Asymmetry in the Ems; Intentional Or Systemic ?"

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Asymmetry in the Ems; Intentional Or Systemic ? "ASYMMETRY IN THE EMS; INTENTIONAL OR SYSTEMIC ?" by Charles WYPLOSZ N° 88 / 41 Charles Wyplosz, Professor of Economics, INSEAD, Fontainebleau Director of Publication : Charles WYPLOSZ, Associate Dean for Research and Development Printed at INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France ASYHHETRY IN THE EMS: INTENTIONAL OR SYSTEMIC ? Charles Wyplosz INSEAD, Fontainebleau, Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, and CEPR August 1988 ABSTRACT: Why has Germany emerged as the center country in the EMS? Most explanations consider that this is an outcome desired by all (or most) member countries. This paper offers an alternative view. Given a policy conflict the higher inflation countries face stronger pressure from the EMS than the lower inflation ones. Thus asymmetry may be systemic, an implication of fixed exchange rates. Paper presented at the Third Congress of the European Economic Association in Bologna. I have benefited from useful discussions with Jacques Melitz, Francesco Giavazzi, and Vittorio Grilli. - 1 - I - INTRODUCTION Germany has apparently become the de-facto center country of the European Monetary System (EMS). 1 This asymmetry is quite surprising given that the EMS was apparently designed to deliver full symmetry. Other previous experiences with fixed exchange rate systems seem to have also resulted in the emergence of a center country. The existence of such hegemonic tendencies, as reported by Eichengreen (1987), is usually explained by the size of the center country, either measured by its GNP - as the US under the Bretton-Woods system - or by the relative development of its financial markets - as the UK under the Gold Exchange Standard. In the case of the EMS, the size argument is a priori unlikely to be a good explanation, since other countries such as France or 2 Italy are not significantly smaller than Germany. The purpose of this paper is to consider other possible sources of asymmetry. The current literature mostly views the asymmetry as desired by the EMS member countries. Yet, it might be that the asymmetry is systemic, merely the inevitable outcome of a fixed exchange rates regime. The reasons why this might occur are presented in Section 3. The existence of a fundamental asymmetry, if demonstrated, would be of importance. It could lead to a reassessment of the costs and benefits from EMS membership and possibly suggest possible reforms. More generally, it would have implications for any potential reconstruction of the international monetary system. 1. For a detailed exposition of this view, see Giavazzi and Giovanini (1988). Evidence based on interventions data is produced by Mastropasqua et.al. (1987). 2. It has been noted that Germanys exports are significantly larger than those from any other EMS country. This is not, however, a powerful argument given that trade related exchange rate transactions represent a very small fraction of exchange market activity. Any explanation must concern chiefly financial transactions, and we return to the size argument in this context. -2- 2 - ASYMHETRY BY INTENT 2.1. Credibility The literature on credibility (see Persson (1988)) has shown how monetary policy may lead to inefficient outcomes because the authorities incentive to create inflation surprises is understood by the public. It is rational for the public to push prices up to the threshold point where the central bank sees further price increases as too costly to warrant a (temporary) expansionary effect. The key here is Rogoffs (1985) observation that the inefficiency is reduced if the central bank is known to be more adverse to inflation than the public at large, because the inflationary threshold is lowered, and credibly so. When applied to the EMS, this argument implies that the Bundesbank plays the role of the conservative central banker. EMS membership amounts to borrowing the Bundesbanks credibility. This interpretation, while intuitively appealing, is not entirely convincing for at least three reasons. First, devaluations become the signal that a country does not strictly adhere to the Bundesbanks stance. However, to act as a deterrent devaluations must be costly. One solution is to assume such costs: the public sees devaluations as a failure of the government (Melitz (1988)); but as any exchange rate change implies income and wealth transfers, revaluations are equally disliked in Germany. It is not clear, therefore, that assuming asymmetric costs brings much insight. An alternative is to make devaluations costly by preventing a return to a competitive level (Giavazzi and Pagano (1988)). This threat is both implausible and unrealistic. It is implausible because, if carried out, it would mean continuous and permanent losses of competitiveness so that the system is dynamically unstable. It is unrealistic because such has not been the case with the EMS (with the exception of Italy between 1982 and 1983). Second, we may imagine that all EMS inflation rates converge to the point where realignments are ruled