How Did Britain Democratize? Views from the Sovereign Bond Market

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

How Did Britain Democratize? Views from the Sovereign Bond Market How did Britain Democratize? Views from the Sovereign Bond Market Aditya Dasgupta∗ Daniel Ziblatty May 5, 2013 Abstract This paper examines the response of the market for British sovereign bonds to the passage of the Reform Acts of 1832, 1867, and 1884. We show that the nineteenth century British bond market was acutely sensitive to political events and impounded the risk of default and currency depreciation associated with possible regime instability into bond yields. We demonstrate that British sovereign bond yields therefore represent an accurate barometer of perceived political instability, which we utilize to shed light on the nature of British democratization. Our analysis of monthly data on yields on the British 3% consol, as well as analysis of the contemporaneous reactions of the financial press, suggests that political disorder [Huntington, 1968], broadly conceived as the joint occurrence of social unrest and political stalemate, was the impetus for suffrage reform in Britain, challenging the classical \Whig" view that Britain's pre-modern institutional history predestined it for a uniquely tranquil process of democratization. In the reactions of the bond market, we find indications of intense political disorder preceding major moments of democratization. We also find, quite unexpectedly, that the passage of democratic reform was viewed not as a potential incitor of, but as a resolution to, the incidence of political disorder, prompting nearly immediate drops in bond yields. Finally, we find that this dynamic appears to have varied over time, with a great deal of bond yield volatility in 1832, a smaller, though important, amount in 1867 and none whatsoever in 1884. ∗PhD Candidate in Government, Harvard University. Email: [email protected] yProfessor of Government, Harvard University. Email: [email protected] 1 1 Introduction The process of democratization in Britain { the 1832, 1867, and 1884 Reform Acts in particular { has attracted a great deal of scholarly argument over how democracy emerged. One long-standing view, rooted in a classical \Whig" interpretation of history (see critique by, e.g. [Butterfield, 1965]), is that Britain was distinctive in requiring little social and political conflict to democratize in the age of mass politics. Yet, it is a historical fact that agricultural strikes, protests, and mass demonstrations preceded each of the Reform Acts. However, whether political elites of the time perceived a genuine \threat of revolution" or not is a matter of intense debate amongst researchers. Empirically, scholars on both sides of the debate have mined the historical record for evidence favoring their view, at considerable risk of choosing facts to fit the theory. Of equal concern is the fact that scholars have relied considerably on the written and verbal statements of historical protagonists to assess their perceptions and motivations. Since politicians do not have to \put their money where their mouths are", how do we know if these statements were sincere or if they were strategic? This paper takes a new empirical approach to the debate based on examining the response of the market for British sovereign bonds to the Reform Acts. The nineteenth century British bond market was acutely sensitive to political events and impounded the risk of default associated with possible regime instability into bond yields, we show. Bond yields therefore represent a good barometer of perceived political instability. Bond yields are potentially a better measure of perceptions when analyzed alongside written and verbal statements of politicians because they directly represent revealed preferences and therefore can plausibly be viewed as less strategic and more \sincere" than political speeches alone. Finally, bond yields enable comparison of perceived po- litical risk across time and Reform Acts, especially because a single type of government bond, the British 3% consol, was traded heavily on the London stock exchange over the entire period in question. In this paper we first provide a brief history and literature overview of the 1832, 1867 and 1884 Reform Acts and summarize our argument. In the second section, we explain the research design. In the third and fourth sections, we present and analyze the bond market data. Finally, we conclude with some thoughts on the implications of our findings for the study of democratization more generally. Overall, we come to three new conclusions. First, against the classical \Whig" view that British democratization was in some way uniquely genetically \hardwired" into British political development, rooted in the shrouds of England's seventeenth century history, making political violence a minimal factor in the democratization of Britain, we 2 find evidence of major turmoil in bond markets preceding moments of democratization. But, second, quite surprisingly, we find that that against a backdrop of deep-seated po- litical disorder, bond markets \liked" democratization: the passage of suffrage reform, especially early in the century, coincided not with increases but