Evaluation of Election Outcomes Under Uncertainty

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Evaluation of Election Outcomes Under Uncertainty Evaluation of Election Outcomes under Uncertainty Noam Hazon1, Yonatan Aumann1, Sarit Kraus1, Michael Wooldridge2 1Department of Computer Science 2Department of Computer Science Bar-Ilan University University of Liverpool Israel United Kingdom {hazonn,aumann,sarit}@cs.biu.ac.il [email protected] ABSTRACT a computational perspective, many interesting theoretical We investigate the extent to which it is possible to evaluate questions arise. Perhaps the most natural question from a the probability of a particular candidate winning an elec- computer science perspective is: are the voting protocols to tion, given imperfect information about the preferences of select a winning outcome e±ciently computable, given all the electorate. We assume that for each voter, we have a the agents preferences? Fortunately, it seems that relatively probability distribution over a set of preference orderings. few voting protocols are hard to compute in this sense [4]. Thus, for each voter, we have a number of possible prefer- Perhaps more intriguing are questions related to the com- ence orderings { we do not know which of these orderings plexity of manipulating a voting procedure. It can often be actually represents the voters' preferences, but we know for computationally infeasible for an agent to compute the most each one the probability that it does. We give a polynomial bene¯cial manipulation [3], implying that while manipula- algorithm to solve the problem of computing the probability tion is possible in theory, it is infeasible in practice. The that a given candidate will win when the number of candi- complexity of manipulation was studied in [3, 2, 6] under dates is a constant. However, when the number of candi- the assumption that the number of outcomes is unbounded, dates is not bounded, we prove that the problem becomes while [5, 7] analyzed the complexity of manipulation with #P-Hard for the Plurality, Borda, and Copeland voting pro- a constant number of outcomes. However, most of these tocols. We further show that even evaluating if a candidate results assume perfect information about voter preferences, has any chance to win is NP-Complete for the Plurality vot- which is surely a very unrealistic assumption in real world ing protocol, in the weighted voters case. We give a poly- settings. nomial algorithm for this problem when the voters' weights In this work, we investigate voting systems under an im- are equal. perfect information model. We assume that what is known about an electorate is the following. For each voter, we have a probability distribution over a set of preference orderings. Categories and Subject Descriptors The idea is that although we do not know a voter's prefer- I.2.11 [Arti¯cial Intelligence]: Distributed Arti¯cial In- ence ordering exactly, we know that it is one of a set of possi- telligence|Coherence and coordination, Intelligent agents; ble orderings (typically a subset of the overall set of possible F.2.1 [Analysis of Algorithms and Problem Complex- preference orders), and we have a probability distribution ity]: Numerical Algorithms and Problems; J.4 [Social and over these. This information may be estimated using histor- Behaviorial Sciences]: [Economics] ical data. In this setting, the following fundamental question arises: given such an incomplete information model of voter General Terms preferences and a particular voting system, how hard is it to compute the probability that a particular candidate will Algorithms, Economics, Theory win? To the best of our knowledge, this question is not addressed in the existing literature1. Keywords The motivation for investigating this question is not merely Computational social choice, Voting protocols theoretical interest (which is, of course, by itself a legitimate thing). In many situations, it might be bene¯cial to try to foresee the probability of an outcome being chosen using 1. INTRODUCTION only partial knowledge about the other agents preferences, In many multi-agent systems, it is desirable to have a mech- which is modeled by a probability distribution as we have anism which enables the agents within the system to make described. One area is the avoidance of strategic voting by a collective decision on a given issue. The mechanism by a coalition of manipulators. Suppose that agent A wants to which such a collective decision is made is typically a vot- vote for an outcome which is its most preferred one. An- ing procedure. When considering voting procedures from other manipulator agent, B, could try to convince A that Cite as: Evaluation of Election Outcomes under Uncertainty, Noam Ha- its outcome does not have any chance to be the winner so zon, Yonatan Aumann, Sarit Kraus and Michael Wooldridge, Proc. of 7th he should directly vote for his second preferred outcome; Int. Conf. on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (AAMAS 2008), Padgham, Parkes, Müller and Parsons (eds.), May, 12- 1 16.,2008,Estoril,Portugal,pp.959-966. The exception is the work of [5] but their result holds only Copyright °c 2008, International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and for weighted voters with weights that are not bounded by Multiagent Systems (www.ifaamas.org). All rights reserved. P oly(n) as we will show later. 