Antonin Scalia Law School George Mason University Journal of International Commercial Law

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Antonin Scalia Law School George Mason University Journal of International Commercial Law ANTONIN SCALIA LAW SCHOOL GEORGE MASON UNIVERSITY JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW ARTICLES: AFTER LISBON: REGIONALIZATION, STANDARDIZATION, AND THE RISE OF SOCIAL AND ENVIRONMENTAL FACTORS IN EU INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT AGREEMENTS JULIA JOHNSON EUCLIDIAN PARALLELISM, LEGAL PLURALISM AND LEGAL TRANSPLANTS VIS-À- VIS TRANSPOSING THE CISG INTO THE UK LEGAL ORDER KATERINA GEORGIADO NOTES: PATENT PROTECTION REGULATION AND THE RIGHT TO HEALTH: RIPE FOR DISCUSSION IN RENEGOTIATING KORUS-FTA AERIN KIM FATCA: WHO FORGOT TO ATTACH THE CARROT TO THE STICK? RICH WHITE VOLUME 10 FALL ISSUE NUMBER 1 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW VOLUME 10 FALL ISSUE NUMBER 1 CONTENTS ARTICLES AFTER LISBON: REGIONALIZATION, STANDARDIZATION, AND THE RISE OF SOCIAL AND ENVIRONMENTAL FACTORS IN EU INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT AGREEMENTS Julia Johnson 1 EUCLIDIAN PARALLELISM, LEGAL PLURALISM AND LEGAL TRANSPLANTS VIS-À-VIS TRANSPOSING THE CISG INTO THE UK LEGAL ORDER Katerina Georgiado 29 NOTES PATENT PROTECTION REGULATION AND THE RIGHT TO HEALTH: RIPE FOR DISCUSSION IN RENEGOTIATING KORUS-FTA Aerin Kim 53 FATCA: WHO FORGOT TO ATTACH THE CARROT TO THE STICK? Rich White 78 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW VOLUME 10 FALL ISSUE NUMBER 1 Editor-in-Chief ZACHARY FAYNE Executive Editor Managing Editor Symposium Editor TAE ADERMAN REBECCA KIM PERRY RIHL Senior Articles Editor Senior Notes Editor Senior Research Editor WAI SAM LAO RICH WHITE REBECCA MAIETTA Research Editor AERIN KIM CANDIDATE MEMBERS AMANDA ALEXANDER CHAD CROWELL KELLY CROWE ARMON MIRIAN KIMBERLY ROTHENBERGER MELISSA SEVIER SARAH SMERLING JULIE ZHOU Faculty Advisor JEREMY RABKIN Cite as 9 GEO. MASON J. INT’L COM. L. ___ (2018) The George Mason Journal of International Commercial Law is published three times per year. The George Mason Journal of International Commercial Law can be contacted as follows: George Mason Journal of International Commercial Law 3301 N. Fairfax Drive, Arlington, VA 22201 http://www.georgemasonjicl.org/ The George Mason Journal of International Commercial Law is a traditional student-edited legal periodical at the George Mason University School of Law in Arlington, Virginia. Providing international scholars and practitioners a forum to exchange, develop, and publish innovative ideas, the Journal is uniquely situated to address the legal issues affecting international commerce. The Journal publishes scholarly, concise, and practical material from leading scholars and practitioners to provide a source of authority and analysis for the advancement of uniformity in the law underlying international commerce. Subscriptions: Single issues are available for download online at http://www.georgemasonjicl.org. Print versions are available by request to the Managing Editor at the mail address listed above or by email at: [email protected]. Single issues may be purchased for $15 per copy for domestic and $18 for foreign subscribers. Submissions: The Editors welcome submissions of unsolicited manuscripts. The George Mason Journal of International Commercial Law seeks to publish articles and essays making a significant, original contribution to the fields concerning international commerce. Footnotes should follow the form prescribed in The Bluebook: A Uniform System of Citation (20th ed. 2015). Articles must be both well written and completely argued at the time of submission. Manuscripts and editorial correspondence should be addressed to Senior Articles Editor, George Mason Journal of International Commercial Law, at the address listed above or by email at: [email protected]. ©2018 by Journal of International Commercial Law. All Rights Reserved. AFTER LISBON: REGIONALIZATION, STANDARDIZATION, AND THE RISE OF SOCIAL AND ENVIRONMENTAL FACTORS IN EU INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT AGREEMENTS Julia Johnson* “One must never forget that monetary union . is ultimately a political project. It aims to give a new impulse to the historic movement toward union of the European states” -Giscard d’Estaing, drafter of the EU Constitution 1997 I. INTRODUCTION The Lisbon Treaty (hereinafter “Lisbon” or “TFEU”),1 which took effect on December 1, 2009, 2 has lasting implications for international investment policy in the European Union (hereinafter “EU”). These changes will affect bilateral investment treaties (hereinafter “BITs”)3 between EU and non-EU nations. 