rather with sharp drops in the premium that investors demanded to hold British sovereign debt. Finally, we find that the market volatility associated with the process of democratization declined over the century. Political disorder seems to have played a large role in 1832, with yields rising sharply in 1830-31 in response to social and political conflict but declin- ing as the 1832 Reform Act's passage approached, returning to pre-crisis levels within months. A similar pattern is apparent around the passage of the 1867 Reform Act, though the scale of the spike in bond yields prior to the passage of reform was much less, suggesting relatively lower perceived political risk. Bond markets were extremely calm around the passage of the 1884 Reform Act, suggesting that the threat of political disorder played no role whatsoever in this case. This evidence of over-time variation suggests a new periodization of the consolidation of the British political order, in which the constitutional order was still in flux in the first third of the nineteenth century, and only firmly consolidated in the second half of the nineteenth century. 2 Background and Theory The question of why old nondemocratic elites would ever dilute their power by ex- panding the suffrage is a central question for the historical study of democratization. (e.g. [Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005]). To date the debate has tended to be bifurcated between two views, that democratization emerges out of revolutionary threats from below and is only conceded when threats of revolution are so severe that democrati- zation is the \lesser of two evils," or alternatively that democratization is an \elite project" [Collier, 1999], negotiated among elites in competition with each other but quite independent of social forces. The former view conjures images of reactive elites only ceding democracy in the face of intense social conflict and contention, while the latter account suggests a dynamic in which political elites pursue suffrage reform while forging back-room pacts, largely in isolation from societal changes. Britain is often taken as a crucial test case that is a battleground for these two perspectives. One the one hand, it is frequently regarded as paradigmatic of a type of political development in which industrialization proceeded alongside a gradual or consensual 19th century process of democratization (e.g. [Dahl, 1971]) in which political violence and social unrest is thought to have played only a minimal role. From this view, 3 the pre-industrial political violence of the seventeenth century [Moore, 1966], and early supremacy of the English parliament established after the 1688 Glorious Revolution gave rise to a path of smooth democratization in Britain because its constitutional order was secure long before the age of mass suffrage ( [North and Weingast, 1989]; [Ansell and Samuels, 2010]). Whether suffrage expansion came as a result of elite competition as argued by Collier [Collier, 1999], building on Cowling [Cowling, 1967] and Himmelfarb [Himmelfarb, 1966], or occurred as a result of an effort by political elites to shift British politics away from a patronage to programmatic party competition [Lizzeri and Persico, 2004], in all of these views, democratization in Britain was a low-stakes political competition among elites in a constitutional system that already provides well-institutionalized guarantees for secure property rights.1 On the other hand, a second prominent perspective argues that suffrage expansion is only achieved when elites reluctantly concede democratic reform facing a \threat of revolution" ( [Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005]; [Morrison, 2011]; [Aidt and Franck, 2013]. This view reminds us that democracy in Britain was achieved piecemeal, chiefly in the reforms of 1832, 1867, and 1884, and always in the face of social conflict.2 Fur- thermore, from this view, the role of social conflict in prompting suffrage reform was decisive, as has recently been elaborated by Acemoglu and Robinson [Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005], who elegantly formalize the old but controversial claim, made by the liberal historian Trevelyan [Trevelyan, 1920], for example, that the Reform Acts were unwilling concessions intended by the political establishment to avoid revolution and appease the increasingly restless disenfranchised sectors of society. For evidence, pro- ponents of this view point to the steady stream of public demonstrations and strikes and other forms of extra-parliamentary pressure that led up to each of the reforms. These include the chaotic `Days of May' of 1832, the Hyde Park riots of 1867, and the anti-House of Lords protests of 1884. It has even been argued that 1831 was the closest that Britain has ever come to revolution [Evans, 1994]. In the `revolutionary 1In the `elite project' perspective, the Reform Acts represented the efforts of ambitious politicians to gain votes by pandering to pro- reform sentiment. In this perspective, the strikes and protests leading up to the Reform Acts were unimportant; Himmelfarb, for example, argues that the much vaunted Hyde Park riots of 1867 amounted to little more than \broken railings and trampled flower beds".
