Flexible Exchange Rates in the Short Run

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Flexible Exchange Rates in the Short Run RUDIGER DORNBUSCH MassachusettsInstitute of Technology PAUL KRUGMAN MassachusettsInstitute of Technology Flexible Exchange Rates in the Short Run CONSIDERABLE FLEXIBILITY in exchange rates has marked the seven- ties. A series of events, startingwith the appreciationof the deutsche mark in 1969, and includingthe realignmentin the SmithsonianAgree- ment in 1971 and a second realignment,have broughtthe world into a periodof controlledflexibility of rates.Flexible rates were the mechanism economistshad long advocatedfor attainingexternal balance,' but the experiencein the last few years has led many to reconsiderit. That reconsiderationis stimulatedby some surprisesin the performance of flexible rates. First among these are the recurrent,large cycles in ex- Note: We are indebted to Pedro Aspe, Roger Hankin, and Jay Helms for valuable assistance. Helpful comments from Karl Brunner,Jerry A. Hausman, and members of the Brookings panel are gratefully acknowledged.Financial support was provided by a grant from the Ford Foundation. 1. The literature on flexible rates goes back to Milton Friedman, "The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates," in his Essays in Positive Economics (University of Chi- cago Press, 1953). Subsequent writing includes Egon Sohmen, Flexible Exchange Rates: Theory and Controversy (University of Chicago Press, 1961); Richard E. Caves, "Flexible Exchange Rates," American Economic Review, vol. 53 (May 1963), pp. 120-29; Harry G. Johnson, "The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates, 1969," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, vol. 51 (June 1969), pp. 12-24; Herbert Giersch, "On the Desirable Degree of Flexibility of Exchange Rates," WeltwirtschaftlichesArchiv, vol. 109, no. 2 (1973), pp. 191-213; Edward Tower and Thomas D. Willett, The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas and Exchange- Rate Flexibility, Special Papers in International Economics 11 (Princeton Univer- sity, International Finance Section, 1976); and Richard N. Cooper, "Monetary Theory and Policy in an Open Economy," Scandinavian Journal of Economics, vol. 78, no. 2 (1976), pp. 146-63. 537 538 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3:1976 changerates. The dollar-markrate, for example,fluctuated more than 10 percent in less than six months, though there was no comparabledis- crepancyin the movementof pricelevels. Both the fluctuationsin rates and their side effectssoon causedgovern- ments to adopt exchange-ratetargets and to intervene in the market. Governmentsrealized that exchange-ratemovements had real effects: they alteredrelative prices and real incomes and they causedinflation or could serve to reduce inflationarypressure. Exchange-rate targets were also an attractivealternative to the disciplineof externalbalance imposed by a flexiblerate, which was far from appropriatein face of the real dis- turbancesof 1973-74. Confrontedwith a transitorydecline in real in- come, policymakersmuch preferredusing reserves and borrowingto a free adjustmentof exchangerates. The worldwiderecession of 1974-76 demonstrated,with the benefitof hindsight,that even under flexible rates there is scope for coordinated stabilizationpolicy. A coordinatedexpansion in economicactivity would have allowed every country to experiencesome export-ledrecovery at stableexchange rates. Against this background,we proposeanother look at flexiblerates and ask how they fit into conventionalmacroeconomic thinking. The paper seeks primarilyto pull together existing knowledge,factual and theo- retical.The focus is entirelyon the shortrun. We are concernedwith two relatedquestions: How are exchangerates determined,and what role do they play in a short-runmacroeconomic context?The answersare developedin part from theoryand in partfrom empirical evidence. The next major section covers theory, from pur- chasingpower parity and the Keynesianmodel. The theoryof purchasing power parity emphasizesthe relation between price levels and the ex- change rate but is not a theory of exchange-ratedetermination and has little to say about the macroeconomicrole of exchangerates. Keynesian theory, by contrast,places the exchangerate in the center of macroeco- nomics. The exchangerate is identifiedwith the relativeprice of goods and thus is a determinantof the allocation of world spendingbetween domestic and foreign goods. Under conditionsof capital mobility there is an importantlink betweeninternational interest rates and the exchange rate. The Keynesianmodel servesas a startingpoint for a realisticmodel but requiresseveral extensions. Hence, we incorporatethe implicationsof Rudiger Dornbusch and Paul Krugman 539 exchange-rateexpectations, both as part of the adjustmentprocess and as an independentsource of macroeconomicdisturbances. The model is furtherextended by a look at the impact of relativeprices on the saving rate. It is arguedthat an exchange-ratemovement changes relative prices, or the terms of trade, and thereforechanges real income. The changein real income,in turn,may altersaving and spendingat an unchangedlevel of output.The firstsection ends with a discussionof capitalmobility and the suggestionthat exchange rates are determinedin asset markets.We conclude that asset-marketviews and balance-of-paymentsviews of exchange-ratedetermination differ little provided proper emphasis is placedon the capitalaccount in the latter. The model that emergesemphasizes the link betweeninterest rates and exchangerates, identifiesthe exchangerate with the terms of