4 Further, Lisbon has started to change global investment flows by consolidating and centralizing the EU’s investment framework.5 Investment agreements may be increasingly standardized and regionalized. Consolidation will likely also promote the EU’s social and environmental goals by standardizing provisions in investment agreements. Strengthened by new authorities under Lisbon, the EU, operating through the European Council, upon recommendation by the European Commission (referred collectively herein as “EC”), 6 and European * J.D., Duke University School of Law. 1 Consolidated Versions of the Treaty on European Union, 2008 O.J. C 115/01; Lisbon Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, 2008 O.J. C 115/01, available at http://eur- lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=OJ:C :2008:115:TOC [hereinafter TFEU]. 2 Press Release, European Commission “European Commission Welcomes the Entry Into Force of the Treaty of Lisbon,”(Dec. 1, 2009) (“The Treaty of Lisbon amends the current EU and EC treaties, without replacing them. It will provide the Union with the legal framework and tools necessary to meet future challenges and to respond to citizens’ demands.”). 3 A BIT “protect[s] the investment of an investor in the territory of a host country.” Sean Cumberlege & Bryan Neihart, THE LAW OF TRANSNATIONAL BUS. TRANSACTIONS § 23:27 (Ved Nanda & Ralph Lake eds., 2014). 4 Carrie E. Anderer, Bilateral Investment Treaties and the EU Legal Order: Implications of the Lisbon Treaty, 35 BROOK. J. INT’L L. 851, 854 (2010). 5 Id. at 875; Thomas Daemen, Why the European Union’s Lisbon Treaty Matters to In- House Counsel, 28 No. 5 ACC Docket 88, 90 (2010). 6 TFEU, art. 207 (“The European Parliament and the Council, acting by means of regulations in accordance with the ordinary legislative procedure, shall adopt the measures defining the framework for implementing the common commercial policy . The Commission shall make recommendations to the Council, which shall authorise it to open the necessary negotiations. The Council and the Commission shall be responsible for ensuring that the agreements negotiated are compatible with internal Union policies and rules.”). 2 GEO. MASON J. INT’L COM. L. [VOL. 10:1 Parliament (hereinafter “EP”), has greater capacity to centralize and govern BITs entered into by EU and non-EU nations.7 The EU’s capacity to create a common investment policy, and to enter into BITs on behalf of all EU countries, may affect BITs entered into by individual EU member states with non-EU nations. 8 After Lisbon, non-EU nations may be concerned with possible drawbacks of a centralized EU investment policy. They may believe that centralization will disadvantage investors, causing a greater risk of expropriation or diminished returns.9 Investors may be discouraged from investing, fearing the uncertainty will reduce the intended benefits of their investments.10 Despite these drawbacks, Lisbon signifies a unification of EU member nations as they work together to reach shared goals. Unification will in turn benefit investors.11 Exclusive competence means the exclusive authority to govern over a particular topic or area.12 How the EC and EP will use the exclusive competence authorized by Lisbon will become apparent with time.13 The EU and its member nations currently have shared competence over many governance decisions, 14 meaning that the member nations may pursue binding acts on behalf of that EU member nation when the EU does not act.15 When enacting policies, the EP incorporates non-economic factors such as political, social, environmental, and human rights issues. After Lisbon, many of these