out. The resulting credible disciplinary effect must however be weighed against a serious signal extraction effect. While the no-realignment rule may be optimal in face of domestic demand disturbances, a devaluation may be the best response to adverse supply shocks. If the public cannot distinguish among disturbances, the authorities face the choice between a loss of credibility and an inferior policy response. Finally, it is relatively easy to design institutions which - 3 deliver domestic conservative central bankers (strong independence, rewards, surveillance, disindexation, etc...). Why then adopt a foreign one? 2.2. Disinflation Another possible interpretation is that the EMS experience so far has been one of a successful joint disinflation. In such a disinflationary context, there exist conditions under which an EMS, centered around the lowest inflation country, Pareto dominates the Nash outcome under free float (Begg and Wyplosz (1987)). This possibility calls for two brief comments. First, it implies that Germanys leadership need not be sustained in a context where priorities shift away from inflation. Second, game theoretic results appear to be very sensitive to model specifications and the assumptions made about inter-country spillover effects: welfare implications of ambiguous policy linkages are far from convincing. 2.3. Portfolio preferences Asymmetric portfolio preferences may translate a dollar weakness into a DM strength, leaving most other currencies in an intermediate position, therefore weak relatively to the DM. Such an asymmetry, however, which looks systemic, cannot be simply assumed, it must be explained. (It has been shown to violate the traditional theory of portfolio optimization, see Frankel (1986)). Portfolio asymmetry may be a consequence of exchange controls in devaluation- prone countries, whose currencies become poor substitutes to the dollar. If, as argued in section 3, exchange controls are a systemic implication of the EMS, we still need to work out the corresponding portfolio theory. A more readily acceptable view (see e.g. Cohen et al. (1988)) is that the portfolio asymmetry reflects markets expectations about policy responses. This view then boils down to the credibility argument of the previous section. 3 - A SYSTEMIC ASYMMETRY ? It has long been believed (see, e.g. Nurkse (1945)) that a fixed exchange rate regime exerts more pressure on high than on low inflation countries because - 4 - the former see their exchange reserves fall. The long run inflation rate, while a policy choice, is constrained by a number of country characteristics such as the tax system, the degree of social consensus, specific markets structures, etc... Assuming that such constraints are exogenous and lead different countries to different steady state inflation rates, I sketch two arguments which suggest that this situation leads to a fundamental asymmetry. 3.1. Framework: a fixed exchange rate model The discussion is organized around a simple fixed exchange rate model adapted from Obstfeld (1988). Except for interest rates, all variables are expressed as deviations of their logs from the initial equilibrium (x . log X - log X0). The money base market equilibrium is (with obvious notations): (1) m - p ay - i/b In the absence of exchange controls, interest parity prevails: (2) i i + è, where é de/dt. Demand for the domestic good is: (3) d - a (i-p) + e (e+p-p) + g where dp/dt and p is the log of the foreign price level. The first part in (3) is interpreted as real absorption, the second part as the current 3 account and the last term g is a fiscal policy shift parameter. For simplicity it is assumed that y, i and p are constant (no inflation in the EMS partner country) and therefore y = p i O. The domestic good price is sticky and evolves as: (4) p = Y (d-Y) 3. Using upper-case letters for the level of variables (e.g. x log X), D = A + CA . A(1+CA/A) so that d a + log (1+CA/A) = a + CA/A. - 5 - where q is the shadow price which would be observed under PPP: (5) q e + p If the exchange rate is credibly fixed, è.0 and (1) to (5) reduce to: (6) (1-ay)f -erre + yg The money base is endogenously determined via (1) so that the only available instrument is fiscal policy. 3.2. Crises and Exchange Controls The model is first used to illustrate speculative crises in a fixed but adjustable exchange rate system. The literature on balance of payments crises has shown how an anticipated devaluation must eventually lead to a temporary period of floating. Thus pure realignments (i.e. without a temporary float) are impossible unless devaluing countries use exchange controls. To see this, we consider the balance sheet of the central bank: (7) m log M log (E0R + D) where R and D are, respectively, foreign currency holdings and domestic credit, E 0 being the reference exchange rate used for valuation of exchange 4 reserves. The evolution of R is governed by the balance of payments identity linking the current account (CA) and the capital account (KA): • E R CA + KA (8) o With no trend growth and perfect substitutability (see (2)), capital movements need not Lake place except when a realignment is imminent: as é goes to 4.
