Real Property Co-Ownership and Mineral Developments
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Duty of Care for the Bona Fide Prospective Purchaser Exemption from Cercla Liability
BROWNFIELDS REMEDIATED? HOW THE BONA FIDE PROSPECTIVE PURCHASER EXEMPTION FROM CERCLA LIABILITY AND THE WINDFALL LIEN INHIBIT BROWNFIELD REDEVELOPMENT FENTON D. STRICKLAND* INTRODUCTION Communities across the nation suffer from the negative impacts of abandoned, underused, and potentially contaminated properties called “brownfields.”1 The term “brownfield” generally refers to “real property, the expansion, redevelopment, or reuse of which may be complicated by the presence or potential presence of a hazardous substance, pollutant, or contaminant.”2 According to a report prepared for the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) in 2003 by Environmental Management Support, Inc., the number of brownfields in the United States ranges from 450,000 to 1,000,000.3 In the early 1990s, the U.S. Conference of Mayors labeled brownfields “one of the most critical problems facing U.S. [c]ities.”4 The appearance of abandoned properties in metropolitan areas may puzzle the typical uninformed resident. However, property developers, lending institutions, governments, lawyers, environmental agencies, and real estate professionals understand the primary reason for the condition. Developers are “hesitant to redevelop brownfields because of the investment risk and potential liability for cleanup costs.”5 This uncertainty, which causes apprehension for parties who might otherwise be inclined to redevelop brownfields, is a by-product of the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act of 1980 (CERCLA).6 In recognition of the serious impact that the brownfield problem has had, as well as how uncertainty about liability has contributed to the problem, Congress, in 2002, enacted the Small Business Liability Relief and Brownfields Revitalization * J.D. Candidate, 2005, Indiana University School of Law—Indianapolis; B.S., 1994, Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana. -
Doctrines of Waste in a Landscape of Waste
Missouri Law Review Volume 72 Issue 4 Fall 2007 Article 8 Fall 2007 Doctrines of Waste in a Landscape of Waste John A. Lovett Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.missouri.edu/mlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation John A. Lovett, Doctrines of Waste in a Landscape of Waste, 72 MO. L. REV. (2007) Available at: https://scholarship.law.missouri.edu/mlr/vol72/iss4/8 This Conference is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Missouri Law Review by an authorized editor of University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Lovett: Lovett: Doctrines of Waste Doctrines of Waste in a Landscape of Waste John A. Lovett* I. INTRODUCTION One of the virtues of William Stoebuck and Dale Whitman's seminal hornbook, The Law of Property, is its extensive treatment of the subject of waste. ' Using half of a chapter, Stoebuck and Whitman introduce their read- ers to one of the great subjects of the common law of property, one that at- 2 3 4 tracted the attention of Coke, Blackstone, Kent, and many others. Their detailed analysis of the subject, which provides a general historical overview, a discussion of the seminal voluntary waste cases, Melms v. Pabst Brewing Co.,5 and Brokaw v. Fairchild,6 and a presentation of the legal and equitable remedies for waste, may strike some readers as old-fashioned. Although one recent law review article has called attention to several early nineteenth century waste cases, 7 relatively little contemporary academic scholarship has addressed waste doctrine in depth. -
Farm Building Rent Presentation
Building Rent What’s a Fair Value? Ken Bolton UW‐Extension Center For Dairy Profitability Arriving at a Fair Rental Value • For whom? • Landlord? • Renter? • Both? – High/Low approach Arriving at a Fair Rental Value Landlord Renter • High • High – Out –of‐pocket costs, PLUS – Full ownership cost – Annual ownership costs • Low • Rate of return on Investment – Less than • Low (Out Of Pocket) • Taxes – Taxes • Insurance – Insurance • Repairs – Repairs? Arriving at a Fair Rental Value • Full ownership cost – Actual costs for • Taxes‐ (1‐1.5% of building’s market value) • Insurance‐ (0.5‐1.0% “) • Repairs‐ (1.0‐1.5% “) ‐PLUS‐ • Capital Recovery Charge (CRC) – Depreciation (0‐5%) – Interest on investment‐ CD rate Arriving at a Fair Rental Value • What’s a Building Worth? – Market value – Insured value – Assessed value – Appraised value – Replacement cost MINUS depreciation – Contributory value • Farm value‐land value Real Estate Tax Bill Arriving at a Fair Rental Value • “Improvements” – House‐ 4 bedroom, finished basement built 1996 – Shop‐ 40’ X 60’, 4‐ season built 2004 – Pole barn ‐ 40’ X 60’ built 2004 Arriving at a Fair Rental Value • “Fair” market Value • Using The Real Estate Tax Bill – Assessed value of Improvements ‐ value of improvements not to be rented= value building to be rented – $274,700 – ($214,700 house + 50,000 shop) = • $10,000 pole barn – 40’ X 60”= 2400 ft.2 = $4.17/ft.2 Arriving at a Fair Rental Value • Real Estate Tax Bill, continued – $10,000 building value X 2.5% (taxes, insurance, repairs) = • $250 – $10,000 building value X 3% (depreciation) = • $300 – $10,000 building value X 1% (hopeful CD rate) = • $100 – Total ($250 + 300 + 100) = • $650/year/ $54.17/month (add value of technology) • $250 min. -