considerations may play greater importance in international investment policies.16 Political, collective, and social issues, such as humanitarian and environmental rights, will likely be more prominent in future extra-EU BITs, (BITs entered into between EU members and non-EU nations), as well as EU investment decisions.17 With the increased importance of the EP and the EC, member states will be more likely to abide by non-economic policies, positively reforming extra-EU BITs and developing a more transparent, efficient, and sustainable EU investment framework.18 Lisbon’s changes to the EU investment structure may improve relationships between EU and non-EU nations, which may 7 Id. at 861; TFEU art. 207. 8 Id. at 875. 9 Id. at 875. 10 Id. 11 Id. 12 TFEU, art. 5(3). 13 See e.g., John R. Schmertz & Mike Meier, EU Publishes the Text of the Treaty of Lisbon and Charter of Fundamental Rights on the European Union, 13 INT’L L. UPDATE 205, 220 (2007). 14 “FAQ on the EU Competence[s] of the European Commission Powers,” THE EUROPEAN CITIZENS’ INITIATIVE, http://ec.europa.eu/citizens- initiative/public/competences/faq (last visited Apr. 24, 2017). 15 Id. 16 Erika Szyszczak, Building a Socioeconomic Constitution: A Fantastic Object?, 35 FORDHAM INT’L L.J. 1364, 1369 (2012) (“The new emphasis upon social values and the role of solidarity is significant in a global economy increasingly leaning towards neoliberal values and a European economy heavily shaken by economic recession.”). 17 Id. 18 Id. at 1389. 2018] AFTER LISBON 3 increase investment flows. Finally, extra-EU BITs often possess a stigma of bias in favor of investors in the host state, particularly in favor of the EU, but over time, this conflict of interest will likely be relaxed due to the rise of exogenous concerns in investment policy, thus linking policy with investor protection. Such exogenous concerns may include environmental, social, and public policy protections both within and outside the EU. However, as will be described further, political differences between the EC and EP could result in a disagreement between the EP and EC on key investment policies, leading to a potential deadlock. This article will review the EU’s international investment policy from several different parameters.
Recommended publications
  • The Disclosure of State Corporate Income Tax Data: Turning the Clock Back to the Future Richard Pomp University of Connecticut School of Law
    University of Connecticut OpenCommons@UConn Faculty Articles and Papers School of Law Spring 1993 The Disclosure of State Corporate Income Tax Data: Turning the Clock Back to the Future Richard Pomp University of Connecticut School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://opencommons.uconn.edu/law_papers Part of the Taxation-Federal Commons, and the Taxation-State and Local Commons Recommended Citation Pomp, Richard, "The Disclosure of State Corporate Income Tax Data: Turning the Clock Back to the Future" (1993). Faculty Articles and Papers. 121. https://opencommons.uconn.edu/law_papers/121 +(,121/,1( Citation: 22 Cap. U. L. Rev. 373 1993 Content downloaded/printed from HeinOnline (http://heinonline.org) Mon Aug 15 17:19:23 2016 -- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License -- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text. -- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your HeinOnline license, please use: https://www.copyright.com/ccc/basicSearch.do? &operation=go&searchType=0 &lastSearch=simple&all=on&titleOrStdNo=0198-9693 THE DISCLOSURE OF STATE CORPORATE INCOME TAX DATA: TURNING THE CLOCK BACK TO THE FUTURE RICHARD D. POMP* INTRODUCTION .............................................. 374 I. THE DISCLOSURE OF INCOME TAX INFORMATION AT THE FEDERAL LEVEL: AN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE .......... 378 A. The Civil War Income Taxes: 1861-1872 ............... 379 B. The 1894 Income Tax ................................ 384 C. The Tariff Act of 1909 ............................... 386 D . 1913-1923 .......................................... 389 E. The 1924 and 1926 Acts ............................... 391 F. The Pink Slip Provisions: 1934-1935 ................