959 otherwise this outcome will also lose to A's least preferred inators); ­ = f!1;:::;!mg is a non-empty set of outcomes, candidate. Due to lack of exact knowledge how the other or candidates { the things the voters are trying to decide agents will vote, A may be convinced by B. Alternatively, over; and Â= fÂ1;:::; Âng is a non-empty set of preference A can estimate the other agent's probabilities to vote for the relations, Âi⊆ ­ £ ­ is a (strict) preference relation over ­, outcomes, by asking people who know them, or by using the for each i 2 V , which is usually private to i. history of their former votes on the same issue. The ability The preference aggregation problem is that of combining to calculate the probability of an outcome winning should the preference relations Âi to obtain a social preference or- then help A to decide whether B has a valid point. der, and the general problem of social choice theory is to This ability to calculate the probability of an outcome ¯nd some way of aggregating preference relations in such a winning might also be useful in other domains. For example, way that certain principles (such as the Pareto condition) (and somewhat more speculatively), consider large multi- are satis¯ed [1]. Generating the social preference order is agent environments, in which there is a need to keep com- commonly done by a voting system which speci¯es the form munication to a minimum. The voting process inevitably of the ballot, the set of allowable votes, and the voting pro- requires communication between the election o±cer and the tocol (an algorithm for determining the outcome). We are voters in order to elicit their preferences. However, one way concerned with settings in which we simply want to select to reduce the communication load is to calculate the prob- one outcome from ­, and the voting protocol runs in poly- abilities on the agents preferences from their voting history nomial time. and then calculate the probability of each outcome to win: We now review some common voting systems in the case the winning outcome is then the one which gets the high- of un-weighted votes (i.e., the case where wi = 1 for all i). est probability to be the winner. In this way, we simulate The evaluation of a voting protocol for weighted votes is a voting process by choosing the successful outcome with- done by simply replacing the vote of each voter i with wi out the need to use communication at all. (This method identical un-weighted votes. In general, voting systems can might be extended to a more sophisticated protocol which be classi¯ed based on their ballot type. In binary voting uses limited communication by asking only a subset of the systems a voter either votes or does not vote for a given voters about their current preferences, although we do not candidate. In ranked voting systems, each voter ranks the investigate this possibility here.) candidates in order of preference. We represent this ballot We therefore analyze the ability to calculate the probabil- as a vector where the ¯rst candidate is the most preferred ity of an outcome to win in various di®erent settings. We candidate, the second one is the second preferred candidate ¯rst give some background and review some common voting and so on. Condorcet systems (or pairwise systems) are systems in Section 2. We formally de¯ne the above men- a class of ranked voting systems that meet the Condorcet tioned \evaluation" question in De¯nition 1. In Section 3, we criterion. That is, the candidate who, when compared in give a polynomial algorithm to answer the evaluation prob- turn with each of the other candidates, is preferred over the lem if the number of outcomes is a constant number, and we other candidate is always declared to be the winner, if such show that the result of [5] holds only for weighted voting sys- a candidate exists. tems with weights that are not bounded by P oly(n). If the ² Binary voting systems: number of candidates is not bounded, the evaluation prob- lem becomes much harder: we show in Section 4 that even Plurality (aka. ¯rst-past-the-post, relative majority, or for the Plurality, Borda, and Copeland voting protocols the winner-take-all). Each voter votes for one candidate, problem is #P-Hard. We then analyze a simpler question, and the candidate that receives the most votes wins (the CHANCE-EVALUATION problem { De¯nition 8): can (even if it receives less than a majority of votes).
Recommended publications
  • Unit 7 Electoral Systems and Electoral Processes
    Electoral Systems and Electoral UNIT 7 ELECTORAL SYSTEMS AND Processes ELECTORAL PROCESSES Structure 7.0 Objectives 7.1 Introduction 7.2 Classification of electoral systems 7.3 Majoritarian Systems 7.3.1 First-Past-the-Post/ Single-Member Plurality system 7.3.2 Second Ballot System 7.3.3 Alternative Vote (AV)/ Supplementary Vote (SV) system 7.3.4 Condorcet Method 7.4 Proportional Representation Systems 7.4.1 Single-Transferable-Vote (STV) System 7.4.2 Party-List System 7.5 Mixed Methods 7.5.1 Mixed-Member Proportional or Additional Member System 7.5.2 Semi-Proportional Method 7.5.3 Cumulative Vote System 7.5.4 Slate System 7.6 Comparative Assessment of Majoritarian and PR Systems 7.7 Let Us Sum Up 7.8 References 7.9 Answers to Check Your Progress Exercises Dr. Tulika Gaur, Guest Faculty, Non-Collegiate Women's Education Board, University of Delhi, Delhi 97 Representation and Political 7.0 OBJECTIVES Participation An electoral system does not only set rules for election, but also plays crucial role in shaping the party system and political culture of the country. This unit focuses on electoral systems and processes. After going through this unit, you should be able to: Define electoral system, Identify the various dimensions of an electoral system, Assess combinations of electoral methods used by different countries in their national or local elections, Examine the advantages and disadvantages of different kinds of electoral systems, and Analyse the links between parties and electoral process. 7.1 INTRODUCTION The electoral system refers to a set of rules through which people get to choose their representatives or political leaders.