Long-Term Leases: Rent Reset Analysis
Peer-Reviewed Article Long-Term Leases: Rent Reset Analysis by Tony Sevelka, MAI, SRA, AI-GRS Abstract A provision for resetting rent is often found in long-term leases, with the objective being to periodically analyze the value attributed to the leased real estate. The property rights to be valued at each rent reset depend on the language of the lease, especially the rent reset clause. The lack of specificity associated with use of the term market value has led to questionable application of the term in rent resets. Inconsistent interpretations of a lease can lead to divergent opin- ions of value. Sometimes rent resetting provisions have no connection to the terms of the lease or the actual property rights; this may result in situations where it is difficult to apply conventional appraisal methods. This article summarizes and discusses a sample of rent reset cases and explores creative valuation solutions to rent reset valuation challenges. Introduction rent reset is dictated by the provisions of the lease, and the lease usually calls for arbitration if Rent reset clauses are typically found in long- the landlord and tenant are unable to negotiate a term leases for land (unimproved or improved).1 new rent within a specified time frame. A lease is “a contract in which the rights to use A rent reset analysis for a land lease has the and occupy land, space, or structures are trans- same objective as for a space lease—quantifying ferred by the owner to another for a specified a new rent—unless the land lease only calls for a period of time -
The Law of Property
THE LAW OF PROPERTY SUPPLEMENTAL READINGS Class 14 Professor Robert T. Farley, JD/LLM PROPERTY KEYED TO DUKEMINIER/KRIER/ALEXANDER/SCHILL SIXTH EDITION Calvin Massey Professor of Law, University of California, Hastings College of the Law The Emanuel Lo,w Outlines Series /\SPEN PUBLISHERS 76 Ninth Avenue, New York, NY 10011 http://lawschool.aspenpublishers.com 29 CHAPTER 2 FREEHOLD ESTATES ChapterScope ------------------- This chapter examines the freehold estates - the various ways in which people can own land. Here are the most important points in this chapter. ■ The various freehold estates are contemporary adaptations of medieval ideas about land owner ship. Past notions, even when no longer relevant, persist but ought not do so. ■ Estates are rights to present possession of land. An estate in land is a legal construct, something apart fromthe land itself. Estates are abstract, figments of our legal imagination; land is real and tangible. An estate can, and does, travel from person to person, or change its nature or duration, while the landjust sits there, spinning calmly through space. ■ The fee simple absolute is the most important estate. The feesimple absolute is what we normally think of when we think of ownership. A fee simple absolute is capable of enduringforever though, obviously, no single owner of it will last so long. ■ Other estates endure for a lesser time than forever; they are either capable of expiring sooner or will definitely do so. ■ The life estate is a right to possession forthe life of some living person, usually (but not always) the owner of the life estate. It is sure to expire because none of us lives forever. -
STATE of MAINE EXECUTIVE DEPARTMENT STATE PLANNIJ'\G OFFICE 38 STATE HOUSE STATION AUGUSTA, MAINE 043 3 3-003Fi ANGUS S
MAINE STATE LEGISLATURE The following document is provided by the LAW AND LEGISLATIVE DIGITAL LIBRARY at the Maine State Law and Legislative Reference Library http://legislature.maine.gov/lawlib Reproduced from scanned originals with text recognition applied (searchable text may contain some errors and/or omissions) Great Pond Tasl< Force Final Report KF 5570 March 1999 .Z99 Prepared by Maine State Planning Office I 84 ·State Street Augusta, Maine 04333 Acknowledgments The Great Pond Task Force thanks Hank Tyler and Mark DesMeules for the staffing they provided to the Task Force. Aline Lachance provided secretarial support for the Task Force. The Final Report was written by Hank Tyler. Principal editing was done by Mark DesMeules. Those offering additional editorial and layout assistance/input include: Jenny Ruffing Begin and Liz Brown. Kevin Boyle, Jennifer Schuetz and JefferyS. Kahl of the University of Maine prepared the economic study, Great Ponds Play an Integral Role in Maine's Economy. Frank O'Hara of Planning Decisions prepared the Executive Summary. Larry Harwood, Office of GIS, prepared the maps. In particular, the Great Pond Task Force appreciates the effort made by all who participated in the public comment phase of the project. D.D.Tyler donated the artwork of a Common Loon (Gavia immer). Copyright Diana Dee Tyler, 1984. STATE OF MAINE EXECUTIVE DEPARTMENT STATE PLANNIJ'\G OFFICE 38 STATE HOUSE STATION AUGUSTA, MAINE 043 3 3-003fi ANGUS S. KING, JR. EVAN D. RICHERT, AICP GOVERNOR DIRECTOR March 1999 Dear Land & Water Resources Council: Maine citizens have spoken loud and clear to the Great Pond Task Force about the problems confronting Maine's lakes and ponds. -
1400 Co Ownership and Condominium