    [Show full text]
  • Retroactive Remedial Tax Legislation and the Statute of Limitations - the Silenced Claimant V
    Duquesne Law Review Volume 9 Number 1 Article 11 1970 Retroactive Remedial Tax Legislation and the Statute of Limitations - The Silenced Claimant v. I.R.S. Raymond F. Sekula Follow this and additional works at: https://dsc.duq.edu/dlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Raymond F. Sekula, Retroactive Remedial Tax Legislation and the Statute of Limitations - The Silenced Claimant v. I.R.S., 9 Duq. L. Rev. 1 (1970). Available at: https://dsc.duq.edu/dlr/vol9/iss1/11 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Duquesne Scholarship Collection. It has been accepted for inclusion in Duquesne Law Review by an authorized editor of Duquesne Scholarship Collection. Duquesne Law Review Volume 9, Number 1, Fall 1970-1971 Retroactive Remedial Tax Legislation and the Statute of Limitations- The Silenced Claimant v. I.R.S. Raymond F. Sekula* I. A HISTORY OF THE PROBLEMS INVOLVED This article is concerned with inequality in federal taxation, spe- cifically the inequality in some of the retroactive tax relief statutes enacted by Congress. These statutes have retroactively applied to years which have been normally "closed" for purposes of refunds by the statute of limitations in Section 6511 of the Internal Revenue Code. At times, the Congress has mentioned in some of these statutes that the relief given did not apply to such closed years. When the legislation has been silent in that respect, the courts have had to decide whether the statute implicitly reopens the statute of limitations on claims for refunds. Retroactive tax legislation is not new.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics During the Lincoln Administration
    4-15 Economics 1 of 4 A Living Resource Guide to Lincoln's Life and Legacy ECONOMICS DURING THE LINCOLN ADMINISTRATION War Debt . Increased by about $2 million per day by 1862 . Secretary of the Treasury Chase originally sought to finance the war exclusively by borrowing money. The high costs forced him to include taxes in that plan as well. Loans covered about 65% of the war debt. With the help of Jay Cooke, a Philadelphia banker, Chase developed a war bond system that raised $3 billion and saw a quarter of middle class Northerners buying war bonds, setting the precedent that would be followed especially in World War II to finance the war. Morrill Tariff Act (1861) . Proposed by Senator Justin S. Morrill of Vermont to block imported goods . Supported by manufacturers, labor, and some commercial farmers . Brought in about $75 million per year (without the Confederate states, this was little more than had been brought in the 1850s) Revenue Act of 1861 . Restored certain excise tax . Levied a 3% tax on personal incomes higher than $800 per year . Income tax first collected in 1862 . First income tax in U. S. history The Legal Tender Act (1862) . Issued $150 million in treasury notes that came to be called greenbacks . Required that these greenbacks be accepted as legal tender for all debts, public and private (except for interest payments on federal bonds and customs duties) . Investors could buy bonds with greenbacks but acquire gold as interest United States Note (Greenback). EarthLink.net. 18 July 2008 <http://home.earthlink.net/~icepick119/page11.html> Revenue Act of 1862 Office of Curriculum & Instruction/Indiana Department of Education 09/08 This document may be duplicated and distributed as needed.