Recommended publications
  • Introduction
    How did Britain Democratize? Views from the Sovereign Bond Market Aditya Dasgupta1 Daniel Ziblatt2 Abstract To assess competing theories of democratization, we analyze British sovereign bond market responses to the 1832, 1867 and 1884 Reform Acts, and to two failed Chartist agitations. Analyses of high-frequency 3% consol yield data and historical financial press suggest three conclusions. First, democratic reform episodes were preceded by increases in perceived political risk, comparable to democratizing episodes in other countries. Second, both democratic reform and repression were followed by yield de- clines. Third, the source of political risk in Britain was both social unrest and political deadlock. Together, the findings challenge the \Whig" characterization of British de- mocratization as exceptionally risk-free. Introduction The process of democratization in Britain { the franchise expansions legislated in the 1832, 1867, and 1884 Reform Acts in particular { has attracted a great deal of scholarly argument over how democracy emerged. One long-standing view, rooted in a classical \Whig" interpre- tation of history (see critique by Herbert Butterfield (1965)), is that Britain was distinctive in requiring little social and political conflict to democratize. Others argue that, whether driven by destabilizing constitutional crises or even the threat of mass revolution (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005), the process of democratization in Britain was deeply conflictual. A key empirical issue at stake in this debate is this: what was the level of perceived political risk during each of Britain's major episodes of suffrage expansion? Scholars on both sides of 1PhD Candidate, Department of Government, Harvard University. Email: [email protected] 2Professor, Department of Government, Harvard University.
    [Show full text]
  • “FRESHER by FAR” PRODUCE Ple of Peace with Israel and .Ac­ Son of West Hartfrod
    .r • 'V*- r \ .. ^ \ V I • P A G E F O R T Y WEDNESDAY, 'JUNE 24, 1970 ittanrliratpr lEaatttng H^araUt A :\ Jfosf Manchester Stores Open Until 9 O^Clock Members of Scandla Lodge, About Town Vasa Order of America, will at­ Some Downtown Shoppers Average Daily Net Prem Run r h , Parents Without Partners, tend Vasa Field Day on Sun­ The Weather Manchester Chapter, will hold day starting at 9:80 a.m. at AN EXOmm PARTY IDGAI For The Week Kkided Vasa Park, South Meriden. To Receive Lucky Bucks June 99, 1970 Fair, unsenaonably oqdI an Informal coffee and conver­ CiMfemar flefc-Up nigtit; low about SS. Ttamorroav sation, at the home of Mrs. Ed­ There will be entertainment, games and dancing. Dinners sunny, low humkUity; Mgh na Geer, 80 W'etherell St. to­ “ Lucky Buck" cards will be tion was the Mystery Shopper. Hem* D«1lv«r*d liH M * of Swedish meatballs and sill distributed to shoppers in the 70a. Saturday’s ouUook-«taudy, night at 8. The meeting is open Next month, the promotion 15,770 herring wlU be served. Hoidogs Downtown business area tomor­ chance o< alwwrara. to interested persons. Hostess wilt focus on the mid-July Side­ in tmd hamburgers will alsO' be row through Saturday, entitling walk Sales. In August, actual- Mancheater— A City of Village Charm asks, to be notified by those available. the card holders to $6 worth of size antique cars will be dis­ planning to attend. retail merchandising. played in the Downtown busi­ i move VOL. LXXXIX, NO.