1400 CO-OWNERSHIP AND CONDOMINIUM Marshall E. Tracht Associate Professor, Hofstra University School of Law © Copyright 1999 Marshall E. Tracht Abstract Co-ownership refers to legal relations in which two or more entities have equal rights to the use and enjoyment of property. Co-ownership relationships may satisfy the preferences of some owners, and predefined categories of co-ownership, as opposed to contractually defined relations, may allow parties to satisfy these preferences at relatively low cost. However, shared ownership results in coordination and externality problems, which the law attempts to mitigate in numerous ways, including judicial oversight of ‘reasonableness’ (as in the law of waste) or fiduciary duties; ending the co-ownership relation (through the right of partition) or providing rules that seek to optimize the joint decision-making process (such as compulsory unitization). A major area of growth in shared ownership is in condominium developments, where entities own some property individually, while co-owning common facilities. This permits parties to take advantage of economies of scale and the joint provision of common goods. Condominium arrangements are governed by a combination of contract, statute and judicial law, and typically include democratic decision-making structures intended to minimize the sum of decision-making costs (gathering information, voting, and bargaining) and the cost of erroneous decisions. JEL classification: K11, P32, H41 Keywords: Cotenancy, Co-ownership, Condiminium, Cooperative, Communal Ownership 1. Introduction Co-ownership refers to legal relationships that entitle two or more entities to equal rights to the use and enjoyment of property. Although it most often arises in the context of real property, co-ownership may apply to any type of property. -
Property a Law2112
PROPERTY A LAW2112 FIXTURES V CHATTELS Define fixture: Chattels ‘so attached to the land’ it becomes a part of the land.’ Fixtures automatically pass with the conveyance of the land. o S18 Property Law Act (1958): land includes “…corporeal hereditaments...” i.e. fixtures o S38 Interpretation of Legislation Act (1984) – includes buildings and other structures permanently affixed to land. Define chattel: Personal property that can be moved, not affixed to the land. Chattels can become fixtures by a third party if they are the actual rights holder of the property. i.e. furniture, household appliances. Ø Doctrine of Fixtures Test 1. Identify who is arguing fixture, and who is arguing chattel. 2. Role of presumptions: “Whatever is affixed to the soil becomes part of the soil”. – NAB V Blacker (2000) If object is fixed to the land other than by its own weight, presumption it’s a fixture. (Belgrave) If object rests on its own weight, presumption it’s a chattel (Belgrave) i. If attachment, onus of evidence is on person who wants it to be a chattel (NAB) ii. If no attachment, onus is on person who wants it to be a fixture (NAB) 3. Consider: Was there already a contract in place detailing with the nature of the object in question? – If not, apply common law tests (BelgraVe; NAB). a. Degree of annexation test – Extent the chattel has been affixed to the land. i. Mode and structure of annexation: Degree to which it is annexed to the land. For example in Leigh v Taylor – tapestries were fastened to canvas by tracKs. -
1 Property Taxes and Residential Rents Leah J. Tsoodle & Tracy M
Forthcoming. Journal of Real Estate Economics, 2008, 36(1), pp. 63-80. Property Taxes and Residential Rents Leah J. Tsoodle & Tracy M. Turner Abstract. Property taxes are a fundamental source of revenue for local governments, comprising 73% of local government tax revenue in the United States. In this paper, we empirically investigate the impact of residential property taxes on residential rents. Using data from the American Housing Survey and the National League of Cities, we estimate numerous specifications of a hedonic rent equation with comprehensive unit-level, neighborhood-level and city-level controls. We find that a one standard deviation increase in the property tax rate raises residential rents by roughly $400 annually. ______________________ Tsoodle: Coordinator, State of Kansas Land Use-Value Project. Turner: Department of Economics, Kansas State University. We thank Allen Featherstone, John Crespi, Bryan Schurle, Dong Li, and session participants at the American Real Estate and Urban Economics May 2005 conference for valuable feedback. We thank Matt Gardner for a helpful discussion, Jack Goodman for generously calculating some statistics for us, and two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments. We especially thank Editor Coulson for his insights and guidance. Tsoodle gratefully acknowledges funding from the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development Early Doctoral Research Program. 1 I. Introduction Property taxes are a fundamental source of revenue for local governments, comprising 73% of local government tax revenue in the United States (Statistical Abstract, 2006), and an extensive literature examines their economic impacts. By extending and empirically testing the Tiebout (1956) model, much of this research investigates the extent to which property taxes and public services are capitalized into house prices, and whether household mobility and local government competition can lead to an efficient provision of local public services. -
Condominium: a Reconciliation of Competing Interests?
