Introduction

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Introduction How did Britain Democratize? Views from the Sovereign Bond Market Aditya Dasgupta1 Daniel Ziblatt2 Abstract To assess competing theories of democratization, we analyze British sovereign bond market responses to the 1832, 1867 and 1884 Reform Acts, and to two failed Chartist agitations. Analyses of high-frequency 3% consol yield data and historical financial press suggest three conclusions. First, democratic reform episodes were preceded by increases in perceived political risk, comparable to democratizing episodes in other countries. Second, both democratic reform and repression were followed by yield de- clines. Third, the source of political risk in Britain was both social unrest and political deadlock. Together, the findings challenge the \Whig" characterization of British de- mocratization as exceptionally risk-free. Introduction The process of democratization in Britain { the franchise expansions legislated in the 1832, 1867, and 1884 Reform Acts in particular { has attracted a great deal of scholarly argument over how democracy emerged. One long-standing view, rooted in a classical \Whig" interpre- tation of history (see critique by Herbert Butterfield (1965)), is that Britain was distinctive in requiring little social and political conflict to democratize. Others argue that, whether driven by destabilizing constitutional crises or even the threat of mass revolution (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005), the process of democratization in Britain was deeply conflictual. A key empirical issue at stake in this debate is this: what was the level of perceived political risk during each of Britain's major episodes of suffrage expansion? Scholars on both sides of 1PhD Candidate, Department of Government, Harvard University. Email: [email protected] 2Professor, Department of Government, Harvard University. Email: [email protected] 1 the debate have mined the historical record for evidence favoring their view, at considerable risk of choosing facts to fit the theory. A key methodological problem in this debate has been that scholars have relied considerably on the written and verbal statements of historical protagonists to try to reconstruct their perceptions. Since politicians are strategic in their rhetoric, it is difficult to accurately reconstruct on the basis of statements how fearful political and other social actors actually were of the political events surrounding democratization. This paper takes a new empirical approach to the debate based on examining the response of the market for British sovereign bonds to the Reform Acts. We analyze high-frequency yield data on the British 3% consol, a perpetual government bond which was among the most widely traded securities in nineteenth-century Europe. Bond yields, which impound default and currency risk associated with possible regime instability, represent a reliable contemporaneous indicator of perceived political risk or \barometer of the agitation which is working the public mind," as The Times of London financial pages reported during the 1832 reform crisis (The Times, 12 May 1832). Fluctuations in bond yields represent revealed preferences and therefore can plausibly be viewed as less strategic and more \sincere" than political speeches alone. Finally, analysis of bond yields has two further benefits: it enables comparison of perceived political risk during British reform episodes with analogous events in other countries as well as comparison within Britain across time periods. Our semi-parametric statistical analysis of trends in monthly averages of 3% consol yields around the passage of each of the Reform Acts suggests that franchise extension was preceded by a sharp increase in perceived political risk in the case of the 1832 and 1867 Reform Acts but not the 1884 Reform Act. Surprisingly, however, we also find that the passage of reform was viewed by markets as reducing, rather than contributing to, risk, with yields returning to pre-crisis levels with the passage of democratic reform. We also apply the analysis to two well known \failed" cases of agitation for reform, the Chartist agitations for franchise extension of 1842 and 1848, which suggests that the bond market also viewed repression as 2 an effective form of political stabilization. How large was the political risk during British reform episodes? A within-country com- parison with other time periods in Britain suggests that reform episodes in Britain were associated with exceptionally high levels of bond market volatility. A cross-country com- parison suggests that bond market volatility associated with the reform episodes in Britain was comparable to that of major reform episodes in other western European countries. At the height of the 1832 reform crisis, investors discounted the value of consols by 16.6% from the pre-crisis baseline, while at the height of the 1867 reform crisis investors discounted the value of consols by 8.7%. Finally, to identify the source of this perceived political risk, we conduct structural break analyses utilizing daily and weekly 3% consol yield data and historical analysis of the events corresponding to the detected breaks. We find that both incidents of social unrest, such as the 1831 Swing Riots, and political deadlock, such as failure of reform bills in the legisla- ture, drove major increases in yields { with social unrest playing a large role mainly in the case of the 1832 Reform Act. We find that forward progress on reform, such as Benjamin Disraeli's pivotal acceptance of the Hodgkinson amendment to the 1867 reform bill, drove