trade, and assumesthat movementsin exchangerates will bring about adjustments in the compositionof worlddemand. The second sectionpresents empiri- cal evidence on some of these issues. First, we find that exchangerates indeed have a strongimpact on relativeprices. A depreciationwill raise importprices relative to exportprices, and thus improvea country'scom- petitiveness.For the case of manufactures,a country'sshare in world ex- ports is significantlydetermined by its relative price position, but the adjustmenttakes several years. We also find that, given domesticlabor cost, competitors'prices are an importantdeterminant of export prices, thus contradictingthe simpleKeynesian model. However, this responseis only partial,thus leavingsome terms-of-tradeeffect. In the third section, we find that importprices have an importantim- pact on domesticconsumer prices-an effectthat is not consideredin the simple Keynesianmodel. Also, that section combinesthe importantfea- turesof exchange-ratemovements in a short-runmacroeconomic context. It draws on the Keynesianmodel in emphasizingthe relation between interestrates and exchangerates and the impactof exchangerates on im- port prices. It goes beyond the Keynesianmodel in emphasizingthe ad- verse short-runeffects of expansionarymonetary policies. The exchange- rate depreciationthat is inducedwill only slowly affectthe compositionof demand;it will immediatelyraise import prices and thereby consumer prices. It follows that, given flexiblerates and capitalmobility, countries that seek an expansionin aggregatedemand face an adverseinflation- unemploymenttradeoff. The exchange-rateadjustment speeds up the inflationaryimpact of monetaryexpansion. We concludethat underthese 540 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3:1976 conditions,an individualcountry will wantto use a monetary-fiscalpolicy mix and that, duringa worldwiderecession, there is a compellingcase for coordinatedexpansion. These policy considerationsare taken up in the fourthand finalsection. Theoryof FlexibleExchange Rates This section provides an overviewof the main approachesto flexible exchange rates and lays out the elements of an integratedapproach. Traditionally,there have been three quite differentviews of the role and determinationof exchangerates. A monetaryapproach developed in the wake of the experienceafter WorldWar I holds that domesticmonetary upheaval will be reflectedin external depreciation.A second strandof an'alysis,again originatingin the twenties,emphasizes relations between relativeprice levels and the exchangerate-the famous doctrineof pur- chasingpower parity (PPP). Finally, Keynesianmacroeconomics of the open economy under flexiblerates was developedin the late forties and elaboratedin the sixties and stresses the interactionof output and ex- change-ratedetermination. PRICES AND EXCHANGE RATES Under the skin of any internationaleconomist lies a deep-seatedbelief in some variantof the PPP theoryof the exchangerate.2 According to the law of one price, a commodityshould sell for the same price (freightand duties apart) in variouslocations. An exchangerate that leaves an inter- nationalprice discrepancywill soon lead to arbitrageand therebyto an adjustmentin prices or the exchange rate or both. Given enough time, therefore,the domesticprices of internationallytraded goods will corre- spondto worldprices converted at the going exchangerate. Even if the arbitrageof traded-goodsprices is generallyaccepted, a numberof substantiveissues remain. Does spatialarbitrage have any fur- ther implicationsfor exchangerates, and, specifically,does it imply that 2. The theory and applications of PPP have been extensively reviewed in Law- rence H. Officer, "The Purchasing-Power-ParityTheory of Exchange Rates: A Review Article," International Monetary Fund, StaglPapers, vol. 23 (March 1976), pp. 1-60. RudigerDornbusch and Paul Krugman 541 exchangerates are a functionof price levels?Given domesticand foreign price levels, does the doctrineassert that the exchangerate will attain a particularlevel? If all goods weretraded with no transportcosts or dutiesand with
Recommended publications
  • Monetary Policy in Economies with Little Or No Money
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY IN ECONOMIES WITH LITTLE OR NO MONEY Bennett T. McCallum Working Paper 9838 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9838 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2003 This paper was prepared for presentation at the December 16-17, 2002, meeting of the Hong Kong Economic Association. I am indebted to Marvin Goodfriend, Lok Sang Ho, Allan Meltzer, and Edward Nelson for helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research ©2003 by Bennett T. McCallum. All rights reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit including © notice, is given to the source. Monetary Policy in Economies with Little or No Money Bennett T. McCallum NBER Working Paper No. 9838 July 2003 JEL No. E3, E4, E5 ABSTRACT The paper's arguments include: (1) Medium-of-exchange money will not disappear in the foreseeable future, although the quantity of base money may continue to decline. (2) In economies with very little money (e.g., no currency but bank settlement balances at the central bank), monetary policy will be conducted much as at present by activist adjustment of overnight interest rates. Operating procedures will be different, however, with payment of interest on reserves likely to become the norm. (3) In economies without any money there can be no monetary policy. The relevant notion of a general price level concerns some index of prices in terms of a medium of account.
