Kleptocracy and Divide- And- Rule

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Kleptocracy and Divide- And- Rule ALFRED MARSHALL LECTURE KLEPTOCRACY ANDDIVIDE-AND-RULE: AMODEL OFPERSONAL RULE DaronAcemoglu Thierry Verdier MassachusettsInstitute of Technology DELTA-ENS JamesA. Robinson Universityof California, Berkeley Abstract Manydeveloping countries have suffered under the personal rule of kleptocrats, who implementhighly inef cient economic policies, expropriate the wealth of their citizens, and usethe proceeds for their own glori cation or consumption. We argue that the success of kleptocratsrests, in part,on theirability to usea divide-and-rulestrategy, made possible by theweakness of institutionsin these societies. Members of society need to cooperate in order todepose a kleptocrat,yet such cooperation may be defused by imposing punitive rates of taxationon any citizen who proposes such a move,and redistributing the bene ts to those whoneed to agreeto it. Thus the collective action problem can be intensied bythreatswhich remainoff the equilibrium path. In equilibrium, all are exploited and no onechallenges the kleptocrat.Kleptocratic policies are more likely when foreign aid and rents from natural resourcesprovide rulers with substantial resources to buy off opponents; when opposition groupsare shortsighted; when the average productivity in the economy is low;and when there isgreater inequality between producer groups (because more productive groups are more difcult to buy off). (JEL: O12, H00) 1. Introduction Many countries in Africaand the Caribbean sufferunder “kleptocratic”regimes, wherethe state is controlled and run forthe benet of anindividual, or asmall group, who use their power to transfera large fraction of society’s resources to themselves. Examples of kleptocratic regimesinclude the DemocraticRepublic of the Congo (Zaire)under Mobutu Sese Seko, the Dominican Republic under RafaelTrujillo, Haiti under the Duvaliers, Nicaragua under the Somozas, Uganda under Idi Amin, Liberiaunder Charles Taylor, and the Philippines Acknowledgments: Paper presented as the Marshall Lecture at the European Economic Associ- ation’s Annual meetings in Stockholm, August 24, 2003. We thank Silje Aslaksen for pointing out an algebraic mistake in the rst version and Alexander Debs for excellent research assistance. E-mail addresses: Acemoglu: [email protected]; Robinson: [email protected]; Verdier: [email protected] Journal of the European Economic Association April–May 2004 2(2–3):162– 192 ©2004 by the European Economic Association Acemoglu, Robinson &VerdierKleptocracy and Divide-and-Rule 163 under Ferdinand Marcos. Inall these cases, kleptocratic regimesappear to have been disastrous foreconomic performanceand caused the impoverishment of the citizens. Astudy of the political economy of such regimesmust depart fromthe standard presumptions of most researchin economics and political science, which assume that rulers makechoices within strongly institutionalized poli- ties.1 In these polities, formalpolitical institutions, such as the constitution, the structure of the legislature, or electoral rules, place constraints on the behavior of politicians and political elites, and directly in uence political outcomes. In contrast, kleptocracy emergesin weakly institutionalized polities, whereformal institutions neither place signi cant restrictions on politicians ’ actions nor make them accountable to citizens. While the academicstudy of strongly institutionalized polities is well advanced (e.g., Shepsle and Weingast 1995; Cox 1997; Persson and Tabellini 2000, 2003), there arefew studies, and less of aconsensus, on the nature of weakly institutionalized polities. What determines corruption, rent extraction and bad policies when institutions areweak? Indeed, the qualitative nature of politics appears to differmarkedly between strongly and weakly institutional- ized polities: when institutions arestrong, citizens punish politicians by voting them out of power; when institutions areweak, politicians punish citizens who failto support them. When institutions arestrong, politicians vie forthe support and endorsement of interest groups; when institutions areweak, politicians createand control interest groups. When institutions arestrong, citizens demand rights; when institutions areweak, citizens beg forfavors. The researchprogram proposed in this paper is asystematic study of policymaking in weakly institutionalized societies, and ultimately, astudy of the process by which strongly institutionalized societies emerge(see North and Weingast (1989) fora classic account of such aprocess). Totake a rst step in this program, weconstruct amodel to study kleptocratic politics. Perhaps the most puzzling featureof kleptocracies, illustrated by the examples fromthe Congo, the Dominican Republic, Nicaragua, or Haiti, is their longevity, despite the disastrous policies pursued by the rulers. 