Recommended publications
  • Personal Information Education Professional Positions Other Affi
    CURRICULUM VITAE: PHILIP RICHARD LANE, April 2015 Address: Economics Department, Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Tel.: 353-1-8962259 Email: plane at tcd.ie Home Page: http://www.philiplane.org Personal Information Date of Birth: 27th August 1969 Citizenship: Ireland Education PhD, Economics, Harvard University, 1995. Thesis Title: “Essays in International Macroeco- nomics.” A.M., Economics, Harvard University, 1993. B.A. (Mod.) (Econ.), First Class Honours and Gold Medal, Trinity College Dublin, 1991. Professional Positions Whately Professor of Political Economy, Trinity College Dublin, 2012- Professor of International Macroeconomics, Trinity College Dublin, 2004-2012 Director, Institute for International Integration Studies (IIIS), Trinity College Dublin, 2002-2008 Associate Professor of Economics, Trinity College Dublin, 2000-2004 Lecturer in Economics, Trinity College Dublin, 1997-2000 Assistant Professor of Economics and International A¤airs , Columbia University, 1995-1997 Other A¢ liations Research Fellow, Centre for Economic Policy Research, 2002-. (Research A¢ liate, 1997- 2001). International Research Fellow, Kiel Institute of World Economics, 2005-. Member, Royal Irish Academy, 2007-. Selected Honours, Awards and Grants Irish Research Council Research Project Grant, “External Imbalances and External Adjustment: Lessons from the European Crisis,”2013-2016. Institute for New Economic Thinking Grant, “Financial Globalisation and Macroeco- nomic Policy,”2012-2015. Bhagwati Prize 2010 (best paper in Journal of International Economics; joint with Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti). Fondation Banque de France Grant, “International Leverage,”2009-2010. NoeG Lecture, Austrian Economics Association, Vienna, May 2008. 1 Keynote Speaker, European Economics and Finance Society, Prague, May 2008. Scienti…c Leader, NORFACE Seminar Series Grant “Economic Globalisation and Eu- rope”, 2007-2009.
    [Show full text]
  • SIMULATING an OIL SHOCK with STICKY PRICES by Francesco Giavalli Mehmet ODEKON and Charles WYPLOSZ N° 81/26
    SIMULATING AN OIL SHOCK WITH STICKY PRICES by Francesco GIAVAllI Mehmet ODEKON and Charles WYPLOSZ N° 81/26 Directeur de la Publication : Jean-Claude THOENIG Associate Dean: Research and Development INSEAD Imprimé par l'INSEP), Fontainebleau France SIMULATING AN OIL SHOCK WITH STICKY PRICES Francesco Giavazzi University of Essex and Università di Venezia Mehmet Odekon INSEAD, France Charles Wyplosz INSEAD, France Revised Version: November 1981 Abstract: This paper extends recent work by J. Sachs about the response of a two country plus OPEC neo-classical model to an oil shock with full inter-temporal optimization and perfect foresight. Here, the role of imperfectly flexible prices is studied under the assumption that firms are output constrained. The presence of expected inflation is shown to be pervasive. It affects the real interest rate term structure and therefore the valuation of all components of wealth, as well as the exchange rate and the attending distribution of world expenditures. Inflation also enters the wage adjustment mechanism and therefore the path of unemployment and capital accumulation. Address: Charles Wyplosz, INSEAD, Boulevard de Constance, 77305 Fontainebleau, France I - INTRODUCTION As recently pointed out by Krugman (1980), the proper study of the effects of an oil shock on the exchange rate requires two essentiel fea- tures. First, because the exchange rates which are interesting are those linking the non-OPEC countries, the minimal set up consists of a model including two such countries and OPEC. The exchange rate then reflects how differently the two countries react to the shock. Second, there are two aspects in which the countries reactions may differ: trade and finance.