    [Show full text]
  • RESTORING the LOST ANTI-INJUNCTION ACT Kristin E
    COPYRIGHT © 2017 VIRGINIA LAW REVIEW ASSOCIATION RESTORING THE LOST ANTI-INJUNCTION ACT Kristin E. Hickman* & Gerald Kerska† Should Treasury regulations and IRS guidance documents be eligible for pre-enforcement judicial review? The D.C. Circuit’s 2015 decision in Florida Bankers Ass’n v. U.S. Department of the Treasury puts its interpretation of the Anti-Injunction Act at odds with both general administrative law norms in favor of pre-enforcement review of final agency action and also the Supreme Court’s interpretation of the nearly identical Tax Injunction Act. A 2017 federal district court decision in Chamber of Commerce v. IRS, appealable to the Fifth Circuit, interprets the Anti-Injunction Act differently and could lead to a circuit split regarding pre-enforcement judicial review of Treasury regulations and IRS guidance documents. Other cases interpreting the Anti-Injunction Act more generally are fragmented and inconsistent. In an effort to gain greater understanding of the Anti-Injunction Act and its role in tax administration, this Article looks back to the Anti- Injunction Act’s origin in 1867 as part of Civil War–era revenue legislation and the evolution of both tax administrative practices and Anti-Injunction Act jurisprudence since that time. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 1684 I. A JURISPRUDENTIAL MESS, AND WHY IT MATTERS ...................... 1688 A. Exploring the Doctrinal Tensions.......................................... 1690 1. Confused Anti-Injunction Act Jurisprudence .................. 1691 2. The Administrative Procedure Act’s Presumption of Reviewability ................................................................... 1704 3. The Tax Injunction Act .................................................... 1707 B. Why the Conflict Matters ....................................................... 1712 * Distinguished McKnight University Professor and Harlan Albert Rogers Professor in Law, University of Minnesota Law School.
    [Show full text]
  • Income Inequality in New York City and Philadelphia During the 1860S
    Income Inequality in New York City and Philadelphia during the 1860s By Mark Stelzner Abstract In this paper, I present new income tax data for New York City and Philadelphia for the 1860s. Despite limitations, this data offers a glimpse at the income shares of the top 1, 0.1, and 0.01 percent of the population in the two premier US cities during an important period in our economic history – a glimpse previously not possible. As we shall see, the income shares of top one percent in New York City in the 1860s and mid-2000s are comparable. This combined with recent data and our knowledge of US history highlights new questions. Introduction In July 1863, New York City was ravaged by riots which extend for four full days. These riots are most commonly known for their anti-draft and racist elements. However, economic inequality was also a major factor motivating the mob. “Here [the working classes]… have been slaving in abject poverty and living in disgusting squalor all their days, while, right by their side, went up the cold, costly palaces of the rich,” explained the New York Times in October. “The riot was essentially and distinctly a proletaire outbreak,” continued the Times, “such as we have often foreseen – a movement of the abject poor against the well-off and the rich.” 1 In this paper, I present new income tax data for New York City and Philadelphia for 1863 and 1868 and 1864 to 1866, respectively. This data allows a glimpse at the income shares of the top 1, 0.1, and 0.01 percent of the population in the two premier US cities during an important period in our economic history – a glimpse previously not possible.
    [Show full text]
  • Entity Classification: the One Hundred-Year Debate
    Catholic University Law Review Volume 44 Issue 2 Winter 1995 Article 3 1995 Entity Classification: The One Hundred-Year Debate Patrick E. Hobbs Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.edu/lawreview Recommended Citation Patrick E. Hobbs, Entity Classification: The One Hundred-Year Debate, 44 Cath. U. L. Rev. 437 (1995). Available at: https://scholarship.law.edu/lawreview/vol44/iss2/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by CUA Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Catholic University Law Review by an authorized editor of CUA Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ENTITY CLASSIFICATION: THE ONE HUNDRED-YEAR DEBATE Patrick E. Hobbs* I. Introduction ................................................. 437 II. Evolution of the Tax Definition of the Term "Corporation".. 441 A. The Revenue Act of 1894 ............................... 441 B. The Corporate Excise Tax of 1909 ....................... 452 C. After the Sixteenth Amendment: A Case of Floating Commas and Misplaced Modifiers ....................... 459 D. Developing a Corporate Composite ..................... 468 III. The Failure of the Resemblance Test ........................ 481 A. The Professional Corporation ............................ 481 B. The Limited Partnership ................................. 491 C. The Limited Liability Company .......................... 510 IV . Conclusion .................................................. 518 I. INTRODUCTION One hundred years ago, in the Revenue Act of 1894,1 Congress en- acted our Nation's first peacetime income tax.2 Although the Supreme Court declared it unconstitutional within a year of its enactment,3 at least * Associate Professor of Law, Seton Hall University School of Law. B.S., 1982, Se- ton Hall University; J.D., 1985, University of North Carolina; LL.M., 1988, New York Uni- versity.