2 This longevity is madeeven more paradoxical by the factthat such regimesapparently lacked apolitical base (a core constituency) that supported them. Despite the absence of formalinstitu- tional mechanisms fordeposing unpopular rulers, constraints on the behavior of rulers exist even in weakly-institutionalized societies (e.g., the threat of revo- 1. We owe this terminology and the distinction between strongly and weakly institutionalized polities to Robert Powell. 2. Despite the appealing intuition, perhaps derived from many political analyses of strongly institutionalized societies, that rulers who reduce the utility of citizens ought to be replaced, this appears not to be the case in weakly-institutionalized societies. Many kleptocrats rule for long periods, Mobutu for 32 years, Trujillo for 31 years, and the Somozas for 42 years. 164 Journal of the European Economic Association lution, or competition fromother strongmen). Why do, then, the heavily taxed producers or the poverty-stricken citizens not replacethe kleptocrat? Why do they rarelyform an effectiveopposition constraining the kleptocrat? How can a regimethat apparently bene ts nobody outside of the narrowest of cliques survive? Our basic answer is that this is because the absence of strong institu- tions allows rulers to adopt political strategies which arehighly effectiveat defusing any opposition to their regime. The seminal book by Robert Bates, Markets and States inTropical Africa, provides many clues towards an answer. Bates described the web of inef cient transfers and policies in effectin many parts of Africa,but most notably in Ghana and Zambia,and suggested the following logic: many of these inef cient policies arein place to transferresources fromthe population to the ruling groups, while at the sametime ensuring their political survival. Inparticular, the nexus of inef cient policies appeared to be useful forcreating anenvironment where any group that becamepolitically mobilized against the rulers could be punished, while those that remained loyal wererewarded. With this logic, the Ghanaian government heavily taxed cocoa producers, while atthe sametime subsidizing their inputs of seeds and fertilizers.The subsidies could be allocated selectively as apotential rewardfor not attempting to change the status quo. Similarly, the exchange ratewas kept overvalued because then the government could allocate or withhold valuable rations of foreign exchange in order to guarantee support. In this paper, wesuggest ageneralization of this reasoning, which wedub the divide-and-rule strategy. Divide-and-rule is amethod used by kleptocrats to maintain power in weakly-institutionalized polities while simultaneously pur- suing policies costly to society. The logic of the divide-and-rule strategy is to enable arulerto bribe politically pivotal groups offthe equilibrium path, ensuring that he can remainin power against challenges. To remove arulerfrom power requires the cooperation of distinct social groups which is madedif cult by the collective action problem (Olson 1965). By providing selective incentives and punishments, the divide-and-rule strategy exploits the fragility of social cooperation: when facedwith the threat of being ousted, the kleptocratic ruler intensi es the collective action problem and destroys the coalition against him by bribing the pivotal groups. Moreexplicitly, weconsider adynamic gamebetween the rulerand two producer groups. The kleptocratic rulertaxes production and uses the resulting tax revenue, the rents fromnatural resources and potential foreign aid from outside donors forhis own consumption. The two producer groups, ifthey can cooperate, can remove the rulerfrom power and establish democracy (aregime morefavorable to their interests). We model this cooperation asfollows: one of the two groups (the proposer) makes aproposal to remove the rulerfrom power, and ifthe other group (the proposed) agrees, the ruleris removed and democracy Acemoglu, Robinson &VerdierKleptocracy and Divide-and-Rule 165 is established. The ruler-friendly political institutions, however, imply that before the proposed group responds to the proposal, the rulercan makea counteroffer. This counteroffer enables him to use adivide-and-rule strategy: following achallenge, the ruleruses all his resources and tax revenues to bribe the proposed group (and compensate them forfuture higher taxes ifthey turn down the proposal and keep the rulerin power). Ifhe can do so successfully, he can ght offthe challenge, and anticipating this, no group will challenge the ruler. Therefore,the divide-and-rule strategy remainsoff the equilibrium path, and its anticipation implies that the rulercan follow highly distortionary