    [Show full text]
  • How Did Britain Democratize?1 Views from the Sovereign Bond Market
    How did Britain Democratize?1 Views from the Sovereign Bond Market Aditya Dasgupta2 and Daniel Ziblatt3 1 Acknowledgements: We thank Jim Alt, Ann Carlos, Jeff Frieden, Noam Gidron, Alexander Kuo, James Robinson, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, three anonymous reviewers and seminar participants at Harvard, the Juan March Institute, UCLA, and Yale for comments and Robert Brown and Stephen Easton for sharing data. All errors are our own. 2 PhD Candidate, Department of Government, Harvard University. 1737 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA, 02139. Email: [email protected]. 3 Professor of Government, Department of Government, Harvard University. 1737 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA, 02139. Email: [email protected]. 1 How Did Britain Democratize? Views from the Sovereign Bond Market Abstract To assess competing theories of democratization, we analyze British sovereign bond market responses to the 1832, 1867 and 1884 Reform Acts, and to two failed Chartist agitations for reform. Analyses of high-frequency 3% consol yield data and historical financial press suggest three conclusions. First, democratic reform episodes were preceded by increases in perceived political risk, comparable to democratizing episodes in other countries. Second, both democratic reform and repression were followed by yield declines. Third, the source of political risk in Britain was both social unrest and political deadlock. Together, the findings challenge the “Whig” characterization of British democratization as exceptionally risk-free. Introduction The process of democratization in Britain – in particular the franchise expansions legislated in the 1832, 1867, and 1884 Reform Acts– has attracted intensive scholarly attention.4 One long-standing 4 In this paper we follow the dominant strand in the social scientific literature that refers to “democratization” as the process of introducing democratic political institutions that began in Europe largely in the nineteenth century, with some precursors earlier, along three main dimensions: 1) the expansion and equalization of the right to vote (e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Proquest Dissertations
    THE IMPACT OF ILE ROYALE ON NEW ENGLAND 1713 - 1763 by Donald F. Chard LtMAA.Ci A thesis submitted to the School of Graduate Studies in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Ph.D. in History UNIVERSITY OF OTTAWA OTTAWA, CANADA, 1976 Chard, Ottawa, Canada, 1977 UMI Number: DC54008 INFORMATION TO USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleed-through, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adversely affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. UMI® UMI Microform DC54008 Copyright 2011 by ProQuest LLC All rights reserved. This microform edition is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code. ProQuest LLC 789 East Eisenhower Parkway P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE CHAPTER TABLE OF CONTENTS i TABLES AND MAPS ii ABBREVIATIONS iii NOTE ON DATES iv INTRODUCTION vi I. CANSO, 1710-1721: FOCAL POINT OF NEW ENGLAND- ILE ROYALE RIVALRY 1 II. PATTERNS OF TRADE, 1720-1744 34 III. THE LOUISBOURG EXPEDITION OF 1745 67 IV. VICTORY AT LOUISBOURG: ECONOMIC EXPECTATIONS AND REALIZATIONS, 1745-1748 103 V. THE BITTER FRUITS OF VICTORY: MILITARY AND SOCIAL REPERCUSSIONS OF THE 1745 ASSAULT ON LOUISBOURG 139 VI. IMPERIAL SUBSIDIES AND CURRENCY ADJUTSMENTS.. 168 VII. NEW ENGLAND'S ROLE IN THE ESTABLISHMENT OF HALIFAX AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF NOVA SCOTIA 1749-1755 188 VIII.
