Capitalism and Society
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
KALDOR's WAR J.E. King*
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 1441-5429 DISCUSSION PAPER 25/07 KALDOR’S WAR * J.E. King * Department of Economics and Finance, La Trobe University, Victoria 3086, Australia Email: [email protected] © 2007 J.E. King All rights reserved. No part of this paper may be reproduced in any form, or stored in a retrieval system, without the prior written permission of the author. Introduction In the 1930s the young Nicholas Kaldor (1908-1986) established himself as one of the world’s leading economic theorists (King 2007). As with so many lives, Kaldor’s was turned around by the Second World War. This was not the result of enemy action. Although his family in Hungary suffered grievously at the hands of the Nazis, Nicky himself was not called to arms. While he had become a British citizen in 1934, and made enquiries about joining the Civil Service as an economic advisor, he was told that his Hungarian origins would disqualify him from anything other than menial duties in Whitehall. He therefore decided to stay in academia, and relocated to Cambridge with his remaining LSE colleagues in September 1939, when the Ministry of Works took over the School’s Aldwych site in central London .1 Now based at Peterhouse, Kaldor was able to deepen old friendships and develop new ones. A ‘war circus’ of economists began to operate, named by analogy with the ‘Cambridge circus’ of young theorists who had interrogated Keynes in 1930- 1 after the publication of the Treatise on Money and helped to focus his mind on the revolutionary breakthrough of the General Theory (Moggridge 1995, pp. -
After the Phillips Curve: Persistence of High Inflation and High Unemployment
Conference Series No. 19 BAILY BOSWORTH FAIR FRIEDMAN HELLIWELL KLEIN LUCAS-SARGENT MC NEES MODIGLIANI MOORE MORRIS POOLE SOLOW WACHTER-WACHTER % FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF BOSTON AFTER THE PHILLIPS CURVE: PERSISTENCE OF HIGH INFLATION AND HIGH UNEMPLOYMENT Proceedings of a Conference Held at Edgartown, Massachusetts June 1978 Sponsored by THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF BOSTON THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF BOSTON CONFERENCE SERIES NO. 1 CONTROLLING MONETARY AGGREGATES JUNE, 1969 NO. 2 THE INTERNATIONAL ADJUSTMENT MECHANISM OCTOBER, 1969 NO. 3 FINANCING STATE and LOCAL GOVERNMENTS in the SEVENTIES JUNE, 1970 NO. 4 HOUSING and MONETARY POLICY OCTOBER, 1970 NO. 5 CONSUMER SPENDING and MONETARY POLICY: THE LINKAGES JUNE, 1971 NO. 6 CANADIAN-UNITED STATES FINANCIAL RELATIONSHIPS SEPTEMBER, 1971 NO. 7 FINANCING PUBLIC SCHOOLS JANUARY, 1972 NO. 8 POLICIES for a MORE COMPETITIVE FINANCIAL SYSTEM JUNE, 1972 NO. 9 CONTROLLING MONETARY AGGREGATES II: the IMPLEMENTATION SEPTEMBER, 1972 NO. 10 ISSUES .in FEDERAL DEBT MANAGEMENT JUNE 1973 NO. 11 CREDIT ALLOCATION TECHNIQUES and MONETARY POLICY SEPBEMBER 1973 NO. 12 INTERNATIONAL ASPECTS of STABILIZATION POLICIES JUNE 1974 NO. 13 THE ECONOMICS of a NATIONAL ELECTRONIC FUNDS TRANSFER SYSTEM OCTOBER 1974 NO. 14 NEW MORTGAGE DESIGNS for an INFLATIONARY ENVIRONMENT JANUARY 1975 NO. 15 NEW ENGLAND and the ENERGY CRISIS OCTOBER 1975 NO. 16 FUNDING PENSIONS: ISSUES and IMPLICATIONS for FINANCIAL MARKETS OCTOBER 1976 NO. 17 MINORITY BUSINESS DEVELOPMENT NOVEMBER, 1976 NO. 18 KEY ISSUES in INTERNATIONAL BANKING OCTOBER, 1977 CONTENTS Opening Remarks FRANK E. MORRIS 7 I. Documenting the Problem 9 Diagnosing the Problem of Inflation and Unemployment in the Western World GEOFFREY H. -
What We Know and Do Not Know About the Natural Rate of Unemployment
Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 11, Number 1—Winter 1997—Pages 51–72 What We Know and Do Not Know About the Natural Rate of Unemployment Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence F. Katz lmost 30 years ago, Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1968) developed the concept of the "natural rate of unemployment." In what must be one of Athe longest sentences he ever wrote, Milton Friedman explained: "The natural rate of unemployment is the level which would be ground out by the Wal- rasian system of general equilibrium equations, provided that there is imbedded in them the actual structural characteristics of the labor and commodity markets, in- cluding market imperfections, stochastic variability in demands and supplies, the cost of gathering information about job vacancies and labor availabilities, the costs of mobility, and so on." Over the past three decades a large amount of research has attempted to formalize Friedman's long sentence and to identify, both theo- retically and empirically, the determinants of the natural rate. It is this body of work we assess in this paper. We reach two main conclusions. The first is that there has been considerable theoretical progress over the past 30 years. A framework has emerged, organized around two central ideas. The first is that the labor market is a market with a high level of traffic, with large flows of workers who have either lost their jobs or are looking for better ones. This by itself implies that there must be some "frictional unemployment." The second is that the nature of relations between firms and workers leads to wage setting that often differs substantially from competitive wage setting. -