Recommended publications
  • Directors Fortnight Cannes 2000 Winner Best Feature
    DIRECTORS WINNER FORTNIGHT BEST FEATURE CANNES PAN-AFRICAN FILM 2000 FESTIVAL L.A. A FILM BY RAOUL PECK A ZEITGEIST FILMS RELEASE JACQUES BIDOU presents A FILM BY RAOUL PECK Patrice Lumumba Eriq Ebouaney Joseph Mobutu Alex Descas Maurice Mpolo Théophile Moussa Sowié Joseph Kasa Vubu Maka Kotto Godefroid Munungo Dieudonné Kabongo Moïse Tshombe Pascal Nzonzi Walter J. Ganshof Van der Meersch André Debaar Joseph Okito Cheik Doukouré Thomas Kanza Oumar Diop Makena Pauline Lumumba Mariam Kaba General Emile Janssens Rudi Delhem Director Raoul Peck Screenplay Raoul Peck Pascal Bonitzer Music Jean-Claude Petit Executive Producer Jacques Bidou Production Manager Patrick Meunier Marianne Dumoulin Director of Photography Bernard Lutic 1st Assistant Director Jacques Cluzard Casting Sylvie Brocheré Artistic Director Denis Renault Art DIrector André Fonsny Costumes Charlotte David Editor Jacques Comets Sound Mixer Jean-Pierre Laforce Filmed in Zimbabwe, Mozambique and Belgium A French/Belgian/Haitian/German co-production, 2000 In French with English subtitles 35mm • Color • Dolby Stereo SRD • 1:1.85 • 3144 meters Running time: 115 mins A ZEITGEIST FILMS RELEASE 247 CENTRE ST • 2ND FL • NEW YORK • NY 10013 www.zeitgeistfilm.com • [email protected] (212) 274-1989 • FAX (212) 274-1644 At the Berlin Conference of 1885, Europe divided up the African continent. The Congo became the personal property of King Leopold II of Belgium. On June 30, 1960, a young self-taught nationalist, Patrice Lumumba, became, at age 36, the first head of government of the new independent state. He would last two months in office. This is a true story. SYNOPSIS LUMUMBA is a gripping political thriller which tells the story of the legendary African leader Patrice Emery Lumumba.
    [Show full text]
  • Protecting Politics: Deterring the Influence Of
    Protecting Politics Deterring the Influence of Organized Crime on Elections Protecting Politics: Deterring the Influence of Organized Crime on Elections Elections are essential elements of democratic systems. Unfortunately, abuse and manipulation (including voter intimidation, vote buying or ballot stuffing) can distort these processes. However, little attention has been paid to an intrinsic part of this threat: the conditions and opportunities for criminal interference in the electoral process. Most worrying, few scholars have examined the underlying conditions that make elections vulnerable to organized criminal involvement. This report addresses these gaps in knowledge by analysing the vulnerabilities of electoral processes to illicit interference (above all by organized crime). It suggests how national and international authorities might better protect these crucial and coveted elements of the democratic process. Case studies from Georgia, Mali and Mexico illustrate these challenges and provide insights into potential ways to prevent and mitigate the effects of organized crime on elections. International IDEA Clingendael Institute ISBN 978-91-7671-069-2 Strömsborg P.O. Box 93080 SE-103 34 Stockholm 2509 AB The Hague Sweden The Netherlands T +46 8 698 37 00 T +31 70 324 53 84 F +46 8 20 24 22 F +31 70 328 20 02 9 789176 710692 > [email protected] [email protected] www.idea.int www.clingendael.nl ISBN: 978-91-7671-069-2 Protecting Politics Deterring the Influence of Organized Crime on Elections Protecting Politics Deterring the Influence of Organized Crime on Elections Series editor: Catalina Uribe Burcher Lead authors: Ivan Briscoe and Diana Goff © 2016 International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance © 2016 Netherlands Institute of International Relations (Clingendael Institute) International IDEA Strömsborg SE-103 34 Stockholm Sweden Tel: +46 8 698 37 00, fax: +46 8 20 24 22 Email: [email protected], website: www.idea.int Clingendael Institute P.O.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Leaders in Africa: Presidents, Patrons Or Profiteers?