    [Show full text]
  • The Home Office and Public Disturbance, C.1800-1832
    The Home Office and Public Disturbance, c.1800-1832 Nathan Ashley Bend Submitted to the University of Hertfordshire in partial fulfilment of the requirements of the degree of PhD. May 2018 ii Abstract This thesis examines the role of the Home Office in the machinery of order from c.1800-1832. It combines institutional enquiry with the study of popular protest by examining protest from the viewpoint of the Home Office. It looks at how the growth of the Home Office was stagnated due to efforts to economise, and how it transformed its systems to make them more efficient in response to peaks of administrative work caused by popular tumult. The different roles that each person performed in the Home Office is outlined, and by doing so the pivotal role of the permanent under- secretary of state, who remains underrepresented in histories of protest, is exposed. It also looks at what powers the home secretary had at his disposal, and how they were used to repress food riots, the Luddite disturbances, the movement for parliamentary reform, the Swing riots, political agitation leading to the Great Reform Act, and trade unions. It compares the different approaches of home secretaries and argues that although the use of powers was generally guided by established precedent, others such as domestic espionage were more divisive, and were influenced by the personality and experience of the home secretary. The thesis also examines the relationships between the Home Office hierarchy and government departments with authorities in the provinces. This thesis brings together all the available records which relate to the Home Office as an institution and those which relate to public disturbance.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Notices
    THE LONDON GAZETTE, 16TH MAY 1969 5169 Public Notices Any Public Notices received too late for classification appear on a later page; see Contents on first page BANK OF ENGLAND AN ACCOUNT pursuant to the Acts 7 & 8 Viet. ch. 32,18 & 19 Geo. 5. ch. 13 and 9 & 10 Geo. 6. ch. 74, for the Week ending on Wednesday, the 14th day of May 1969. Issue DEPARTMENT £ £ Notes issued: Government Debt ... 11,015,100 In Circulation 3,188,832,624 Other Government Securities 3,238,010,240 In Banking Department 61,587,026 Other Securities 714,660 Coin other than Gold Coin ... 260,000 Amount of Fiduciary Issue ... £3,250,000,000 Gold Coin and Bullion 419,650 £3,250,419,650 £3,250,419,650 Dated the 15th day of May 1969. J. S. Fforde, Chief Cashier. BANKING DEPARTMENT £ Capital 14,553,000 Government Securities 433,104,415 Rest 3,342,426 Other Securities 235,753,722 Public Deposits (including Exchequer, Notes 61,587,026 National Loans Fund, National Coin 827,719 Debt Commissioners and Dividend Accounts) 14,466,709 Other Deposits 698,910,747 Seven Day and other Bills £731,272,882 £731,272,882 Dated the 15th day of May 1969. J. S. Fforde, Chief Cashier. 14th May 1969, at the offices of the Board at WATER ACTS Bamford, Sheffield. A notice explaining the effect of the proposed Ministry of Housing and Local Government Order will be found in The Leicester Mercury, The May 1969 Sheffield Morning Telegraph, The Nottingham Guardian Journal and The Derby Evening Telegraph DERWENT VALLEY WATER BOARD of the 14th and 21st days of May 1969.
    [Show full text]
  • Pirate Articles and Their Society, 1660-1730
    ‘Piratical Schemes and Contracts’: Pirate Articles and their Society, 1660-1730 Submitted by Edward Theophilus Fox to the University of Exeter as a thesis for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Maritime History In May 2013 This thesis is available for Library use on the understanding that it is copyright material and that no quotation from the thesis may be published without proper acknowledgement. I certify that all material in this thesis which is not my own work has been identified and that no material has previously been submitted and approved for the award of a degree by this or any other University. Signature: ………………………………………………………….. 1 Abstract During the so-called ‘golden age’ of piracy that occurred in the Atlantic and Indian Oceans in the later seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries, several thousands of men and a handful of women sailed aboard pirate ships. The narrative, operational techniques, and economic repercussions of the waves of piracy that threatened maritime trade during the ‘golden age’ have fascinated researchers, and so too has the social history of the people involved. Traditionally, the historiography of the social history of pirates has portrayed them as democratic and highly egalitarian bandits, divided their spoil fairly amongst their number, offered compensation for comrades injured in battle, and appointed their own officers by popular vote. They have been presented in contrast to the legitimate societies of Europe and America, and as revolutionaries, eschewing the unfair and harsh practices prevalent in legitimate maritime employment. This study, however, argues that the ‘revolutionary’ model of ‘golden age’ pirates is not an accurate reflection of reality.
