two-part commentary on the New Brandeis School (the “New Brandeisians”) in Antitrust. In this first part, I examine why the New Brandeisians are correct to reject the consumer welfare standard. Instead of arguing, as the New Brandeisians do, that the consumer welfare standard leads to unacceptable outcomes, I argue that the consumer or total welfare standard was theoretically flawed and unrigorous from the start. My basic argument is that antitrust law addresses the impact of business strategies in markets where there are winners and losers. For example, in the classical exclusionary monopolist case, the monopolist’s conduct is enjoined to increase competition in the affected market or markets. As a result of the intervention, consumers benefit, but the monopolist is worse off. One hundred years of analysis by the welfare economists themselves shows that in such situations “welfare” or “consumer welfare” cannot be used as a reliable guide to assess the results of antitrust policy. Pareto Optimality does not apply in these situations because there are losers. Absent an ability to divine “cardinal utility” from obser- vations of market behavior, other approaches such as consumer surplus, and compensating and equivalent variation cannot be coherently extended from the individual level to markets. The Kaldor-Hicks compensation principle that is in standard use in law and economics was created to address problems of interpersonal comparisons of utility and the existence of winners and losers. -
Capitalism and Society
Capitalism and Society Volume 3, Issue 3 2008 Article 2 The Many Contributions of Edmund Phelps: American Economic Association Luncheon Speech Honoring the 2006 Nobel Laureate in Economics James J. Heckman∗ ∗University of Chicago; Geary Institute, University College Dublin; and the American Bar Foundation Copyright c 2008 The Berkeley Electronic Press. All rights reserved. Heckman: The Many Contributions of Edmund Phelps The following speech was given at the American Economic Association Annual Meetings, New Orleans, January 5, 2008. This draft was revised August 14, 2008. This research was supported by the American Bar Foundation and the Geary Institute, University College Dublin. Throughout his career, Ned Phelps has made fundamental contributions to growth theory, macroeconomics, public finance and social welfare theory that deserved the high recognition accorded by the Nobel Prize committee in October, 2006. He is one of the most original thinkers in economics. The citation issued when Phelps was made a Distinguished Fellow of the American Economic Association still speaks for the community of economists today: The collection of papers from a conference that he organized, Microeconomic Foundations, pushed questions about theoretical foundations to the front of the research agenda and changed forever our notion of what constitutes an acceptable macroeconomic theory... Throughout his career Phelps has been willing to step outside of the existing analytical framework and rethink the basic issues... He continues to push theorists and policy makers to rethink their analysis of expectations, inflation, and unemployment and to set a high standard for what it means to be an economic theorist. (American Economic Association 2001) Phelps’s output of original concepts, models and theorems has been vast. -
Anticipations of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen Mechanism1
Anticipations of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen Mechanism1 André Roncaglia de Carvalho2 ABSTRACT This paper aims to contribute to the literature on the intellectual history of the economics discipline in Brazil and its place within the network of international transmission of economic ideas, by delving into the history of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen mechanism, namely: the behavior of periodically-adjusted fixed nominal wages under persistent inflationary conditions (the sawtooth wages model). Ranging from the immediate post-War years to the end of the 1960s, our narrative reveals that prior to Nicholas Kaldor’s statement of the sawtooth model of real wages, other contributions sprung from various traditions. To this effect, we underline the discoursive appraisal by Celso Furtado (1954) and the early neoclassical model by Bent Hansen (1951), only to fit both of them in a broader historical context of the economics discipline, whereby the emergence of formal mathematical methods allows for the connection between this debate and the Operations Research Program in the North-American universities in the early 1950s. Keywords: chronic inflation, sawtooth model, formal mechanic models, Celso Furtado Operations Research Program RESUMO Este artigo busca contribuir com a literatura de história da ciência econômica no Brazil e seu lugar na rede internacional de transmissão das ideias econônomicas, por meio de uma análise da história do mecanismo Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen, qual seja: o comportamento de rendas nominais fixas com reajustamento periódico sob inflação -
Three Revolutions in Macroeconomics: Their Nature and Influence
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Laidler, David Working Paper Three revolutions in macroeconomics: Their nature and influence EPRI Working Paper, No. 2013-4 Provided in Cooperation with: Economic Policy Research Institute (EPRI), Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario Suggested Citation: Laidler, David (2013) : Three revolutions in macroeconomics: Their nature and influence, EPRI Working Paper, No. 2013-4, The University of Western Ontario, Economic Policy Research Institute (EPRI), London (Ontario) This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/123484 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen -
Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics
Munich Personal RePEc Archive Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics Azad, Rohit The New School for Social Research, Columbia University, Jawaharlal Nehru University 1 October 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/80056/ MPRA Paper No. 80056, posted 08 Jul 2017 14:35 UTC Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics Rohit Azad 1 Introduction In the aftermath of the Great Depression, there was turmoil in the field of Macroeconomics, which resulted in the Keynesian ‘revolution’. However, the current Great Recession, the worst crisis that capitalism has faced since then, has failed, at least so far, to generate an upheaval in the teaching and practice of Macroeconomics. This seems bizarre as if nothing has happened and the economists are just going about doing business as usual. Without going into the politics of why this is so, let me just focus on how Macroeconomics ought to be taught to students at the intermediate level, which gives them an overall perspective on the subject1. I must note that this article has been inspired by an editorial published in EPW [2013]. Macroeconomics as a subject proper came into existence with the writ- ings of John Maynard Keynes2. There were debates during his time about how to characterise a capitalist economy, most of these are still a part of the discussion among economists. Keynes [1936, 1937] argued that capitalism is a fundamentally unstable system so the state needs to intervene to control this instability. Keynes [1936] has been interpreted in different, often contradictory, ways. In today’s context, they can be broadly classified in two categories: Post Keynesian and New Keynesian. -
Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative -
Mythical Expectations
The University of Notre Dame Australia ResearchOnline@ND Business Book Chapters School of Business 2008 Mythical Expectations Robert Leeson University of Notre Dame Australia, [email protected] Warren Young Follow this and additional works at: https://researchonline.nd.edu.au/bus_chapters Recommended Citation Leeson, R., & Young, W. (2008). Mythical expectations. In R. Leeson (Ed). The anti-Keynesian tradition. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. This Book Chapter is brought to you by the School of Business at ResearchOnline@ND. It has been accepted for inclusion in Business Book Chapters by an authorized administrator of ResearchOnline@ND. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Chapter 7 Mythical Expectations Robert Leeson and Warren Young According to the conventional account, economists have relied on three types of expectations: static (contained in the original Keynesian Phillips curve); adaptive (introduced by Milton Friedman’s in the course of his Monetarist counter-revolution) and rational (part of Robert Lucas’s natural rate New Classical counter revolution). This chapter argues that there a fourth expectational type: the myths associated with these natural rate counter revolutions. The conventional chronology regarding the relationship between expectations and the Phillips curve is that Friedman's 1967 AEA Presidential Address (Friedman, 1968a) transformed macroeconomics by focusing on the neglect of expectations in the Keynesian Phillips curve. However, the archival evidence reveals this conventional account to be both inadequate and inaccurate . In this chapter, it will be shown that Phillips allocated a more destabilising role to inflationary expectations than did Friedman and that the adaptive expectations formula used to undermine the original Phillips curve was actually provided to Friedman by Phillips. -
Paul Samuelson's Ways to Macroeconomic Dynamics
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Boianovsky, Mauro Working Paper Paul Samuelson's ways to macroeconomic dynamics CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2019-08 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Boianovsky, Mauro (2019) : Paul Samuelson's ways to macroeconomic dynamics, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2019-08, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/196831 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Paul Samuelson’s Ways to Macroeconomic Dynamics by Mauro Boianovsky CHOPE Working Paper No. 2019-08 May 2019 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3386201 1 Paul Samuelson’s ways to macroeconomic dynamics Mauro Boianovsky (Universidade de Brasilia) [email protected] First preliminary draft. -
The Impact of the Translations of Keynes’ Works on the Romanian Thought
518297-LLP-2011-IT-ERASMUS-FEXI THE IMPACT OF THE TRANSLATION OF KEYNES’ WORK ON THE ROMANIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT CHIARA BENVENUTI UNIVERSITY OF BUCHAREST BUCHAREST, ROMANIA [email protected] CONTENTS THE IMPACT OF THE TRANSLATIONS OF KEYNES’ WORKS ON THE ROMANIAN THOUGHT ABSTRACT The objective of this reading guide is to present the main interpretations of Keynes’ work as developed by Romanian authors. More, specifically, this guide aims to specify what shaped the result of translation through an analysis of the adaptation of economic ideas in the context of the most important features and trends defining Romanian economics and the Romanian economic thought before and the decade after the political and economic changes of 1989. 1. KEYNES’ GENERAL THEORY AND THE “NEOCLASSICAL SYNTHESIS” CONSENSUS There is a consensus among the economists that the political economy idea diffused in Eastern Europe and the paradigm shift brought by them were defined in terms of a specific post-war development of Western economics known as neoclassical synthesis (Aligica & Evans 2008) The angular stone of the paradigm was Keynes‘ General Theory (1936), an initially obscure book proposing a theory where involuntary unemployment was attributed to a deficiency in aggregate demand. After the Second World War, what was understood as ”Keynesianism” was in fact a synthesis between neoclassical economics and the ”orthodox” Keynes of the General Theory (Hall 1989). In the neo-Keynesian model the neoclassical model of Smith and Marshall was assumed to hold in the long-run while the Keynesian one was applicable in the short run and for situations when the economic situation was marked by sticky wages, liquidity traps and interest-insensitive investment.