    Political Leaders in Africa: Presidents, Patrons or Profiteers? By Jo-Ansie van Wyk Occasional Paper Series: Volume 2, Number 1, 2007 The Occasional Paper Series is published by The African Centre for the Constructive Resolution of Disputes (ACCORD). ACCORD is a non-governmental, non-aligned conflict resolution organisation based in Durban, South Africa. ACCORD is constituted as an education trust. Views expressed in this Occasional Paper are not necessarily those of ACCORD. While every attempt is made to ensure that the information published here is accurate, no responsibility is accepted for any loss or damage that may arise out of the reliance of any person upon any of the information this Occassional Paper contains. Copyright © ACCORD 2007 All rights reserved. Apart from any fair dealing for the purpose of private study, research, criticism or review, as permitted under the Copyright Act, no part may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior permission of the publisher. ISSN 1608-3954 Unsolicited manuscripts may be submitted to: The Editor, Occasional Paper Series, c/o ACCORD, Private Bag X018, Umhlanga Rocks 4320, Durban, South Africa or email: [email protected] Manuscripts should be about 10 000 words in length. All references must be included. Abstract It is easy to experience a sense of déjà vu when analysing political lead- ership in Africa. The perception is that African leaders rule failed states that have acquired tags such as “corruptocracies”, “chaosocracies” or “terrorocracies”. Perspectives on political leadership in Africa vary from the “criminalisation” of the state to political leadership as “dispensing patrimony”, the “recycling” of elites and the use of state power and resources to consolidate political and economic power.
    [Show full text]
  • Post-Communist Mafia State
    REVIEWS 275 tion’s wealth for themselves: rather, as is the Magyar, Bálint: case in Hungary, it could be a country whose corrupt, kleptocratic leaders also go out of POST-COMMUNIST MAFIA STATE. their way to actively control illicit societal THE CASE OF HUNGARY. activities and organized crime. These leaders do not simply steal from the state: they rot Budapest: Central European University it and create a society of thieves dependent Press. 2016. 311 pages. upon the elites who sanction their crimes (pp. 81–82). It is a vicious cycle that makes DOI: 10.5817/PC2018-3-275 everyone complicit in the state’s corruption. Magyar’s latest text successfully tests his An unequivocal condemnation of the Fi­ expanded theory of the mafia state, con­ desz­controlled Hungary, Bálint Magyar’s cretizing it and demonstrating how Hun­ Post-Communist Mafia State: The Case of gary’s authoritarian government can mas­ Hungary could not be timelier. This book querade as a ‘good’ state whilst eroding civil explores the deceitful mechanisms by which society and democratic institutions – even the hybrid regime installed by Prime Min­ without exerting any physical mass violence ister Viktor Orbán and his fellow Fidesz of­ (see Levitsky, Lucan 2010). It argues that ficials has systematically stripped Hungari­ Hungary is a corrupt, parasitic state (p. 13). ans of civil liberties (p. 255) with impunity, The book begins with the premise that upon ironically owing to its control over the rule its accession to the European Union in 2004, of law. While this text specifically investi­ Hungary was the model of liberal democrat­ gates democratic backsliding in Hungary, its ic consolidation for other former Commu­ framework will surely prove crucial for un­ nist states.