Nicholas Kaldor
PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS 26 NICHOLAS KALDOR NICHOLAS KALDOR – ONE OF THE FIRST CRITICS OF MONETARISM doc. Ing. Ján Iša, DrSc. Known in economic circles as one of the thought in several fields, but it was his work founders of Post-Keynesianism, Nicholas on the theory of distribution and economic Kaldor (1908–1986) ranks among the worl- growth that stirred the greatest reaction. d's foremost economists of the second half Less well-known, however, is Kaldor's con- of the 20th century. Kaldor contributed to tribution to monetary theory, which has long the development of modern economic been standing quietly in the background. Nicholas Kaldor was born in Budapest on 12 May 1908. rous Third World countries, as well as an advisor to central His father was a lawyer and his mother came from wealthy banks and to the United Nations Economic Commission for business family. Although his father had wanted him to Latin America. Most significant, however, was his role as an study law, Kaldor opted for economics. He began his studi- advisor to Labour finance ministers from 1964 to 1968 and es at the University of Berlin in 1925 and then after two 1974 to 1976. After completing his two-year mission in years moved to the London School of Economics (LSE), Geneva in 1949, Kaldor began to work at Cambridge Uni- from which he graduated in 1930. He remained at the LSE versity and became, as John Maynard Keynes had been, a as lecturer until 1947, during which time his colleagues inc- fellow of King's College, Cambridge. -
Edmund Phelps and Modern Macroeconomics Robert W
This article was downloaded by:[informa internal users] On: 9 January 2008 Access Details: [subscription number 755239602] Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Review of Political Economy Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t713444532 Edmund Phelps and Modern Macroeconomics Robert W. Dimand a a Department of Economics, Brock University, Ontario, Canada Online Publication Date: 01 January 2008 To cite this Article: Dimand, Robert W. (2008) 'Edmund Phelps and Modern Macroeconomics', Review of Political Economy, 20:1, 23 - 39 To link to this article: DOI: 10.1080/09538250701661798 URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09538250701661798 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdf This article maybe used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material. Review of Political Economy, Volume 20, Number 1, 23–39, January 2008 Edmund Phelps and Modern Macroeconomics ROBERT W. -
Welfare Goal in Antitrust Journals.Sagepub.Com/Home/Abx
The Antitrust Bulletin 1-39 ª The Author(s) 2018 The Unsound Theory Behind Article reuse guidelines: sagepub.com/journals-permissions the Consumer (and Total) DOI: 10.1177/0003603X18807802 Welfare Goal in Antitrust journals.sagepub.com/home/abx Mark Glick* Abstract This is the first installment of a two-part commentary on the New Brandeis School (the “New Brandeisians”) in Antitrust. In this first part, I examine why the New Brandeisians are correct to reject the consumer welfare standard. Instead of arguing, as the New Brandeisians do, that the consumer welfare standard leads to unacceptable outcomes, I argue that the consumer or total welfare standard was theoretically flawed and unrigorous from the start. My basic argument is that antitrust law addresses the impact of business strategies in markets where there are winners and losers. For example, in the classical exclusionary monopolist case, the monopolist’s conduct is enjoined to increase competition in the affected market or markets. As a result of the intervention, consumers benefit, but the monopolist is worse off. One hundred years of analysis by the welfare economists themselves shows that in such situations “welfare” or “consumer welfare” cannot be used as a reliable guide to assess the results of antitrust policy. Pareto Optimality does not apply in these situations because there are losers. Absent an ability to divine “cardinal utility” from obser- vations of market behavior, other approaches such as consumer surplus, and compensating and equivalent variation cannot be coherently extended from the individual level to markets. The Kaldor-Hicks compensation principle that is in standard use in law and economics was created to address problems of interpersonal comparisons of utility and the existence of winners and losers. -
Anticipations of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen Mechanism1