major decreases in bond yields. We corroborate these findings qualitatively, utilizing digital archives of The Times of London, The Economist, and The Investor's Monthly Manual, the major financial news sources of the time. In sum, our findings point to two main conclusions. First, we find evidence of major perceived political risk in bond markets immediately preceding the passage of the 1832 and 1867 Reform Acts, which was comparable to that of major democratic episodes in other western European countries. This finding runs against the classical \Whig" view that the \constitutional watershed" of 1688 meant that subsequent political and economic modernization in Britain, including nineteenth century mass democratization, could proceed absent significant political crisis. The results suggest that Britain's path of democratization, 3 especially in 1832 and in 1867, was more turbulent than analysts normally recognize. Second, we find that bond markets reacted favorably to the passage of democratic reform, with forward progress on reform corresponding to sharp drops in the premium that investors demanded to hold British sovereign debt. This second finding suggests that democratic reform in Britain was viewed by markets as an effective form of political stabilization. The paper is organized as follows. We first provide a brief history of the 1832, 1867 and 1884 Reform Acts as well as an overview of the theoretical debate. In the second section, we explain our empirical strategy and present the data. In the third section, we report the results. Finally, we conclude with interpretation of the results and thoughts on the the implications of our findings for the study of democratization more generally. Theoretical Debate The question of why incumbent nondemocratic elites dilute their power by expanding the franchise is a central question for the historical study of democratization (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005). The case of Britain { and the successive franchise expansions legislated in the Reform Acts of 1832, 1867, and 1884 { has attracted particular attention because it is considered to be an unusually gradual and consensual case of democratization without much of the crisis and social and political conflict that is normally thought to accompany democratization (Dahl, 1971). This unusually tranquil trajectory is typically explained with reference to the constitu- tional settlement of the 1688 Revolution that generated institutional checks that made the process of political and economic modernization one absent major political risk. In this view, the pre-industrial political violence of the seventeenth century (Moore, 1966), and the early supremacy of the English parliament, gave rise to a path of smooth democratization in Britain because its constitutional order was secure long before the age of mass suffrage 4 (North and Weingast, 1989; Ansell and Samuels, 2010; Cox, 2012). Whether suffrage expan- sion occurred as a result of an effort by political elites to shift British politics away from patronage to programmatic party competition (Lizzeri and Persico, 2004) or, as argued by Maurice Cowling (1967) and Gertrude Himmelfarb (1966), resulted from partisan political competition, in each of these views democratization in Britain was a low-stakes political process in a constitutional system that already provided well-institutionalized guarantees for secure property rights. But, challenging this account, a second prominent perspective highlights the presence of major social unrest and constitutional crisis in nineteenth century Britain, asserting that old regime elites only reluctantly conceded democratic reform in the face of intense social and political instability (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005; Morrison, 2011; Aidt and Franck, 2013). In one prominent illustration of this argument, Acemoglu and Robinson (2005) elegantly formalize and extend the old but controversial claim, made by the British historian G.M. Trevelyan (1920), that the Reform Acts were reluctant concessions intended
Recommended publications
  • “FRESHER by FAR” PRODUCE Ple of Peace with Israel and .Ac­ Son of West Hartfrod
    .r • 'V*- r \ .. ^ \ V I • P A G E F O R T Y WEDNESDAY, 'JUNE 24, 1970 ittanrliratpr lEaatttng H^araUt A :\ Jfosf Manchester Stores Open Until 9 O^Clock Members of Scandla Lodge, About Town Vasa Order of America, will at­ Some Downtown Shoppers Average Daily Net Prem Run r h , Parents Without Partners, tend Vasa Field Day on Sun­ The Weather Manchester Chapter, will hold day starting at 9:80 a.m. at AN EXOmm PARTY IDGAI For The Week Kkided Vasa Park, South Meriden. To Receive Lucky Bucks June 99, 1970 Fair, unsenaonably oqdI an Informal coffee and conver­ CiMfemar flefc-Up nigtit; low about SS. Ttamorroav sation, at the home of Mrs. Ed­ There will be entertainment, games and dancing. Dinners sunny, low humkUity; Mgh na Geer, 80 W'etherell St. to­ “ Lucky Buck" cards will be tion was the Mystery Shopper. Hem* D«1lv«r*d liH M * of Swedish meatballs and sill distributed to shoppers in the 70a. Saturday’s ouUook-«taudy, night at 8. The meeting is open Next month, the promotion 15,770 herring wlU be served. Hoidogs Downtown business area tomor­ chance o< alwwrara. to interested persons. Hostess wilt focus on the mid-July Side­ in tmd hamburgers will alsO' be row through Saturday, entitling walk Sales. In August, actual- Mancheater— A City of Village Charm asks, to be notified by those available. the card holders to $6 worth of size antique cars will be dis­ planning to attend. retail merchandising. played in the Downtown busi­ i move VOL. LXXXIX, NO.