    [Show full text]
  • A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Economics
    Copyright is owned by the Author of the thesis. Permission is given for a copy to be downloaded by an individual for the purpose of research and private study only. The thesis may not be reproduced elsewhere without the permission of the Author. A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Econol11ics: Making Economics Accessible to Students A thesis presented in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics at Massey University Palmerston North, New Zealand. Leanne Marie Smith July 2000 Abstract Paul A. Samuelson is the founder of the modem introductory economics textbook. His textbook Economics has become a classic, and the yardstick of introductory economics textbooks. What is said to distinguish economics from the other social sciences is the development of a textbook tradition. The textbook presents the fundamental paradigms of the discipline, these gradually evolve over time as puzzles emerge, and solutions are found or suggested. The textbook is central to the dissemination of the principles of a discipline. Economics has, and does contribute to the education of students, and advances economic literacy and understanding in society. It provided a common economic language for students. Systematic analysis and research into introductory textbooks is relatively recent. The contribution that textbooks play in portraying a discipline and its evolution has been undervalued and under-researched. Specifically, applying bibliographical and textual analysis to textbook writing in economics, examining a single introductory economics textbook and its successive editions through time is new. When it is considered that an economics textbook is more than a disseminator of information, but a physical object with specific content, presented in a particular way, it changes the way a researcher looks at that textbook.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Monetary Policy in the New Keynesian Model: Evidence from Vietnam
    The role of monetary policy in the New Keynesian Model: Evidence from Vietnam By: Van Hoang Khieu William Davidson Institute Working Paper Number 1075 February 2014 The role of monetary policy in the New Keynesian Model: Evidence from Vietnam Khieu, Van Hoang Graduate Student at The National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies (GRIPS), Japan. Lecturer in Monetary Economics at Banking Academy of Vietnam. Email: [email protected] Cell phone number: +81-8094490288 Abstract This paper reproduces a version of the New Keynesian model developed by Ireland (2004) and then uses the Vietnamese data from January 1995 to December 2012 to estimate the model’s parameters. The empirical results show that before August 2000 when the Taylor rule was adopted more firmly, the monetary policy shock made considerable contributions to the fluctuations in key macroeconomic variables such as the short-term nominal interest rate, the output gap, inflation, and especially output growth. By contrast, the loose adoption of the Taylor rule in the period of post- August 2000 leads to a fact that the contributions of the monetary policy shock to the variations in such key macroeconomic variables become less substantial. Thus, one policy implication is that adopting firmly the Taylor rule could strengthen the role of the monetary policy in driving movements in the key macroeconomic variables, for instance, enhancing economic growth and stabilizing inflation. Key words: New Keynesian model, Monetary Policy, Technology Shock, Cost-Push Shock, Preference Shock. JEL classification: E12, E32. 1 1. Introduction Explaining dynamic behaviors of key macroeconomic variables has drawn a lot of interest from researchers.
    [Show full text]
  • Has US Comparative Advantage Changed? Does This Affect Sustainability?