Anticipations of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen Mechanism1 André Roncaglia de Carvalho2 ABSTRACT This paper aims to contribute to the literature on the intellectual history of the economics discipline in Brazil and its place within the network of international transmission of economic ideas, by delving into the history of the Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen mechanism, namely: the behavior of periodically-adjusted fixed nominal wages under persistent inflationary conditions (the sawtooth wages model). Ranging from the immediate post-War years to the end of the 1960s, our narrative reveals that prior to Nicholas Kaldor’s statement of the sawtooth model of real wages, other contributions sprung from various traditions. To this effect, we underline the discoursive appraisal by Celso Furtado (1954) and the early neoclassical model by Bent Hansen (1951), only to fit both of them in a broader historical context of the economics discipline, whereby the emergence of formal mathematical methods allows for the connection between this debate and the Operations Research Program in the North-American universities in the early 1950s. Keywords: chronic inflation, sawtooth model, formal mechanic models, Celso Furtado Operations Research Program RESUMO Este artigo busca contribuir com a literatura de história da ciência econômica no Brazil e seu lugar na rede internacional de transmissão das ideias econônomicas, por meio de uma análise da história do mecanismo Kaldor-Pazos-Simonsen, qual seja: o comportamento de rendas nominais fixas com reajustamento periódico sob inflação -
Three Revolutions in Macroeconomics: Their Nature and Influence
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Laidler, David Working Paper Three revolutions in macroeconomics: Their nature and influence EPRI Working Paper, No. 2013-4 Provided in Cooperation with: Economic Policy Research Institute (EPRI), Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario Suggested Citation: Laidler, David (2013) : Three revolutions in macroeconomics: Their nature and influence, EPRI Working Paper, No. 2013-4, The University of Western Ontario, Economic Policy Research Institute (EPRI), London (Ontario) This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/123484 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen -
Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics
Munich Personal RePEc Archive Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics Azad, Rohit The New School for Social Research, Columbia University, Jawaharlal Nehru University 1 October 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/80056/ MPRA Paper No. 80056, posted 08 Jul 2017 14:35 UTC Plurality in Teaching Macroeconomics Rohit Azad 1 Introduction In the aftermath of the Great Depression, there was turmoil in the field of Macroeconomics, which resulted in the Keynesian ‘revolution’. However, the current Great Recession, the worst crisis that capitalism has faced since then, has failed, at least so far, to generate an upheaval in the teaching and practice of Macroeconomics. This seems bizarre as if nothing has happened and the economists are just going about doing business as usual. Without going into the politics of why this is so, let me just focus on how Macroeconomics ought to be taught to students at the intermediate level, which gives them an overall perspective on the subject1. I must note that this article has been inspired by an editorial published in EPW [2013]. Macroeconomics as a subject proper came into existence with the writ- ings of John Maynard Keynes2. There were debates during his time about how to characterise a capitalist economy, most of these are still a part of the discussion among economists. Keynes [1936, 1937] argued that capitalism is a fundamentally unstable system so the state needs to intervene to control this instability. Keynes [1936] has been interpreted in different, often contradictory, ways. In today’s context, they can be broadly classified in two categories: Post Keynesian and New Keynesian. -
Lucas' Equilibrium Account of the Business Cycles
Department of Economics- FEA/USP Lucas’ Equilibrium Account of the Business Cycles: Optimizing Behavior, General Equilibrium, and Modeling Rational Expectations HUGO C. W. CHU WORKING PAPER SERIES Nº 2015-30 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FEA-USP WORKING PAPER Nº 2015-30 Lucas’ Equilibrium Account of the Business Cycle: Optimizing Behavior, General Equilibrium, and Modeling Rational Expectations Hugo Chu [[email protected]] Abstract Robert E. Lucas Jr. is considered the “architect” of modern macroeconomics. His equilibrium approach to the business cycles has provoked a major change in the understanding of macroeconomic phenomena since the late 1960s. In this article we attempt to describe historically how he put together the main