    [Show full text]
  • GUIDELINES to ASSIST NATIONAL MINORITY PARTICIPATION in the ELECTORAL PROCESS Guidelines for Electoral Process.Qxd 03-05-06 11:39 Page 1
    Cover Minority #1 08.09.2003 14:22 Uhr Seite 1 GUIDELINES TO ASSIST NATIONAL MINORITY PARTICIPATION IN THE ELECTORAL PROCESS Guidelines_for_Electoral_Process.qxd 03-05-06 11:39 Page 1 GUIDELINES TO ASSIST NATIONAL MINORITY PARTICIPATION IN THE ELECTORAL PROCESS Guidelines_for_Electoral_Process.qxd 03-05-06 11:39 Page 2 Published by the OSCE Office for Democratic Institutions and Human Rights (ODIHR) Aleje Ujazdowskie 19 00-557 Warsaw Poland www.osce.org/odihr © OSCE/ODIHR 2001 Reprint 2003 All rights reserved. The contents of this publication may be freely used and copied for educational and other non-commercial purposes, provided that any such reproduction be accompanied by an acknowledgement of the OSCE/ODIHR as the source. Guidelines_for_Electoral_Process.qxd 03-05-06 11:39 Page 3 TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. INTRODUCTION . 5 2. BACKGROUND TO THE LUND RECOMMENDATIONS . 7 3. THE IMPORTANCE OF PROCESS . 9 4. INTERNATIONAL LEGAL FRAMEWORK . 11 5. LUND RECOMMENDATION ON ELECTIONS: NO. 7 . 15 5.1 Content Explanation . 15 5.1.1 The individual rights to participate in elections . 16 5.1.2 The prohibition against discrimination . 20 5.2 Legal Framework and Options . 22 6. LUND RECOMMENDATION ON ELECTIONS: NO. 8 . 24 6.1 Content Explanation . 24 6.2 Legislative Framework . 27 7. LUND RECOMMENDATION ON ELECTIONS: NO. 9 . 28 7.1 Content Explanation . 28 7.2 Legislative Framework and Options . 31 7.3 Other Mechanisms . 38 8. LUND RECOMMENDATION ON ELECTIONS: NO. 10 . 40 8.1 Content Explanation . 40 8.1.1 District magnitude . 40 8.1.2 Territorial delimitation . 41 9. ENSURING FAIR CONDUCT OF ELECTIONS: THE ADMINISTRATION OF THE ELECTIONS .
    [Show full text]
  • The Supplementary Vote Electoral System Again Worked Very Well in London
    blo gs.lse.ac.uk http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/politicsandpolicy/archives/23468 The Supplementary Vote electoral system again worked very well in London. There is no basis for arguing that voters don’t understand their choices Blog Admin A recent article on the London mayoral election suggested that the way the public voted showed that a majority of people did not understand the voting system used. Patrick Dunleavy explains why this criticism of the voting system is quite unfounded. Looking back at the mayoral election in London, James Ball writing in the Guardian Comment section outlines some problems as he sees it with the Supplementary Vote system used to elect London’s powerf ul mayor. He writes: The vast majority of voters decided to use their second preference vote: 1.76 million second preferences were cast, around 80% of the electorate. But only around one in 10 of these were actually counted towards the total. Of the 346,000 or so people who voted for one of the minority candidates, only 185,000 actually cast their vote in such a way as to influence the result. More than 1.1 million people cast their second preference for a candidate with no chance of being in the run-off for the final two. There are two ways to interpret the figures: a large portion of Londoners don’t fully understand the voting system, or they are using it in a remarkably sophisticated way to send subtle signals to minority candidates. If this was the case, there does seem to be a problem.