    [Show full text]
  • Voting, Rhetoric, and the Determinants of Electoral Reform∗
    Taking the Leap: Voting, Rhetoric, and the Determinants of Electoral Reform∗ Scott Mosery Andrew Reevesz May 1, 2013 Abstract The Second Reform Act ushered in the age of democratic politics in the UK by expanding the voting franchise to include the working classes and providing new representation to industri- alized cities. Using unsupervised topic model analysis of parliamentary debates and quantitative analysis of roll call votes, we use new historical data to investigate why electoral reform suc- cessfully passed the House of Commons in 1867. Specifically we consider why reform passed under a minority Conservative government while a similar bill failed under a majority Liberal government despite no election or change in membership of the House of Commons. We find that party, not constituency, is responsible for explaining votes on reform and that, ultimately, it was the reduction in the number of aspects in the debate over reform that allowed a minority Conservative government to enact the Second Reform Act. ∗Paper prepared for the The Westminster Model of Democracy in Crisis? Comparative Perspectives on Origins, Development and Responses, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, May 13-14, 2013. yAssistant Professor, Department of Government, University of Texas at Austin, 1 University Sta. A1800, Austin, TX, 78712; http://smoser.webhost.utexas.edu/, [email protected], (512) 232-7305. zW. Glenn Campbell and Rita Ricardo-Campbell National Fellow and the Robert Eckles Swain National Fellow at the Hoover Institution; Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, 232 Bay State Road, Boston University, Boston, MA 02215; http://andrewreeves.org, [email protected], (650)723-8016. 1 Over the course of the nineteenth century, the United Kingdom's electoral system was trans- formed from an aristocratic oligarchy to one exhibiting most of the modern hallmarks of a democ- racy.
    [Show full text]
  • How Did Britain Democratize?1 Views from the Sovereign Bond Market
    How did Britain Democratize?1 Views from the Sovereign Bond Market Aditya Dasgupta2 and Daniel Ziblatt3 1 Acknowledgements: We thank Jim Alt, Ann Carlos, Jeff Frieden, Noam Gidron, Alexander Kuo, James Robinson, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, three anonymous reviewers and seminar participants at Harvard, the Juan March Institute, UCLA, and Yale for comments and Robert Brown and Stephen Easton for sharing data. All errors are our own. 2 PhD Candidate, Department of Government, Harvard University. 1737 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA, 02139. Email: [email protected]. 3 Professor of Government, Department of Government, Harvard University. 1737 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA, 02139. Email: [email protected]. 1 How Did Britain Democratize? Views from the Sovereign Bond Market Abstract To assess competing theories of democratization, we analyze British sovereign bond market responses to the 1832, 1867 and 1884 Reform Acts, and to two failed Chartist agitations for reform. Analyses of high-frequency 3% consol yield data and historical financial press suggest three conclusions. First, democratic reform episodes were preceded by increases in perceived political risk, comparable to democratizing episodes in other countries. Second, both democratic reform and repression were followed by yield declines. Third, the source of political risk in Britain was both social unrest and political deadlock. Together, the findings challenge the “Whig” characterization of British democratization as exceptionally risk-free. Introduction The process of democratization in Britain – in particular the franchise expansions legislated in the 1832, 1867, and 1884 Reform Acts– has attracted intensive scholarly attention.4 One long-standing 4 In this paper we follow the dominant strand in the social scientific literature that refers to “democratization” as the process of introducing democratic political institutions that began in Europe largely in the nineteenth century, with some precursors earlier, along three main dimensions: 1) the expansion and equalization of the right to vote (e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Analyzing the Agenda of Parliament in the Age of Reform∗