    [Show full text]
  • CURRICULUM VITAE Career
    17 January 2019 CURRICULUM VITAE Name: Charles Richard Bean Birth Date: 16 September 1953 Nationality: British Career 1965-71 Brentwood School, Brentwood, Essex. 1972-75 Emmanuel College, Cambridge University. BA, 1975 (First in Economics and Mathematics; MT Dodds prize). MA, 1979. 1975-79 HM Treasury Economic Assistant, Short-Term Forecasting Division. 1979-81 Massachusetts Institute of Technology. PhD, 1981 (Essays in Unemployment & Economic Activity); Harkness Fellow. 1981-82 HM Treasury Economic Adviser, Monetary Policy Division. 1982-2000 London School of Economics Department of Economics: Lecturer (1982-86); Reader (1986-90); Professor (1990-2000); Chair of Department (1999-2000). Centre for Economic Performance: Deputy Director (1990-94). Academic Planning and Resources Committee (1995-98). 1990 Stanford University, Visiting Professor. 1999 Reserve Bank of Australia, Visiting Professor. 2000-14 Bank of England Executive Director for Monetary Analysis & Statistics (2000-08); Deputy Governor for Monetary Policy (2008-14). Monetary Policy Committee (2000-14, Vice-Chair, 2008-14); Financial Policy Committee (2011-14) G7 Deputies (2008-14; Co-Chair, 2013); G20 Deputies (2008-14; Co-Chair, 2009); OECD Working Party 3 (2002-14; Chair, 2010-12). 2014- London School of Economics Professor of Economics (part-time). 2017- Office for Budget Responsibility Member, Budget Responsibility Committee (part-time) Honours President, Royal Economic Society (2013-15) Knight Bachelor (Queen’s Birthday Honours, 2014) Journal Responsibilities Assistant Editor, Economic Policy (1985-86). Editor, special issue of Economica on Unemployment (1986). Managing Editor, Review of Economic Studies (1986-90). Assistant Editor, Economic Journal (1996-2000) Editorial Boards: Review of Economic Studies (1984-96, Chairman 1992-96); Moneda e Credito (1987-97); Journal of Applied Econometrics (1991-2003); Economica (1996-2000); World Economics (1999-2000); International Journal of Central Banking (2004-10, Chairman).
    [Show full text]
  • By Michael C. Burda* Assistant Professor of Economics
    "THE CONSEQUENCES OF GERMAN ECONOMYC AND MONETARY UNSON" by Michael C. Burda N° 90/53/EP Assistant Professor of Economics, INSEAD, Boulevard de Constance Fontainebleau 77305 Cedex, France Printed at INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France Preliminary The Consequences of German Economic and Monetary Union Michael C. Burda INSEAD, OFCE (Paris) and the Centre for Economic Policy Research June 1990 Abstract This paper analyzes some of the consequences of the pending economic and monetary union of the two Germanies. Particular emphasis is given to the real implications for the supply side of the German Democratic Republic and for resource flows between the two economic regions. Presented at the Kieler Woche Conference, 19-22 June 1990. This paper is a working paper for a forthcoming special issue of the Revue de lOFCE on Eastern Europe. I am grateful to B. Gorzig and R. Filip-Kohn of the Deutsches Institut filr Wirtschaftsforschung, U.Ludwig of the Akademie der Wissenschaf ten der DDR, and especially 0. Passet of the OFCE for discussions and data. The recent turn of events in Eastern Europe has provided economists with a laboratory experiment never imagined possible: the introduction of a market economy where none had previously existed. All the more extraordinary is the "experiment" posed by the economic monetary and social union (GEMU) between the Federal Republic of Germany (FRG) and the German Democratic Republic (GDR), by which the latter will drop its centrally planned economy and take the plunge into a free market system. In this peculiar setting, differences in tastes, language, and institutions will be largely marginalized, leaving only the market to answer the question: Can Ludwig Erhards postwar Wirtschaftswunder be repeated in a country that has not known capitalism for almost a half-century? This paper analyzes the German Economic and Monetary Union ( GEMU) and its implications for both Germanies from several perspectives.