    [Show full text]
  • Voting Systems in the UK
    BRIEFING PAPER Number 04458, 26 October 2017 By Neil Johnston Voting systems in the UK Inside: 1. Current voting systems 2. Electoral systems in the UK – recent developments 3. Previous government reviews of electoral systems 4. International comparisons www.parliament.uk/commons-library | intranet.parliament.uk/commons-library | [email protected] | @commonslibrary Number 04458, 26 October 2017 2 Contents Summary 3 1. Current voting systems 4 1.1 First Past the Post (FPTP) 4 1.2 Alternative Vote (AV) 4 1.3 Supplementary Vote 4 1.4 Single Transferable Vote (STV) 5 1.5 Additional Member System 5 1.6 Closed Party List System 6 1.7 Table showing where the voting systems are used in the UK 7 2. Electoral systems in the UK – recent developments 8 2.1 The AV Referendum 8 2.2 Directly electing members of the National Park authorities in England 9 2.3 Devolution of elections to Wales 10 2.4 2017 manifesto commitments 10 3. Previous government reviews of electoral systems 12 3.1 Report of the Independent Commission on the Voting System [October 1998] 12 3.2 Review of Voting Systems: the experience of new voting systems in the United Kingdom since 1997 [January 2008] 12 4. International comparisons 15 4.1 First Past the Post 15 4.2 Additional Member Systems – Germany and New Zealand 15 4.3 Two Round Systems – France 15 4.4 AV – Australia and Ireland 16 4.5 STV – Ireland 16 4.6 List Systems 16 Cover page image copyrightTo the polling station by Matt. Licensed under CC BY 2.0 / image cropped.
    [Show full text]
  • Faclair Airson Riaghaltas Ionadail Gàidhlig Agus Beurla
    Faclair airson Riaghaltas Ionadail Gàidhlig agus Beurla Dictionary for Local Government Scottish Gaelic and English Air a chur ri chèile le Compiled by The European Language Initiative a bhuineas do mhodh : a thogas meanmna ____________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ a ghabhas leasachadh a nì bacadh br a rinneadh leis a‟ phrìomhaire remediable, obstructionist, prime-ministerial adj retrievable adj obstructive adj gnìomh a rinneadh leis suidheachadh a ghabhas innleachdan a nì bacadh a‟ phrìomhaire leasachadh obstructionist tactics a prime-ministerial action a retrievable situation à seo suas cgr A a nì mì-rian br adv hence a ghabhas obrachadh disruptive adj a bhuineas do mhodh viable adj giùlan a nì mì-rian procedural adj a sheallas inbhe moladh a ghabhas obrachadh disruptive behaviour prestigious adj a viable proposition a bhuineas don bhuidseat budgetary adj a rèir roi a sheasas na aonar a lìonas beàrn according to, stand-alone adj a bhuineas don phrìomhaire stop-gap adj relative (to) prep buidheann a sheasas na aonar a stand-alone body prime-ministerial adj a rèir an lagha according to law a mhair fada br a bhuineas don tuath luachan a rèir a chèile a tha a‟ tighinn a-steach br prolonged adj provincial adj relative values incoming adj thug am pàrtaidh dùbhlain cha tig na h-argamaidean ionnsaigh air an riaghaltas a mhair a dh‟aindeoin roi le gin a rèir a chèile a thaobh roi le gin fada notwithstanding adv the arguments are
    [Show full text]
  • First Past the Post (FPTP), Also Known As Simple Majority Voting Or Plurality Voting
    First Past the Post First Past The Post (FPTP), also known as Simple majority voting or Plurality voting How does First Past The Post work? Under First Past The Post (FPTP) voting takes place in single-member constituencies. Voters put a cross in a box next to their favoured candidate and the candidate with the most votes in the constituency wins. All other votes count for nothing. We believe FPTP is the very worst system for electing a representative government. Where is First Past The Post used? FPTP is the second most widely used voting system in the world, after Party List-PR. In crude terms, it is used in places that are, or once were, British colonies. Of the many countries that use First Past The Post , the most commonly cited are the UK to elect members of the House of Commons, both chambers of the US Congress, and the lower houses in India and Canada. First Past The Post used to be even more widespread, but many countries that used to use it have adopted other systems. Find out more about reform overseas... Pros and cons of First Past The Post The case for The arguments against It's simple to understand and thus Representatives can get elected on tiny amounts of public support as it doesn't cost much to administer. does not matter by how much they win, only that they get more votes than other candidates. It doesn't take very long to count It encourages tactical voting, as voters vote not for the candidate they all the votes and work out who's most prefer, but against the candidate they most dislike.