    Analyzing the Agenda of Parliament in the Age of Reform∗ VERY PRELIMINARY W. Walker Hanlon Northwestern University, NBER, CEPR July 27, 2021 Abstract This article provides a new measure of the agenda of the British Parliament{the sub- stantive topics on which debate was focused{from 1810-1914. This measure is obtained by applying a keyword approach to debate descriptions from the Hansard records. The results provide a new tool for analyzing the evolution of the British political system across this important period of history. To illustrate the utility of this measure, I an- alyze two issues. First, I use the data to identify key turning points, years that saw the most dramatic changes in the issues being debated. This analysis identifies three points, the First Reform Act (1832), the repeal of the Corn Laws (1846), and the rise of the Labour Party (1910), as critical periods of change. In contrast, little seems to have changed in the years around the Second Reform Act (1867) or Third Reform Act (1884). The data are also used to study the impact of changes in party control on the agenda of Parliament. I find little evidence that shifts in the identity of the party in government substantially influenced the issues that came before Parliament. This finding suggests that parties played a reactive rather than a proactive role in determining what issues Parliament needed to address at any given point in time. ∗I thank Alexandra E. Cirone and seminar participants at the Northwestern Economic History Brownbag for helpful comments. Author email: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Proquest Dissertations
    THE IMPACT OF ILE ROYALE ON NEW ENGLAND 1713 - 1763 by Donald F. Chard LtMAA.Ci A thesis submitted to the School of Graduate Studies in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Ph.D. in History UNIVERSITY OF OTTAWA OTTAWA, CANADA, 1976 Chard, Ottawa, Canada, 1977 UMI Number: DC54008 INFORMATION TO USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleed-through, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adversely affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. UMI® UMI Microform DC54008 Copyright 2011 by ProQuest LLC All rights reserved. This microform edition is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code. ProQuest LLC 789 East Eisenhower Parkway P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE CHAPTER TABLE OF CONTENTS i TABLES AND MAPS ii ABBREVIATIONS iii NOTE ON DATES iv INTRODUCTION vi I. CANSO, 1710-1721: FOCAL POINT OF NEW ENGLAND- ILE ROYALE RIVALRY 1 II. PATTERNS OF TRADE, 1720-1744 34 III. THE LOUISBOURG EXPEDITION OF 1745 67 IV. VICTORY AT LOUISBOURG: ECONOMIC EXPECTATIONS AND REALIZATIONS, 1745-1748 103 V. THE BITTER FRUITS OF VICTORY: MILITARY AND SOCIAL REPERCUSSIONS OF THE 1745 ASSAULT ON LOUISBOURG 139 VI. IMPERIAL SUBSIDIES AND CURRENCY ADJUTSMENTS.. 168 VII. NEW ENGLAND'S ROLE IN THE ESTABLISHMENT OF HALIFAX AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF NOVA SCOTIA 1749-1755 188 VIII.
    [Show full text]
  • The Home Office and Public Disturbance, C.1800-1832
    The Home Office and Public Disturbance, c.1800-1832 Nathan Ashley Bend Submitted to the University of Hertfordshire in partial fulfilment of the requirements of the degree of PhD. May 2018 ii Abstract This thesis examines the role of the Home Office in the machinery of order from c.1800-1832. It combines institutional enquiry with the study of popular protest by examining protest from the viewpoint of the Home Office. It looks at how the growth of the Home Office was stagnated due to efforts to economise, and how it transformed its systems to make them more efficient in response to peaks of administrative work caused by popular tumult. The different roles that each person performed in the Home Office is outlined, and by doing so the pivotal role of the permanent under- secretary of state, who remains underrepresented in histories of protest, is exposed. It also looks at what powers the home secretary had at his disposal, and how they were used to repress food riots, the Luddite disturbances, the movement for parliamentary reform, the Swing riots, political agitation leading to the Great Reform Act, and trade unions. It compares the different approaches of home secretaries and argues that although the use of powers was generally guided by established precedent, others such as domestic espionage were more divisive, and were influenced by the personality and experience of the home secretary. The thesis also examines the relationships between the Home Office hierarchy and government departments with authorities in the provinces. This thesis brings together all the available records which relate to the Home Office as an institution and those which relate to public disturbance.