    [Show full text]
  • Topic 2 Revision Sheet – Reform and Reaction 1830-1841
    Topic 2 Revision sheet – Reform and reaction 1830-1841 After Catholic Emancipation Act 1829: Tory split into Ultras, Canningites and Wellington supporters Background – King George died, poor harvests unemployment, rising prises and population The want for reform! • Whigs were pushing for parliamentary reform and the Tory Cannigites supported the Whigs • Middle class wanted reform and representation • King William IV more open to reform than his predecessor Whigs came to power in 1830 – a coalition of Whigs and Canningite Tories Who were they? . Prime minister = Earl Grey . Foreign Secretary = Viscount Palmerston . Lord Chancellor = Lord Brougham – a radical Whig keen on reform . Home Secretary = Lord Melbourne . Leader of house of commons/Paymaster of the forces = Lord John Russell. Swing Riots – 1830-1 (Got name from Captain Swing) Causes = poor harvests 1829 and 1830, rising prices and population and shortage of jobs - Riots erupted in rural areas of southern and eastern England - included agricultural labourers and craftsmen - Riots were not organised, but had common targets of new threshing machines/property of farmers - Riots not linked with demands in reform but caused political pressure Increase in number of political unions (e.g. BPU) – increased pressure for reform Problems with electoral system - Unequal constituencies - Open boroughs, pocket boroughs, rotten boroughs, pot wallopers - Elections only held if seat was to be contested - Men who owned land worth 40 shillings could only vote The Great Reform Bill 1st Bill March 1831
    [Show full text]
  • Manchester's Radical History How Hyde
    7/1/2021 Manchester's Radical History – Exploring Greater Manchester's Grassroots History Manchester's Radical History Exploring Greater Manchester's Grassroots History NOVEMBER 30, 2013 BY SARAH IRVING How Hyde ‘Spymasters’ looked for Commies on BBC Children’s Hour By Derek Paison Salford born folk singer and song- writer Ewan MacColl is remembered today more for his music than his agit-prop plays. But it was his political activities before the last war and his membership of the Communist Party that led to MI5 opening a file on him in the 1930s and why they kept him, and his friends, under close surveillance. Secret service papers released by the national archives, now in Ashton-under-Lyne central library, offer a clue into how British intelligence (MI5) spied on working-class folk singer Ewan MacColl and his wife playwright, Joan Lilewood, who lived at Oak Coage on Higham Lane, Hyde, Cheshire, during World War II. MI5 opened a file on James Henry Miller (MacColl’s real name) in the early 1930s when he was living in Salford. As an active Communist Party member, he had been involved in the unemployed workers’ campaigns and in the mass trespass of Kinder Scout in Derbyshire. Before enlisting in the army in July 1940, he had wrien for the radio programme Children’s Hour. In Joan Lilewood’s autobiography, she writes: “Jimmie was registered at the Labour Exchange as a motor mechanic, but he did beer busking, singing Hebridean songs to cinema queues. Someone drew Archie Harding’s aention to him and from that time on he appeared in the North Region’s features (BBC) whenever a ‘proletarian’ voice was needed.” As a BBC presenter for Children’s Hour and Communist Party member, Lilewood also came under the watch of MI5.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Drummond, the Boundary Commission and the 1832 Reform Act*
    ‘One of the best men of business we had ever met’: Thomas Drummond, the boundary commission and the 1832 Reform Act* Martin Spychal Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/histres/article/90/249/543/5603617 by guest on 27 September 2021 Institute of Historical Research/History of Parliament Abstract As one of Britain’s landmark constitutional reforms, the 1832 Reform Act has attracted considerable historical attention. However, only cursory notice has been paid to the extensive work completed by the 1831–2 boundary commission to reform the nation’s parliamentary boundaries. Drawing on previously unused archival material, this article provides the first sustained analysis of the boundary reforms that took place in England’s ancient boroughs in 1832, revealing the significance of Thomas Drummond, a previously obscure royal engineer and chair of the English and Welsh boundary commission, to the ‘Great Reform Act’. As well as revealing the wider importance of parliamentary boundaries to the passage of reform by 1832, Drummond and the boundary commission established significant precedents for the expansion of the reformed British state and future parliamentary reform. On 1 December 1831, as political union activity surrounding the reform bill reached fever pitch and the government of the second Earl Grey was making preparations to introduce its third reform bill of the year, Staffordshire M.P. Edward Littleton sat down for dinner in London with several prominent whigs. Conversation turned to the topic of Thomas Drummond – a royal engineer who since August that year had been supervising the operations of the English and Welsh borough boundary commission as part of the government’s preparations for electoral reform.