    [Show full text]
  • Power and Plunder in Putin's Russia Miriam Lanskoy, Dylan Myles-Primakoff
    Power and Plunder in Putin's Russia Miriam Lanskoy, Dylan Myles-Primakoff Journal of Democracy, Volume 29, Number 1, January 2018, pp. 76-85 (Article) Published by Johns Hopkins University Press DOI: https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.2018.0006 For additional information about this article https://muse.jhu.edu/article/683637 Access provided by your local institution (13 Mar 2018 16:12 GMT) PRE created by BK on 11/20/17. The Rise of Kleptocracy POWER AND PLUNDER IN PUTIN’S RUSSIA Miriam Lanskoy and Dylan Myles-Primakoff Miriam Lanskoy is senior director for Russia and Eurasia at the National Endowment for Democracy (NED). She is the author, with Ilyas Akhmadov, of The Chechen Struggle: Independence Won and Lost (2010). Dylan Myles-Primakoff is senior program officer for Russia and Eurasia at the NED. Since Vladimir Putin rose to power in 1999, the quest to restore the might of the Russian state at home and abroad has been a hallmark of his rule. Yet another such hallmark has been rampant looting by the country’s leaders. Thus Russia has figured prominently in recent schol- arly discussions about kleptocracies—regimes distinguished by a will- ingness to prioritize defending their leaders’ mechanisms of personal enrichment over other goals of statecraft. In a kleptocracy, then, cor- ruption plays an outsized role in determining policy. But how have the state-building and great-power ambitions of the new Russian elite coex- isted with its scramble for self-enrichment? Putin’s Russia offers a vivid illustration of how kleptocratic plunder can become not only an end in itself, but also a tool for both consolidating domestic political control and projecting power abroad.
    [Show full text]
  • Corruption Perceptions Index 2020
    CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX 2020 Transparency International is a global movement with one vision: a world in which government, business, civil society and the daily lives of people are free of corruption. With more than 100 chapters worldwide and an international secretariat in Berlin, we are leading the fight against corruption to turn this vision into reality. #cpi2020 www.transparency.org/cpi Every effort has been made to verify the accuracy of the information contained in this report. All information was believed to be correct as of January 2021. Nevertheless, Transparency International cannot accept responsibility for the consequences of its use for other purposes or in other contexts. ISBN: 978-3-96076-157-0 2021 Transparency International. Except where otherwise noted, this work is licensed under CC BY-ND 4.0 DE. Quotation permitted. Please contact Transparency International – [email protected] – regarding derivatives requests. CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX 2020 2-3 12-13 20-21 Map and results Americas Sub-Saharan Africa Peru Malawi 4-5 Honduras Zambia Executive summary Recommendations 14-15 22-23 Asia Pacific Western Europe and TABLE OF CONTENTS TABLE European Union 6-7 Vanuatu Myanmar Malta Global highlights Poland 8-10 16-17 Eastern Europe & 24 COVID-19 and Central Asia Methodology corruption Serbia Health expenditure Belarus Democratic backsliding 25 Endnotes 11 18-19 Middle East & North Regional highlights Africa Lebanon Morocco TRANSPARENCY INTERNATIONAL 180 COUNTRIES. 180 SCORES. HOW DOES YOUR COUNTRY MEASURE UP?
    [Show full text]
  • UC Berkeley Electronic Theses and Dissertations
    UC Berkeley UC Berkeley Electronic Theses and Dissertations Title The Logic of Kleptocracy: Corruption, Repression, and Political Opposition in Post-Soviet Eurasia Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/92g1h187 Author LaPorte, Jody Marie Publication Date 2012 Peer reviewed|Thesis/dissertation eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California The Logic of Kleptocracy: Corruption, Repression, and Political Opposition in Post-Soviet Eurasia By Jody Marie LaPorte A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Political Science in the Graduate Division of the University of California, Berkeley Committee in charge: Professor Jason Wittenberg, Co-chair Professor Michael S. Fish, Co-chair Professor David Collier Professor Victoria Bonnell Spring 2012 The Logic of Kleptocracy: Corruption, Repression, and Political Opposition in Post-Soviet Eurasia Copyright 2012 by Jody Marie LaPorte Abstract The Logic of Kleptocracy: Corruption, Repression, and Political Opposition in Post-Soviet Eurasia by Jody Marie LaPorte Doctor of Philosophy in Political Science University of California, Berkeley Professor Jason Wittenberg, co-chair Professor Michael S. Fish, co-chair This dissertation asks why some non-democratic regimes give political opponents significant leeway to organize, while others enforce strict limits on such activities. I examine this question with reference to two in-depth case studies from post-Soviet Eurasia: Georgia under President Eduard Shevardnadze and Kazakhstan under President Nursultan Nazarbayev. While a non- democratic regime was in place in both countries, opposition was highly tolerated in Georgia, but not allowed in Kazakhstan. I argue that these divergent policies can be traced to variation in the predominant source and pattern of state corruption in each country.