    3 Has US Comparative Advantage Changed? Does This Affect Sustainability? The evidence is overwhelmingly persuasive that the massive increase in world competition— a consequence of broadening trade flows—has fostered markedly higher standards of liv- ing . this surge in competitive trade has clearly owed, in large part, to significant advances in technological innovation. —Alan Greenspan, chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, “Technology and Trade,” remarks before the Dallas Ambassadors Forum, Dallas, Texas (16 April 1999) [T]he globalization system . is not static, but a dynamic ongoing process: globalization involves the inexorable integration of markets, nation-states and technologies to a degree never witnessed before—in a way that is enabling individuals, corporations and nation- states to reach around the world farther, faster, deeper and cheaper than ever before. —Thomas L. Friedman, The Lexus and the Olive Tree (1999) Why Trade? People trade because they want different things, have different skills, and earn different amounts of money. With individuals represented by their national aggregates, countries trade for the same reasons. Countries differ from one another in terms of resources and the techniques firms use to produce goods and services. People value goods and services differently, depending on their income and tastes. Investors in financial assets have different preferences for risk, return, and diversification. These differ- 29 Institute for International Economics | http://www.iie.com ences are reflected across countries as differences in costs of production, prices for products and services, and rates of return on and “exposures”1 to financial assets. Because costs, prices, and returns differ across countries, it makes sense for a country to trade some of what it produces most cheaply and holds less dear to people who want it more and for whom production is costly or even impossible.
    [Show full text]
  • Nobel Memoir
    Memoir JOSEPH E. STIGLITZ I was born in Gary, Indiana, at the time, a major steel town on the southern shores of Lake Michigan, on February 9, 1943. Both of my parents were born within six miles of Gary, early in the century, and continued to live in the area until 1997. I sometimes thought that my perignations made up for their stability. There must have been something in the air of Gary that led one into economics: the first Nobel Prize winner, Paul Samuelson, was also from Gary, as were several other distinguished economists. (Paul allegedly once wrote a letter of recommendation for me which summarized my accomplishments by saying that I was the best economist from Gary, Indiana.) Certainly, the poverty, the discrimination, the episodic unemployment could not but strike an inquiring youngster: why did these exist, and what could we do about them. I grew up in a family in which political issues were often discussed, and debated intensely. My mother’s family were New Deal Democrats—they worshipped FDR; and though my uncle was a highly successful lawyer and real estate entrepreneur, he was staunchly pro-labor. My father, on the other hand, was probably more aptly described as a Jeffersonian democrat; a small businessman (an independent insurance agent) himself, he repeatedly spoke of the virtues of self-employment, of being one’s own boss, of self-reliance. He worried about big business, and valued our competition laws. I saw him, conservative by nature, buffeted by the marked changes in American society during the near-century of his life, and adapt to these changes.
    [Show full text]
  • The Law of One Price Lagen Om Ett Pris
    LIU-IEI-FIL-A—09/00489—SE Linköping University, Sweden Department of Management and Engineering Master’s Thesis in Finance 15hp The International Business Program Spring 2009 The Law of One Price Evidence from Three European Stock Exchanges Lagen om ett pris Bevis från tre europeiska börsmarknader Author: – Sanna Olkkonen – Supervisor: Göran Hägg The Law of One Price – Evidence from Three European Stock Exchanges Abstract For the last decades the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) has had a vital role in the financial theory. According to the theory assets, independent of geographic location, always are correctly priced due to the notion of information efficiency across financial markets. A consequence of EMH is the Law of One Price, hereafter simply the Law, which is the main concept of this thesis. The Law extends the analysis by stating that in a perfectly integrated and competitive market cross- traded assets should trade for the same common-currency price in every country. This becomes a fact due to the presence of arbitrageurs’ continuous vigilance in the financial markets, where any case of mispricing is acted upon in a matter of seconds by buying the cheaper asset and selling it where the price is higher in order to make a profit from the price gap. Past research reveals that mispricing on cross-traded assets does exist, indicating that there exists evidence of violations of the Law on financial markets. However, in the real world most likely only a few cases of mispricing equal arbitrage opportunities due to the fact that worldwide financial markets are not characterized by the perfect conditions required by Law.