    [Show full text]
  • Revisionist Analysis of Edmund Burke's Political Ideology
    University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers Graduate School 1991 Revisionist analysis of Edmund Burke's political ideology Raenelle Fisher The University of Montana Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Fisher, Raenelle, "Revisionist analysis of Edmund Burke's political ideology" (1991). Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers. 5247. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd/5247 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Maureen and Mike MANSFIELD LIBRARY Copying allowed as provided under provisions of the Fair Use Section of the U.S. COPYRIGHT LAW, 1976. Any copying for commercial purposes or financial gain may be undertaken only with the author’s written consent. University of A REVISIONIST ANALYSIS OF EDMUND BURKE'S POLITICAL IDEOLOGY by Raenelie Fisher B. AO, University of Montana, 1989 Presented in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts University of Montana 1991 Approved by Chairman, Board aminer Dean, Graduate School UMI Number: EP40711 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Notices
    THE LONDON GAZETTE, 16TH MAY 1969 5169 Public Notices Any Public Notices received too late for classification appear on a later page; see Contents on first page BANK OF ENGLAND AN ACCOUNT pursuant to the Acts 7 & 8 Viet. ch. 32,18 & 19 Geo. 5. ch. 13 and 9 & 10 Geo. 6. ch. 74, for the Week ending on Wednesday, the 14th day of May 1969. Issue DEPARTMENT £ £ Notes issued: Government Debt ... 11,015,100 In Circulation 3,188,832,624 Other Government Securities 3,238,010,240 In Banking Department 61,587,026 Other Securities 714,660 Coin other than Gold Coin ... 260,000 Amount of Fiduciary Issue ... £3,250,000,000 Gold Coin and Bullion 419,650 £3,250,419,650 £3,250,419,650 Dated the 15th day of May 1969. J. S. Fforde, Chief Cashier. BANKING DEPARTMENT £ Capital 14,553,000 Government Securities 433,104,415 Rest 3,342,426 Other Securities 235,753,722 Public Deposits (including Exchequer, Notes 61,587,026 National Loans Fund, National Coin 827,719 Debt Commissioners and Dividend Accounts) 14,466,709 Other Deposits 698,910,747 Seven Day and other Bills £731,272,882 £731,272,882 Dated the 15th day of May 1969. J. S. Fforde, Chief Cashier. 14th May 1969, at the offices of the Board at WATER ACTS Bamford, Sheffield. A notice explaining the effect of the proposed Ministry of Housing and Local Government Order will be found in The Leicester Mercury, The May 1969 Sheffield Morning Telegraph, The Nottingham Guardian Journal and The Derby Evening Telegraph DERWENT VALLEY WATER BOARD of the 14th and 21st days of May 1969.
    [Show full text]
  • Janice Carlisle, “On the Second Reform Act, 1867”
    Janice Carlisle, On the Second Reform Act,... http://www.branchcollective.org/?ps_articles=janice-carlisle-on-the-second-reform-act-1867 Janice Carlisle, “On the Second Reform Act, 1867” Introduction The Second Reform Act (1867) raised in its own time and continues to raise in ours two deceptively simple questions, one of cause and the other of effect. How did a bill for which there was so little enthusiasm become law? To what extent did its passage grant Britain a genuinely representative government? For many contemporary observers, the act was, for better or worse, an obviously liberalizing measure because it typically enfranchised a majority of working-class men living in the boroughs and cities of England and Wales. Thomas Carlyle, writing in his diatribe Shooting Niagara: And After? (1867), had no doubts that the Great Unwashed, as working men were often called, would soon be catastrophically ascendant: the country was about to take the “Niagara leap of democracy,” after which the nation would be ruled by a “Swarmery” of men “buzzing, humming . tumbling in infinite noise and darkness”; all political questions would be determined by a simple “Count of Heads” (4, 10, 1). The poet Coventry Patmore wrote in similar tones of despair, “the orgies of the multitude/ . now begin” (ll. 62-63). The number of potential new electors explains, at least in part, such hysteria. The Second Reform Act – more formally, An Act Further to Amend the Laws Relating to the Representation of the People in England and Wales (30 & 31 Vict., c. 102) – no doubt extended the work of the First Reform Act of 1832.