elements that formed the body of his theoretical framework, namely, the optimizing representative agent, the contingent-claim approach to general equilibrium analysis and the modeling of the rational expectation hypothesis. Lucas’ Expectations and the Neutrality of Money, published in 1972, is the first article containing all elements aforementioned. To reach such a result, he collaborated with Leonard Rapping in 1969 (their first article) and later developed a joint work with Edward Prescott in 1971. Furthermore, we also argue that the way Robert Lucas saw business cycles can be considered an inevitable progress in macroeconomics. Keywords: Robert Lucas, Business Cycles, Representative Agent, General Equilibrium, Rational Expectations. JEL Codes: B2, B22 Lucas’ Equilibrium Account of the Business Cycle: Optimizing Behavior, General Equilibrium, and Modeling Rational Expectations1 Hugo Chu2 [email protected] ABSTRACT Robert E. Lucas Jr. is considered the “architect” of modern macroeconomics. His equilibrium approach to the business cycles has provoked a major change in the understanding of macroeconomic phenomena since the late 1960s. -
Unemployment Solved: an Answer to Krugman, Phelps, Ormerod and Heilbroner
Unemployment solved: An answer to Krugman, Phelps, Ormerod and Heilbroner Paul, ‘we’ actually know ! Thomas Cool [email protected] Http://www.can.nl/~cool April 13 1997 Summary Krugman, Phelps, Ormerod and Heilbroner have produced forceful analyses on the current state of the economy, society and economic theory itself, and all with a distinct attention for unemployment. These authors agree on many points, but disagree on major points too. Interestingly, where these authors disagree, my own work offers new answers, on angles clearly not considered by them. My analysis solves conflicts, fills gaps, and complements on useful points. By relating my work to theirs I hope to enable these authors and their readers to plug into - what I consider - a new synthesis for (a renewed) mainstream economics. Introduction Mainstream economics appears to accept high rates of (equilibrium) unemployment as the apparent characteristic of the modern economy. In this view, unemployment is not inefficient, but the unavoidable price to be paid for other desirables. Take for example the case that the United States has low welfare provisions, less unemployment but more poverty and many prisons, while the European Union has high welfare provisions, high unemployment, less poverty and far fewer prisons: these differences then are explained in terms of political choices for example about institutions, labour market flexibility and employability; and it is suggested that such choices are made at the efficiency frontier. 1 Research economists however are more focussed on the question whether current policy is optimal and whether current unemployment is inefficient. The search is for a Pareto improving solution such that some can advance - notably the unemployed and the poor (underemployed) - without costs to the others. -
Walking a Tightrope: the Neoclassical Synthesis in Action
Walking a tightrope: the neoclassical synthesis in action Michaël Assous1 Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Phare Muriel Dal Pont Legrand Université Cote d’Azur, CNRS GREDEG Sonia Manseri Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Phare Preliminary draft Abstract: The neoclassical synthesis which emerged in the late 1950s is associated to a specific understanding of the connection between short-run Keynesian and long-run neoclassical analyses. In the early 1960s, when economists from both Cambridges tried to revisit the conditions likely to guarantee the stability of long-run paths, this view was challenged. Then, issues related to the determinants of income distribution and expectations were raised. Our goal in this article is to discuss the significance of these findings and see how they challenged the whole neoclassical synthesis. Using original archives material from Duke and Cambridge (UK) Universities, the paper pays mostly attention to arguments raised by Frank Hahn, Nicholas Kaldor, Paul Samuelson, Armatya Sen and Robert Solow. 1 Contact : [email protected]. 1 Introduction In 1955, Samuelson introduced the notion of neoclassical synthesis in the third edition of his Economics. With the works of Robert Solow, James Meade, Trevor Swan and James Tobin, the synthesis started designating the outcome of a process by which short-run Keynesian and long-run neoclassical analyses were made compatible. In a nutshell, as long as the economy was supposed to be managed on a Keynesian-basis in the short-run, the neoclassical growth model was seen as the more appropriate tool to analyze and sustain full-employment growth. In addition, with the publication of Solow 1957 paper, the neoclassical synthesis meant a particular way to empirically deal with the long-run impact of technical progress.