    [Show full text]
  • On Some Recent Developments in Monetary Economics
    ON SOME RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN MONETARY ECONOMICS P. D. Jonson R. w. Rankin* Reserve Bank of Australia Research Discussion Paper 8605 (Revised) August 1986 (Forthcoming, Economic Record September 1986) * This paper is dedicated to the memory of Austin Holmes, OBE, who both commissioned it and provided helpful comments on drafts. It has also benefitted from the comments of many other colleagues, including in particular Palle Andersen, Charles Goodhart, David Laidler and William Poole, as well as participants in seminars at ANU, Melbourne and Monash Universities. The views expressed herein are nevertheless those of the authors. In particular, they are not necessarily shared by their employer. ABSTRACT This survey is motivated by the major changes that have been occurring both within the financial sector and in the relationships between financial and other markets. These changes have complicated both monetary analysis and the practice of monetary policy. Monetary models based on simple aggregative relationships are not well equipped to analyse issues of structural change. Monetary policy has been forced to rely more on "judgement" and less on the application of these models and their suggested policy rules. one obvious example of this is the demise, or at least downgrading, of monetary targets in major western economies. This survey examines some of the main strands in the development of monetary economics in the past two decades. It argues that much of the policy prescription of monetary economics - especially reliance on monetary targeting - depends on simple "stylised facts" about the behaviour of regulated economies. These prescriptions cannot therefore be applied directly to economies where the regulatory structure is changing.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Integration and Convergence to the Law of One Price
    Market Integration and Convergence to the Law of One Price: Evidence from the European Car Market∗ Pinelopi Koujianou Goldberg Frank Verboven Yale University and NBER Catholic University of Leuven and CEPR December 2003 Abstract This paper exploits the unique case of European market integration to investigate the relationship between integration and price convergence in international markets. Using a panel data set of car prices we examine how the process of integration has affected cross- country price dispersion in Europe. We find surprisingly strong evidence of convergence towards both the absolute and the relative versions of the Law of One Price. Our analysis illuminates the main sources of segmentation in international markets and suggests the type of institutional changes that can successfully reduce it. JEL Codes: F0, F15, L62 Keywords: International Price Dispersion, Law of One Price, Market Integration, Price Convergence, European Automobile Market ∗Corresponding author: Pinelopi K. Goldberg; Address: Department of Economics, Yale University, 37 Hillhouse Avenue, P.O. Box 208264, New Haven, CT 06520-8264; Telephone: (203) 432-3569; Fax: (203) 432-6323; Email: [email protected]. Address of Frank Verboven: Faculty of Economics and Applied Economics, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Naamstestraat 69, B-3000 Leuven, Belgium; Email: [email protected]. 1 1Introduction1 This paper uses the European integration process as a case study to explore the link between integration and price convergence in international markets. Few topics have attracted as much attention and controversy in International Economics as the topic of convergence to the Law of One Price (LOOP). While until a few years ago, one was hard-pressed to find evidence in favor of the convergence hypothesis, a number of recent papers claim that Purchasing Power Parity does hold in the long run, with a half-life of shocks of five to six years (see Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000) for a detailed discussion).
    [Show full text]
  • Walking a Tightrope: the Neoclassical Synthesis in Action
    Walking a tightrope: the neoclassical synthesis in action Michaël Assous1 Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Phare Muriel Dal Pont Legrand Université Cote d’Azur, CNRS GREDEG Sonia Manseri Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Phare Preliminary draft Abstract: The neoclassical synthesis which emerged in the late 1950s is associated to a specific understanding of the connection between short-run Keynesian and long-run neoclassical analyses. In the early 1960s, when economists from both Cambridges tried to revisit the conditions likely to guarantee the stability of long-run paths, this view was challenged. Then, issues related to the determinants of income distribution and expectations were raised. Our goal in this article is to discuss the significance of these findings and see how they challenged the whole neoclassical synthesis. Using original archives material from Duke and Cambridge (UK) Universities, the paper pays mostly attention to arguments raised by Frank Hahn, Nicholas Kaldor, Paul Samuelson, Armatya Sen and Robert Solow. 1 Contact : [email protected]. 1 Introduction In 1955, Samuelson introduced the notion of neoclassical synthesis in the third edition of his Economics. With the works of Robert Solow, James Meade, Trevor Swan and James Tobin, the synthesis started designating the outcome of a process by which short-run Keynesian and long-run neoclassical analyses were made compatible. In a nutshell, as long as the economy was supposed to be managed on a Keynesian-basis in the short-run, the neoclassical growth model was seen as the more appropriate tool to analyze and sustain full-employment growth. In addition, with the publication of Solow 1957 paper, the neoclassical synthesis meant a particular way to empirically deal with the long-run impact of technical progress.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Monetary Policy in an Economy with Inflation Persistence
    ARTICLE IN PRESS Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 1425–1456 Optimal monetary policy in an economy with inflation persistence$ Jon! Steinsson Department of Economics, Harvard University, Littauer Center, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA Received 1 April 2001; received in revised form 6 May 2003 Abstract This paper studies optimal monetary policy in a model where inflation is persistent. Two types of price setters are assumed to exist. One acts rationally given Calvo-type constraints on price setting. The other type sets prices according to a rule-of-thumb. This results in a Phillips curve with both a forward-looking term and a backward-looking term. The Phillips curve nests a standard purely forward-looking Phillips curve as well as a standard purely backward-looking Phillips curve as special cases. A cost push supply shock is derived from microfoundations by adding a time varying income tax and by making the elasticity of substitution between goods stochastic. A central bank loss function for this model is derived from a second-order Taylor approximation of the household’s welfare function. Optimal monetary policy for different relative values of the forward- and backward-looking terms is then analyzed for both the commitment case and the case of discretion. r 2003 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: E31; E32; E52; E58 Keywords: Optimal monetary policy; Phillips curve; Inflation persistence; Cost push shock $I thank Michael Woodford for priceless advice and encouragement. I thank Gauti B. Eggertsson, Marc Giannoni, Emi Nakamura, Thorarinn! G. Petursson! and anonymous referees for valuable discussions and comments. Special thanks to Lonn Waters for moral support.