    [Show full text]
  • Pirate Articles and Their Society, 1660-1730
    ‘Piratical Schemes and Contracts’: Pirate Articles and their Society, 1660-1730 Submitted by Edward Theophilus Fox to the University of Exeter as a thesis for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Maritime History In May 2013 This thesis is available for Library use on the understanding that it is copyright material and that no quotation from the thesis may be published without proper acknowledgement. I certify that all material in this thesis which is not my own work has been identified and that no material has previously been submitted and approved for the award of a degree by this or any other University. Signature: ………………………………………………………….. 1 Abstract During the so-called ‘golden age’ of piracy that occurred in the Atlantic and Indian Oceans in the later seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries, several thousands of men and a handful of women sailed aboard pirate ships. The narrative, operational techniques, and economic repercussions of the waves of piracy that threatened maritime trade during the ‘golden age’ have fascinated researchers, and so too has the social history of the people involved. Traditionally, the historiography of the social history of pirates has portrayed them as democratic and highly egalitarian bandits, divided their spoil fairly amongst their number, offered compensation for comrades injured in battle, and appointed their own officers by popular vote. They have been presented in contrast to the legitimate societies of Europe and America, and as revolutionaries, eschewing the unfair and harsh practices prevalent in legitimate maritime employment. This study, however, argues that the ‘revolutionary’ model of ‘golden age’ pirates is not an accurate reflection of reality.
    [Show full text]
  • Topic 2 Revision Sheet – Reform and Reaction 1830-1841
    Topic 2 Revision sheet – Reform and reaction 1830-1841 After Catholic Emancipation Act 1829: Tory split into Ultras, Canningites and Wellington supporters Background – King George died, poor harvests unemployment, rising prises and population The want for reform! • Whigs were pushing for parliamentary reform and the Tory Cannigites supported the Whigs • Middle class wanted reform and representation • King William IV more open to reform than his predecessor Whigs came to power in 1830 – a coalition of Whigs and Canningite Tories Who were they? . Prime minister = Earl Grey . Foreign Secretary = Viscount Palmerston . Lord Chancellor = Lord Brougham – a radical Whig keen on reform . Home Secretary = Lord Melbourne . Leader of house of commons/Paymaster of the forces = Lord John Russell. Swing Riots – 1830-1 (Got name from Captain Swing) Causes = poor harvests 1829 and 1830, rising prices and population and shortage of jobs - Riots erupted in rural areas of southern and eastern England - included agricultural labourers and craftsmen - Riots were not organised, but had common targets of new threshing machines/property of farmers - Riots not linked with demands in reform but caused political pressure Increase in number of political unions (e.g. BPU) – increased pressure for reform Problems with electoral system - Unequal constituencies - Open boroughs, pocket boroughs, rotten boroughs, pot wallopers - Elections only held if seat was to be contested - Men who owned land worth 40 shillings could only vote The Great Reform Bill 1st Bill March 1831
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Paper 5: British Political History 1688-1886 List of Topics And
    1 Paper 5: British Political History 1688-1886 List of Topics and Bibliographies 2019-20 Efforts have been made to ensure that a large number of items are available electronically, but some items are not available in digital formats. Items marked with a † are only available in hardcopy from libraries. Where items are marked with a ‡ it means that extracts from that book are available on Moodle. Chronological topics 1. The impact of the1688 Revolution and the emergence of the Hanoverian settlement, 1688-1721 2. The Whig oligarchy and its opponents, 1721-60 3. George III and the politics of crisis, 1760-84 4. The younger Pitt, Fox, and the revolutionary era, 1784-1806 5. Lord Liverpool and Liberal Toryism 1807-27 6. The collapse of the ancien régime, 1827-35 7. The rise and fall of party in the age of Peel, 1834-50 8. Palmerston and mid-Victorian stability, 1848-67 9. Government and policy in the age of Gladstone and Disraeli, 1867-86 10. The parties and the people 1867-90 Thematic topics 11. The constitution: the roles of monarchy and parliament 12. The process of parliamentary reform, 1815-1886 13. Patriotism and national identity 14. Political communication and the development of a ‘public sphere’ in the eighteenth century 15. The powers of the state 16. Extra-parliamentary politics and political debate in the long eighteenth century 17. Chartism, class and the radical tradition, mainly after 1815 18. Gender and politics 19. Religion and politics 20. Scotland and Britain in the eighteenth century 21. Ireland, 1689-1885 22.
    [Show full text]