    [Show full text]
  • Covid Economics 50, 25 September 2020: 1-2 50, 25 September Covid Economics 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0
    COVID ECONOMICS VETTED AND REAL-TIME PAPERS EDITOR’S FOREWORD ISSUE 50 Charles Wyplosz 25 SEPTEMBER 2020 CORONA POLITICS Helios Herrera, Maximilian Konradt, Guillermo Ordoñez and Christoph Trebesch BOND MARKETS Andrea Zaghini US HOUSING MARKET INCOME AND MORTALITY Yunhui Zhao André Decoster, Thomas Minten and Johannes Spinnewijn VOTER TURNOUT 1 INTEGRATING HEALTH AND Tania Fernández-Navia, Eduardo Polo-Muro ECONOMICS and David Tercero-Lucas Alik Sokolov, Yichao Chen, VOTER TURNOUT 2 Jonathan Mostovoy, Andrew Roberts, Miguel Vázquez-Carrero, Joaquín Artés, Luis Seco and V. Kumar Murty Carmen García and Juan Luis Jiménez Covid Economics Vetted and Real-Time Papers Covid Economics, Vetted and Real-Time Papers, from CEPR, brings together formal investigations on the economic issues emanating from the Covid outbreak, based on explicit theory and/or empirical evidence, to improve the knowledge base. Founder: Beatrice Weder di Mauro, President of CEPR Editor: Charles Wyplosz, Graduate Institute Geneva and CEPR Contact: Submissions should be made at https://portal.cepr.org/call-papers- covid-economics. Other queries should be sent to [email protected]. Copyright for the papers appearing in this issue of Covid Economics: Vetted and Real-Time Papers is held by the individual authors. The Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) The Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) is a network of over 1,500 research economists based mostly in European universities. The Centre’s goal is twofold: to promote world-class research, and to get the policy-relevant results into the hands of key decision-makers. CEPR’s guiding principle is ‘Research excellence with policy relevance’. A registered charity since it was founded in 1983, CEPR is independent of all public and private interest groups.
    [Show full text]
  • Publications and Papers
    Publications and Papers ITO Takatoshi, Faculty Fellow, RIETI (1a) Books Economic Analysis of Disequilibrium: Theory and Empirical Analysis [written in Japanese, original title, "Fukinko no Keizai Bunseki"], Toyo Keizai Shimposha: Tokyo, August 1985, viii + 278 pages, [awarded the 29th Nikkei Economics Book Award, November 1986] The Japanese Economy MIT Press, January 1992. 455 pages. Economics of Consumer-Oriented Policy in Japan [written in Japanese, original title, "Shohisha Jushi no Keizaigaku"] Nihon Keizai Shinbunsha: Tokyo, July 1992. A Vision for the World Economy (with Robert Z. Lawrence and Albert Bressand), xii+124 pages, Washington DC: Brookings Institution, 1996. The Political Economy of Japanese Monetary Policy (with Thomas F. Cargill and Michael M. Hutchison), 236 pages, MIT Press, 1997. An Independent and Accountable IMF (with Jose De Gregorio, Barry Eichengreen, and Charles Wyplosz), Geneva Report on the World Economy No. 1, September 1999, Geneva: International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies. Financial policy and Central Banking in Japan (with Thomas F. Cargill and Michael M. Hutchison), MIT Press, 273 pages, January 2001. No More Bashing: Building a New Japan-United States Economic Relationship (with Fred Bergsten and Marcus Noland), Institute for International Economics, October 2001. Inflation Targeting [written in Japanese], Nihon Keizai Shinbunsha, November 2001 Inflation Targeting in Asia (Authors: Takatoshi Ito and Tomoko Hayashi), Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research, Occasional Paper, No. 1, March 2004, 62pages (1b) Edited Volumes Political Economy of Tax Reform NBER-East Asia Seminar on Economics, volume 1. (co-edited by Anne O. Krueger), Chicago University Press, x+348 pages, 1992. Trade and Protectionism NBER-East Asia Seminar on Economics, volume 2.
    [Show full text]
  • Biographies of Contributors 199
    Biographies of Contributors 199 Biographies of Contributors Don Brash Don Brash was born in New Zealand in 1940. He attended Canterbury University in Christchurch, completing a Bachelor of Arts Degree with a double major in economics and history. In 1962 he obtained his Master of Arts degree with first class honours, majoring in economics. In 1966, Dr Brash obtained a PhD in economics from the Australian National University, with a thesis on American investment in Australian industry. After a career serving with the World Bank in Washington, in the New Zealand banking sector, in the New Zealand Kiwi fruit industry, and as a public policy advisor, Dr Brash became Governor of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand in 1988. Andrew Coleman Andrew Coleman, Assistant Professor of Economics at the University of Michigan, received his PhD from Princeton University in 1998, and joined the faculty in 2000. His primary research interests concern the role of transport and storage costs in determining the spatial patterns of commodity prices and the location of producers, with an emphasis on the effect of transport and storage systems on the evolution of the US economy in the nineteenth century. He teaches development and international finance. Prior to Michigan he worked at the New Zealand Treasury from 1996-99, where as part of his work he investigated the case for a monetary union between Australia and New Zealand. Gordon de Brouwer Gordon de Brouwer is Professor of Economics at the Australian National University. His interests include the economies of Australia, Japan and East Asia, open economy macroeconomics and policy, monetary and financial economics, and international relations.