    [Show full text]
  • Summary of U.S. Balance of Payments, 1969 by MICHAEL W
    Summary of U.S. Balance of Payments, 1969 by MICHAEL W. ICERAN dollar transactions. Changes in bank liabilities are listed with changes in short-term Treasury liabilities under The Balance of Payments Accounts are a double-entry IV.4, to facilitate analysis of the distinction between record of commodity and financial transactions between the Liquidity Balance and Official Settlements Balance. United States and foreign residents. Because it is based on double-entry bookkeeping principles, the balance of (III) Government — The net outflow of Government payments always balances in the sense that receipts loans, grants, and transfers was $4.0 billion in 1969, up equal payments. The double-entry nature of the balance $1.5 billion from 1968. Foreign official institutions, which of payments is illustrated on the lefthand side of the had purchased $1.8 billion of U.S. Government bonds table on the next page. This accounting balance must in 1968, sold $.2 billion in 1969. This $2.0 billion turn- not be confused, however, with a meaningful economic around more than explains the deterioration in the balance, because the economic behavior underlying some Government capital account. of these transactions may not be sustainable. For exam- ple, the receipt of $.8 billion in 1969 from the sale of (IV) Other — Private transfers (IV.1.) represent gifts convertible currencies (IV.3.b) can only continue as and similar payments by American residents to foreign long as the United States’ stock of convertible currencies residents. Errors and Omissions (IV.2.) is the statistical lasts. There are two officially recognized measures of discrepancy between all specifically identifiable receipts the economic balance of payments: the Liquidity Bal- and payments.
    [Show full text]
  • Parity Conditions and Currency Forecasting the Law of One Price
    Chap. 4 (b) Parity Conditions and The Law of One Price Currency Forecasting • This is the assumption that identical goods sell for the same price worldwide. • Forecasts based on the Law of One Price. • Suppose gold trades in NYC at $300/oz. and in London • The Big Mac Index at $310/oz. • Forecasts based on Relative Purchasing Power Parity. • Where will people trade their gold? • Inflation and the Real Rate of Interest • The New York market would mostly attract buyers, • The original Fisher Effect. while the London market would mostly attract sellers. • The International Fisher Effect. • Also, arbitrage would occur: trades could “short-sell” gold in London, and simultaneously buy gold in NYC. • Sept. 19, 2002 by William Pugh • Gold prices in the two markets should soon equalize The Law of One Price and The Law of One Price Purchasing Power Parity • Purchasing power parity is often interpreted as, • What would cause a violation of the law of one starting with a set amount of dollars, converting price? those dollars into another currency buys the • If goods are not easily tradable, they are are same “market basket of goods” in the foreign difficult to arbitrage. country that it would in the U.S.A. • This is the really just the law one price. • Examples of nontradable goods?: • However we will find that this “law” is true only in a very limited sense. Violations of the Law of One Price Violations of the Law of One Price • Haircuts • Law of one price does not hold for nontradable • Taxi rides goods even within the United States! • Restaurant Meals (Big Macs) • Rents in New York City vs Lochapoka, AL • Apartments • Big Macs in Alaska vs.
    [Show full text]