    [Show full text]
  • Turning the Tide on Dirty Money Why the World’S Democracies Need a Global Kleptocracy Initiative
    GETTY IMAGES Turning the Tide on Dirty Money Why the World’s Democracies Need a Global Kleptocracy Initiative By Trevor Sutton and Ben Judah February 2021 WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG Contents 1 Preface 3 Introduction and summary 6 How dirty money went global and why efforts to stop it have failed 10 Why illicit finance and kleptocracy are a threat to global democracy and should be a foreign policy priority 13 The case for optimism: Why democracies have a structural advantage against kleptocracy 18 How to harden democratic defenses against kleptocracy: Key principles and areas for improvement 21 Recommendations 28 Conclusion 29 Corruption and kleptocracy: Key definitions and concepts 31 About the authors and acknowledgments 32 Endnotes Preface Transparency and honest government are the lifeblood of democracy. Trust in democratic institutions depends on the integrity of public servants, who are expected to put the common good before their own interests and faithfully observe the law. When officials violate that duty, democracy is at risk. No country is immune to corruption. As representatives of three important democratic societies—the United States, the European Union, and the United Kingdom—we recognize that corruption is an affront to our shared values, one that threatens the resiliency and cohesion of democratic governments around the globe and undermines the relationship between the state and its citizens. For that reason, we welcome the central recommendation of this report that the world’s democracies should work together to increase transparency in the global economy and limit the pernicious influence of corruption, kleptocracy, and illicit finance on democratic institutions.
    [Show full text]
  • Loyalist Monitoring, and the Sorcery Masonic Lodge∗
    Chapter 4 of Inside Autocracy Expanding the Governing Coalition: \Unite and Rule", Loyalist Monitoring, and the Sorcery Masonic Lodge∗ Brett L. Cartery November 4, 2012 Abstract Scholars have long believed autocrats \divide and rule" their elite; divided elites, the argu- ment goes, are unable to conspire against the autocrat. Yet historical evidence suggests some autocrats do precisely the opposite. This chapter's theoretical model argues an autocrat may create a compulsory elite social club if his inner circle is sufficiently large. Frequent interaction between the inner circle and less trustworthy elite enables the loyalists to learn about { and thus prevent { nascent conspiracies. By reducing the probability of coups d'´etat from less trustwor- thy elites, \unite and rule" monitoring enable the autocrat to expand his governing coalition. Sassou Nguesso's compulsory elite social club takes the form of a Freemasonry lodge, created just before he seized power in 1997. After providing statistical evidence that high level appoint- ment is the best predictor of lodge membership, the chapter employs a matching estimator to establish that lodge membership causes elites to engage in less anti-regime behavior. ∗This research was made possible by grants from the National Science Foundation, United States Institute of Peace, Social Science Research Council, Smith Richardson Foundation, Weatherhead Center for International Affairs, and Institute for Quantitative Social Science. Thanks to Robert Bates, John Clark, Wonbin Kang, Steve Levitsky, James Robinson, and Yuri Zhukov for helpful comments and encouragement, as well as seminar participants at Harvard University and University of Wisconsin-Madison. My greatest debts are to several Congolese friends, who made this research possible and must remain anonymous.