    [Show full text]
  • Causes and Consequences of Persistently Low Interest Rates
    Low for Long? Causes and Consequences of Persistently Low Interest Rates Geneva Reports on the World Economy 17 International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies (ICMB) International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies 2, Chemin Eugène-Rigot 1202 Geneva Switzerland Tel: (41 22) 734 9548 Fax: (41 22) 733 3853 Web: www.icmb.ch © October 2015 International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies Centre for Economic Policy Research Centre for Economic Policy Research 3rd Floor 77 Bastwick Street London EC1V 3PZ UK Tel: +44 (20) 7183 8801 Fax: +44 (20) 7183 8820 Email: [email protected] Web: www.cepr.org ISBN: 978-1-907142-94-9 Low for Long? Causes and Consequences of Persistently Low Interest Rates Geneva Reports on the World Economy 17 Charles Bean London School of Economics and CEPR Christian Broda Duquesne Capital Management Takatoshi Ito University of Tokyo, University of Columbia and CEPR Randall Kroszner Booth School of Business, University of Chicago ICMB INTERNATIONAL CENTER FOR MONETARY AND BANKING STUDIES CIMB CENTRE INTERNATIONAL D’ETUDES MONETAIRES ET BANCAIRES CEPR PRESS The International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies (ICMB) The International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies (ICMB) was created in 1973 as an independent, non-profit foundation. It is associated with Geneva's Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies. Its aim is to foster exchanges of views between the financial sector, central banks and academics on issues of common interest. It is financed through grants from banks, financial institutions and central banks. The Center sponsors international conferences, public lectures, original research and publications. In association with CEPR, the Center has published the Geneva Reports on the World Economy since 1999.
    [Show full text]
  • Reporter NATIONAL BUREAU of ECONOMIC RESEARCH
    NBER Reporter NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Reporter OnLine at: www.nber.org/reporter 2012 Number 1 Program Report IN THIS ISSUE Program Report The Changing Focus of Public Public Economics 1 Economics Research, 1980–2010 Research Summaries Private Health Insurance Markets 7 Transfer of Knowledge across Countries 10 Raj Chetty and Amy Finkelstein* Inflation Forecasting 13 Wealth After Retirement 16 The NBER’s Program on Public Economics (PE) has covered a very wide range of topics since the last program report six years ago. Rather than NBER Profiles 19 attempting to summarize the entire corpus of work that has been done by Conferences 21 this program in the past few years, this report provides a bird’s eye view NBER News 25 of some of the major changes in the field from two perspectives. First, we Program and Working Group Meetings 29 quantify the main trends in public finance research at the NBER over the Bureau Books 35 last thirty years, drawing on statistics from the database of NBER Working Papers. Second, we qualitatively summarize some of the emerging themes of recent research, both in terms of topics and methods. A Statistical Perspective The Public Economics Program began as the Business Taxation and Finance Program, which held its first meeting under the direction of David Bradford in December 1977. It was renamed the Taxation Program in 1980, to reflect the broader research interests of its affiliated researchers. To recog- nize the importance of expenditure as well as tax research, the program was renamed “Public Economics” in 1991, when James Poterba succeeded David Bradford as Program Director.