    [Show full text]
  • Democracy and Civic Participation Commission's Final Report
    NEWHAM DEMOCRACY AND CIVIC PARTICIPATION XXXXXXXX COMMISSION FINAL REPORT Delivered by www.newhamdemocracycommission.org CONTENTS Foreword 4 Executive summary 5 Introduction 10 SECTION 1: THE LOCAL AND NATIONAL CONTEXT 13 1.1 The local context 14 1.2 The national context 18 SECTION 2: THE MAYOR & THE GOVERNANCE OF NEWHAM BOROUGH COUNCIL 19 2.1 Governance systems: the available choices 21 2.2 Roles for Mayors 23 2.3 The Mayor as “first citizen of the Borough” 26 2.4 The Mayor’s relationship with full Council 26 2.5 The Mayor, good governance and democracy 28 2.6 A unique and distinctive Mayoral model for Newham 30 SECTION 3: AREA & NEIGHBOURHOOD GOVERNANCE 33 3.1 What we understand by “area governance” 34 3.2 Components of effective area working 35 3.3 Structural models for area working 40 3.4 Making it work: a structure to develop area-based working across Newham in context of the Newham 43 Mayoral model SECTION 4: PARTICIPATORY & DELIBERATIVE DEMOCRACY 45 4.1 Background 46 4.2 Understanding what we mean by effective, meaningful public participation 50 4.3 Ways of working to develop more deliberative democracy 53 2 Newham Democracy and Civic Participation Commission SECTION 5: CO-PRODUCTION & COMMUNITY EMPOWERMENT 57 5.1 Co-production 58 5.2 Use of co-production in regeneration 63 5.3 Building up the skills and capacity within the council and community on co-production 67 5.4 Empowering communities, and working with the voluntary sector 68 SECTION 6: DEMOCRACY, DATA & INNOVATION 69 6.1 An “Office for Data, Discovery and Democracy” 70
    [Show full text]
  • Appendix: Notes and Sources for Summary Tables
    Appendix: Notes and Sources for Summary Tables Notes Electoral systems are distinguished for having changed at least one of these elements: single- or multi-member districts, ballot, rule or formula. In contrast, changes are recorded within a single system for term, number of seats, number of districts, magnitudes and thresholds, which are given as ranges within each period (or as an average*). Public ballot and indirect elections are indicated when they exist; otherwise assume secret ballot and direct elections. The following abbreviations have been used: Maj. = Majority; Plu. = Plurality; Prop. = Proportional. ‘Universal MS’ indicates the introduction of universal male suffrage. The sign // indicates a period without elections or with authoritarian fake elections. See Glossary for definitions. Sources General Blais, André and Louis Massicotte (1997) ‘Electoral Formulas: A Macroscopic Perspective’, European Journal of Political Research, 32: 107–29. Cox, Gary W. (1997) Making Votes Count. Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press. Freedom House (R. D. Gastil and Adrian Karatnycky eds) (1972–2002) Freedom in the World. The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties. New Brunswick: Transaction <www.freedomhouse.org>. Katz, Richard S. (1997) Democracy and Elections. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press. Lijphart, Arend (1994) Electoral Systems and Party Systems. A Study of Twenty-Seven Democracies, 1945–1990. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press. Mackie, Thomas T. and Richard Rose (1991) The International Almanac of Electoral History, 3rd edn. London and Washington, DC: Macmillan-Congressional Quarterly. Massicotte, Louis, and André Blais (1999) ‘Mixed Electoral Systems: A Conceptual and Empirical Survey’, Electoral Studies, 18, 3: 341–66.
    [Show full text]
  • UK Voting Systems: Briefing Paper and Discussion Report
    UK voting systems: Briefing paper and Discussion Report Briefing paper Each of the voting systems below is used somewhere within the UK political system. System A is used for UK Parliamentary elections. Should it be replaced by one of the other systems? Systems A, B and C are Non-proportional representation in Single-member constituencies A. First-past-the-post First-past-the-post is used to elect MPs to the House of Commons. The UK is divided into constituencies and at a general election, voters put a cross (X) next to their preferred candidate on a ballot paper. Ballot papers are then counted and the one candidate who has received the most votes is elected to represent the constituency. B. Alternative Vote (AV) Under AV, voters rank candidates in order of preference by marking 1, 2, 3 and so on next to names of candidates on a ballot paper. A voter can rank as many or as few candidates as they like or just vote for one candidate. The first preference votes are counted (those with number 1 next to their name). If a candidate receives more than half of the first preference votes then they are elected. If not, the candidate with the fewest first preference votes is eliminated. Their second preference votes are reallocated to the remaining candidates. If by then a candidate has more than half of votes then they are elected. Otherwise, the process of elimination and reallocation of preference votes and is repeated until one candidate has more than half of the votes, and is elected.