Vanderbilt Law Review Volume 18 Issue 4 Issue 4 - A Symposium on Small Article 7 Business Symposium on Small Business 10-1965 Condominium: A Reconciliation of Competing Interests? James C. Clark Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.vanderbilt.edu/vlr Part of the Property Law and Real Estate Commons, and the Tax Law Commons Recommended Citation James C. Clark, Condominium: A Reconciliation of Competing Interests?, 18 Vanderbilt Law Review 1773 (1965) Available at: https://scholarship.law.vanderbilt.edu/vlr/vol18/iss4/7 This Note is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Vanderbilt Law Review by an authorized editor of Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. NOTES Condominium: A Reconciliation of Competing Interests? I. INMRODUCTION As Americans have migrated to urban areas, the suburbs have grown at an astounding pace, principally by means of single home sub- divisions. Of necessity, this march to the suburbs must cease at some point and people will begin to return to the central city and its close- lying peripheral areas if for no other reason than to lessen the heavy economic burden resulting from man-hours wasted in commuting great distances. Often the alternative to the suburban home is an apartment in the city. Apartment renting, however, runs counter to a deeply ingrained American tradition of individual home ownership, a tradition encouraged by favorable tax consequences.' It seems only 1. The homeowner may deduct state and local, and foreign real property taxes, INT. -
Business Income – Landlord As Additional Insured (Rental Value)
POLICY NUMBER: COMMERCIAL PROPERTY CP 15 03 06 07 THIS ENDORSEMENT CHANGES THE POLICY. PLEASE READ IT CAREFULLY. BUSINESS INCOME – LANDLORD AS ADDITIONAL INSURED (RENTAL VALUE) This endorsement modifies insurance provided under the following: BUSINESS INCOME (AND EXTRA EXPENSE) COVERAGE FORM BUSINESS INCOME (WITHOUT EXTRA EXPENSE) COVERAGE FORM SCHEDULE Description Of Rented Premises: Name Of Additional Insured: Mailing Address Of Additional Insured: Applicable Business Income Causes Of Coverage Form Coinsurance Loss Form (Enter Form Number) Limit Of Insurance Percentage $ % Endorsements, If Any, Supplementing Or Restricting The Covered Causes Of Loss With Respect To The Coverage Provided Under This Endorsement: Information required to complete this Schedule, if not shown above, will be shown in the Declarations. A. The person or entity identified in the Schedule is C. With respect to the coverage provided under this insured for loss of "Rental Value", up to the Limit endorsement, the definition of "Rental Value" is of Insurance shown in the Schedule. Such cover- replaced by the following: age applies in accordance with all terms of Busi- "Rental Value" means the: ness Income – "Rental Value" Coverage under the applicable Business Income Coverage Form, and 1. Net income that would have been earned as all conditions in the Common Policy Conditions rental income from tenant occupancy of the and Commercial Property Conditions, except as premises described in the Schedule, as fur- otherwise provided in this endorsement or other nished and equipped by the Additional Insured; applicable endorsement. and B. The Causes Of Loss Form shown in the Schedule 2. Amount of continuing normal operating ex- applies to the coverage provided under this en- penses which are the legal obligation of the dorsement. -
Landlord/Tenant Law
LANDLORD/TENANT LAW Choices for Eviction When a landlord wants a resident to move out, certain procedures must be followed. This page provides a brief description of the various options available to landlords under Washington law. Each option has a specific legal process which must be followed. For a complete definition of eviction options and serving process, review the latest version of the Residential Landlord-Tenant Act for the State of WashingtonB Revised Code of Washington, Title 59. 1. FOR NOT PAYING RENT. If the resident is even one day behind in rent, the landlord can issue a three-day notice to pay rent or vacate. If the resident pays all the rent due within three days, the landlord must accept it and can not evict the resident. A landlord is not required to accept a partial payment. 2. FOR NOT COMPLYING WITH TERMS OF THE RENTAL AGREEMENT. If a resident is not complying with the rental agreement (for example, keeping a cat when the agreement specifies no pets or unauthorized people are living in the rental), the landlord can give a ten-day notice to comply or vacate. If the resident remedies the situation within that time, the landlord can not continue with the eviction process. 3. FOR CREATING A WASTE, NUISANCE, OR ILLEGAL ACTIVITY. If a resident destroys the landlord’s property, uses the premises for unlawful activity including drug-related activities, damages the value of the property or interferes with other resident’s use of the property, the landlord can issue a three-day notice for waste, nuisance or illegal activity.