    [Show full text]
  • Venezuela: Background and U.S
    Venezuela: Background and U.S. Relations Updated January 21, 2019 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R44841 {222A0E69-13A2-4985-84AE-73CC3D FF4D02}- R-065134085251065165027250227152136081055238021128081004254222131230149124116165025173059138019212092197094082070147241055138103109125167218148070191159004086199008187015230011144177144130039148251243207037022138160186199154124002209111056023137069245037120015094018080157060102122054208115 Venezuela: Background and U.S. Relations Summary Venezuela remains in a deep political crisis under the authoritarian rule of President Nicolás Maduro of the United Socialist Party of Venezuela (PSUV). Maduro, narrowly elected in 2013 after the death of Hugo Chávez (1999-2013), is unpopular. Nevertheless, he has used the courts, security forces, and electoral council to repress the opposition. On January 10, 2019, Maduro began a second term after winning reelection on May 20, 2018, in an unfair contest deemed illegitimate by the opposition-controlled National Assembly and most of the international community. The United States, the European Union, the Group of Seven, and most Western Hemisphere countries do not recognize the legitimacy of his mandate. They view the National Assembly as Venezuela’s only democratic institution. Maduro’s inauguration capped his efforts to consolidate power. In 2017, protesters called for Maduro to release political prisoners and respect the opposition-led National Assembly. Security forces quashed protests, with more than 130 killed and thousands
    [Show full text]
  • Sudan's Deep State
    Violent Kleptocracy Series: East and Central Africa Sudan’s Deep State How Insiders Violently Privatized Sudan’s Wealth, and How to Respond By The Enough Project April 2017 REUTERS / Alamy Stock Photo Sudan’s Deep State Violent Kleptocracy Series: East & Central Africa Executive Summary Sudan’s government is a violent kleptocracy, a system of misrule characterized by state capture and co-opted institutions, where a small ruling group maintains power indefinitely through various forms of corruption and violence. Throughout his reign, President Omar al-Bashir has overseen the entrenchment of systemic looting, widespread impunity, political repression, and state violence so that he and his inner circle can maintain absolute authority and continue looting the state. The result of this process, on the one hand, has been the amassment of fortunes for the president and a number of elites, enablers, and facilitators, and on the other hand crushing poverty and underdevelopment for most Sudanese people.* A Failed State? For nearly three decades, President al-Bashir has maintained his position at the pinnacle of Sudan’s political order after seizing power through a military coup in 1989. During his rule, the government of Sudan has perhaps been best known for providing safe haven to Osama bin Laden and other Islamic militants in the 1990s, for committing genocide1 and mass atrocities against its citizens in Darfur, for the secession of South Sudan in 2011, and for ongoing armed conflict—marked by the regime’s aerial bombardment of civilian targets and humanitarian aid blockade—in South Kordofan and Blue Nile. Often portrayed as a country wracked by intractable violence and hampered by racial, religious, ethnic and social cleavages, Sudan ranks consistently among the most fragile or failed states.2 At the same time, Sudan has considerable natural resource wealth and significant economic potential.
    [Show full text]
  • Kitona Operations: Rwanda's Gamble to Capture Kinshasa and The
    Courtesy of Author Courtesy of Author of Courtesy Rwandan Patriotic Army soldiers during 1998 Congo war and insurgency Rwandan Patriotic Army soldiers guard refugees streaming toward collection point near Rwerere during Rwanda insurgency, 1998 The Kitona Operation RWANDA’S GAMBLE TO CAPTURE KINSHASA AND THE MIsrEADING OF An “ALLY” By JAMES STEJSKAL One who is not acquainted with the designs of his neighbors should not enter into alliances with them. —SUN TZU James Stejskal is a Consultant on International Political and Security Affairs and a Military Historian. He was present at the U.S. Embassy in Kigali, Rwanda, from 1997 to 2000, and witnessed the events of the Second Congo War. He is a retired Foreign Service Officer (Political Officer) and retired from the U.S. Army as a Special Forces Warrant Officer in 1996. He is currently working as a Consulting Historian for the Namib Battlefield Heritage Project. ndupress.ndu.edu issue 68, 1 st quarter 2013 / JFQ 99 RECALL | The Kitona Operation n early August 1998, a white Boeing remain hurdles that must be confronted by Uganda, DRC in 1998 remained a safe haven 727 commercial airliner touched down U.S. planners and decisionmakers when for rebels who represented a threat to their unannounced and without warning considering military operations in today’s respective nations. Angola had shared this at the Kitona military airbase in Africa. Rwanda’s foray into DRC in 1998 also concern in 1996, and its dominant security I illustrates the consequences of a failure to imperative remained an ongoing civil war the southwestern Bas Congo region of the Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC).
    [Show full text]