    [Show full text]
  • The Aesthetics of Global Protest: Visual Culture and Communication
    PROTEST AND SOCIAL MOVEMENTS Jenzen & Korkut (eds) Jenzen McGarry, Erhart, Eslen-Ziya, The Aesthetics of Global Protest Edited by Aidan McGarry, Itir Erhart, Hande Eslen-Ziya, Olu Jenzen, and Umut Korkut The Aesthetics of Global Protest Visual Culture and Communication The Aesthetics of Global Protest Protest and Social Movements Recent years have seen an explosion of protest movements around the world, and academic theories are racing to catch up with them. This series aims to further our understanding of the origins, dealings, decisions, and outcomes of social movements by fostering dialogue among many traditions of thought, across European nations and across continents. All theoretical perspectives are welcome. Books in the series typically combine theory with empirical research, dealing with various types of mobilization, from neighborhood groups to revolutions. We especially welcome work that synthesizes or compares different approaches to social movements, such as cultural and structural traditions, micro- and macro-social, economic and ideal, or qualitative and quantitative. Books in the series will be published in English. One goal is to encourage non- native speakers to introduce their work to Anglophone audiences. Another is to maximize accessibility: all books will be available in open access within a year after printed publication. Series Editors Jan Willem Duyvendak is professor of Sociology at the University of Amsterdam. James M. Jasper teaches at the Graduate Center of the City University of New York. The Aesthetics of Global Protest Visual Culture and Communication Edited by Aidan McGarry, Itir Erhart, Hande Eslen-Ziya, Olu Jenzen, and Umut Korkut Amsterdam University Press Cover illustration: With permission of Seamus Travers, Travers Photography, Dublin, Ireland.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Reflections on Student Movements of the 1960S and Early
    Revista Crítica de Ciências Sociais 81 | 2008 Memória e actualidade dos movimentos estudantis Some Reflections on Student Movements of the 1960s and Early 1970s Some Reflections on Student Movements of the 1960s and Early 1970s Quelques réflexions sur les mouvements étudiants des années soixante et du commencement des années soixante-dix Colin Barker Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/rccs/646 DOI: 10.4000/rccs.646 ISSN: 2182-7435 Publisher Centro de Estudos Sociais da Universidade de Coimbra Printed version Date of publication: 1 June 2008 Number of pages: 43-91 ISSN: 0254-1106 Electronic reference Colin Barker, « Some Reflections on Student Movements of the 1960s and Early 1970s », Revista Crítica de Ciências Sociais [Online], 81 | 2008, Online since 01 October 2012, connection on 10 December 2020. URL : http://journals.openedition.org/rccs/646 ; DOI : https://doi.org/10.4000/rccs. 646 Revista Crítica de Ciências Sociais, 81, Junho 2008: 43-91 COLIN BARKER Some Reflections on Student Movements of the 1960s and Early 1970s this article considers the rise and decline of student movements in Europe and america during the 1960s and 1970s. Drawing on materials on student movements in a number of countries, it assesses their historical significance, in the context of a larger ‘protest wave’ with which the student movements of the period intersected. Relating these movements to students’ changing position within advanced capitalism, it suggests that their dynamics were shaped both by the specific characteristics of students as political actors and by the patterns of their inter‑relations with other contemporaneous move‑ ments. the article concludes by noting more recent developments, suggesting that the story of student movements still offers interesting new possibilities.
    [Show full text]