    [Show full text]
  • THE POLITICS of ELECTORAL SYSTEMS This Page Intentionally Left Blank the Politics of Electoral Systems
    THE POLITICS OF ELECTORAL SYSTEMS This page intentionally left blank The Politics of Electoral Systems Edited by MICHAEL GALLAGHER and PAUL MITCHELL 1 3 Great Clarendon Street, Oxford ox26dp Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide in Oxford New York Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto With offices in Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries Published in the United States by Oxford University Press Inc., New York ß The Several Contributors 2005 The moral rights of the authors have been asserted Database right Oxford University Press (maker) First published 2005 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permitted by law, or under terms agreed with the appropriate reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department, Oxford University Press, at the address above You must not circulate this book in any other
    [Show full text]
  • A Taxonomy of Runoff Methodsq Electoral Studies
    Electoral Studies 27 (2008) 395–399 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Electoral Studies journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud A taxonomy of runoff methodsq Bernard Grofman* Department of Political Science and Center for the Study of Democracy, University of California, Irvine, CA 92697-5100, USA abstract Keywords: We look at ways of classifying runoff methods in terms of characteristics such as number of Electoral system rounds, rules used to determine which candidates advance to the next round, and rules Runoff which determine the final winner. We also compare runoffs and so-called instant runoffs Two round ballot such as the alternative vote. Alternative vote Ó 2008 Published by Elsevier Ltd. 1. Introduction is some kind of distribution requirement that opens up the possibility that the popular vote winner may not automat- Most voting rules can (barring ties) always be com- ically be selected (such as rules for regional balance in vote pleted in a single round. By a runoff method we will simply distribution (as in Nigeria, Indonesia, or Kenya) or rules mean an election which may require more than a single such as the weighted voting rule in use in the U.S Electoral round of balloting. How many ballots will be required College). will depend upon the results of the first (and subsequent) In the second section of the essay we consider parallels rounds and on the specific runoff rules. between different runoff rules eliciting a single x vote at In this essay we begin by providing a typology of runoffs each stage of the balloting and various voting procedures that is based on the conditions that will trigger a (k þ 1)th that require voters to provide a (full) rank-ordering of their ballot.
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral System Design: the New International IDEA Handbook
    Electoral System Design: The New International IDEA Handbook Electoral System Design: The New International IDEA Handbook Andrew Reynolds Ben Reilly and Andrew Ellis With José Antonio Cheibub Karen Cox Dong Lisheng Jørgen Elklit Michael Gallagher Allen Hicken Carlos Huneeus Eugene Huskey Stina Larserud Vijay Patidar Nigel S. Roberts Richard Vengroff Jeffrey A. Weldon Handbook Series The International IDEA Handbook Series seeks to present comparative analysis, information and insights on a range of democratic institutions and processes. Handbooks are aimed primarily at policy makers, politicians, civil society actors and practitioners in the field. They are also of interest to academia, the democracy assistance community and other bodies. International IDEA publications are independent of specific national or political interests. Views expressed in this publication do not necessarily represent the views of International IDEA, its Board or its Council members. The map presented in this publication does not imply on the part of the Institute any judgement on the legal status of any territory or the endorsement of such boundaries, nor does the placement or size of any country or territory reflect the political view of the Institute. The map is created for this publication in order to add clarity to the text. © International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance 2005 Reprinted 2008 Applications for permission to reproduce or translate all or any part of this publication should be made to: Information Unit International IDEA SE -103 34 Stockholm Sweden International IDEA encourages dissemination of its work and will promptly respond to requests for permission to reproduce or translate its publications. Graphic design by: Magnus Alkmar Cover photos: © Pressens Bild Printed by: Trydells Tryckeri AB, Sweden ISBN: 91-85391-18-2 Foreword The Universal Declaration of Human Rights states that ‘everyone has the right to take part in the government of his country, directly or through freely chosen representatives’.
    [Show full text]