    [Show full text]
  • Brexit Beckons: Thinking Ahead by Leading Economists of the European Union
    The 23 June 2016 Brexit referendum saw British voters reject membership Brexit Beckons: Thinking ahead by leading economists of the European Union. Now that a decision has been made, it is time to look forward and fnd the best solutions for the UK’s and the EU’s Brexit Beckons: future. This VoxEU eBook regroups the views of more than a dozen leading economists and specialists on a broad range of issues, from various Thinking ahead by perspectives. The topics include globalisation, trade policy, threats to the City, immigration, labour markets, implications for Ireland, the options for Scotland, and the effects on the rest of the EU. Given that the way forward is uncertain and talks may take years, the leading economists aim of this eBook is to provide a frst take on the issues and options facing the UK and the EU. Edited by Richard E. Baldwin Centre for Economic Policy Research 33 Great Sutton Street A VoxEU.org Book London EC1V 0DX CEPR Press Tel: +44 (0)20 7183 8801 Email: [email protected] www.cepr.org CEPR Press Brexit Beckons: Thinking ahead by leading economists CEPR Press Centre for Economic Policy Research 33 Great Sutton Street London, EC1V 0DX UK Tel: +44 (0)20 7183 8801 Email: [email protected] Web: www.cepr.org ISBN: 978-0-9954701-0-1 Copyright © CEPR Press, 2016. Cover image by Jeff Djevdet, reproduced under the Creative Commons license. Brexit Beckons: Thinking ahead by leading economists Edited by Richard E. Baldwin A VoxEU.org eBook Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) The Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) is a network of over 1,000 research economists based mostly in European universities.
    [Show full text]
  • 36. Volkswirtschaftliche Tagung 2008 – 36Th Economics Conference 2008
    Vortragende – Speakers 188 27. Mai 2008 Vortragende – Speakers Karl Aiginger ment). Mr. Beyrer was a member of the Karl Aiginger, born in 1948, has been EU-Expert-Team („EU-Cadett“) of the Director of the Austrian Institute of Department for European Integration- Economic Research (WIFO) since and Trade Policy in the Austrian Fed- March 2005. He is a professor of eco- eral Economic Chamber from 1992 to nomics at the University of Linz and he 1994. Markus Beyrer studied law and held a position of a visiting professor at commercial sciences at the University Stanford University (1982 and 2002); of Vienna and the Vienna University of the Massachusetts Institute of Technol- Economics and Business Administra- ogy (MIT, 1991); and the University of tion; he completed a postgraduate mas- California Los Angeles (UCLA, 1997). ter course for European Law – Euro- He has contributed to the Austrian Ad- Jus– at the Danube University Krems. visory Council for Economic and Social Affairs and the Reform Dialogue of the Josef Christl Austrian Government. He is a lead Josef Christl was born in Mattighofen, manager and contributor to the Euro- Austria, in 1952. He studied business pean Competitiveness Reports since administration at the University of Graz 1998. He is the editor of the Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade (JICT, jointly with André Sapir). Key areas of research include industrial eco- nomics, industrial policy and competi- tiveness. Markus Beyrer Markus Beyrer has been Secretary Gen- eral of the Federation of Austrian In- dustries since August 2004. After his occupation as expert for European and International Affairs in the Department for Environmental Policy in the Aus- trian Federal Economic Chamber and economics at the University of (1996–1999), he became Director of Vienna and the Institute for Advanced the Economic Policy Department of Studies (IHS).
    [Show full text]
  • Politically Acceptable Debt Restructuring in the Eurozone) Plan Presented in This Report Is Designed to Be Safe and to Deal with Moral Hazard
    The Eurozone countries will emerge from the crisis with very high public debts. They Geneva Reports on the World Economy Special Report 3 S3 face the choice between a long drawn out reduction process, likely to last decades, and a one-off debt restructuring. Nobody likes debt restructuring, but the cost of a gradual reduction cannot be dismissed summarily. Debt restructuring, on the other hand, is perceived as dangerous and a source of moral hazard. Yet, debt restructuring can be managed in a safe way and the moral hazard can be mitigated, if not eliminated. The PADRE (Politically Acceptable Debt Restructuring in the Eurozone) plan presented in this report is designed to be safe and to deal with moral hazard. As important as economic effectiveness is political acceptability. There is no appetite in the Eurozone countries for sharing the current debt burden. The proposed plan allows for a deep debt restructuring without any cross-country transfer. PADRE works as follows. An agent buys on the secondary market and at face value a pre-defined sizeable share of existing public bonds, preferably maturing bonds that it rolls over. The agent then swaps the bonds that it has acquired into zero-interest perpetuities. The corresponding debt is effectively wiped out, removing at once the threat of bank runs. In order to finance its purchases of bonds, the agent issues its PADRE own debt. All bondholders are made whole, which eliminates the risk of a bank or financial crisis. Of course, there must be a cost somewhere. It is borne by the agent, which borrows Politically Acceptable Debt at market rate and lends at zero rate over the indefinite future as it rolls its own debt over.
    [Show full text]