    [Show full text]
  • A Historical Examination of the Constitutionality of the Federal Estate Tax
    William & Mary Bill of Rights Journal Volume 27 (2018-2019) Issue 1 Article 5 October 2018 A Historical Examination of the Constitutionality of the Federal Estate Tax Henry Lowenstein Kathryn Kisska-Schulze Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmborj Part of the Constitutional Law Commons, and the Taxation-Federal Estate and Gift Commons Repository Citation Henry Lowenstein and Kathryn Kisska-Schulze, A Historical Examination of the Constitutionality of the Federal Estate Tax, 27 Wm. & Mary Bill Rts. J. 123 (2018), https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmborj/vol27/iss1/5 Copyright c 2018 by the authors. This article is brought to you by the William & Mary Law School Scholarship Repository. https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmborj A HISTORICAL EXAMINATION OF THE CONSTITUTIONALITY OF THE FEDERAL ESTATE TAX Henry Lowenstein* and Kathryn Kisska-Schulze** INTRODUCTION During the 2016 presidential campaign debate, Democratic candidate Hillary Clinton vowed to raise the Federal Estate Tax to sixty-five percent,1 while Republican candidate Donald Trump pledged to repeal it as part of his overall tax reform proposal.2 Following his election into the executive seat, President Trump signed into law the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA) on December 22, 2017, which encompasses the most comprehensive tax law changes in the United States in decades.3 Although the law does not completely repeal the Estate Tax, it temporarily doubles the estate and gift tax exclusion amounts for estates of decedents dying and gifts made after December 31, 2017, and before January 1, 2026.4 Following candidate Trump’s campaign pledge to repeal the Estate Tax,5 and his subsequent signing of the TCJA into law during his first year of presidency,6 an interesting question resonating from these initiatives is whether the Estate Tax is even constitutional.
    [Show full text]
  • The First National Income Tax, 1861–1872
    THE FIRST NATIONAL INCOME TAX 1 The First National Income Tax, 1861–1872 SHELDON D. POLLACK* ABSTRACT During the first months of the American Civil War, an important political debate played out in the U.S. Congress over how to restructure the nation’s system of public finance and taxation. The fiscal crisis occasioned by the mili- tary conflict forced Republican leaders (who dominated our national political institutions) to adopt drastic and controversial measures including the expan- sion of public borrowing, the issuance of a national paper currency (so-called Greenbacks), and the adoption of a national income tax. To be sure, there was widespread resistance within the Republican Party to all of these proposals— most particularly, the income tax. Unsurprisingly, conservative Republicans from the Northeast adamantly opposed the impost. Despite this opposition, a majority of Republicans eventually acquiesced to this “odious” tax based on the need to fund the Union war effort. A number of key Republican leaders in Congress preferred this impost over the alternatives (in particular, a national land tax), casting their arguments in favor of the income tax in terms of “equity,” “justice,” and “fairness.” Based on their support, Congress approved a national income tax, signed into law by President Lincoln on August 5, 1861. While the war effort was largely funded by public borrow- ing and increases to tariff rates, the income tax made a modest contribution to financing the Northern military campaign and emerged as an important component in the reconstituted wartime fiscal system. Although the impost was allowed to expire soon after the resolution of the military conflict, the Civil War income tax served as the model for the modern income tax enacted by Congress more than 40 years later.
    [Show full text]
  • Selective Consumption Taxes in Historical Perspective WILLIAM F
    Excerpt from Adam J. Hoffer and Todd Nesbit, eds., For Your Own Good: Taxes, Paternalism, and Fiscal Discrimination in the Twenty-First Century. Arlington, VA: Mercatus Center at George Mason University, 2018. CHAPTER 1 Selective Consumption Taxes in Historical Perspective WILLIAM F. SHUGHART II Jon M. Huntsman School of Business, Utah State University Imposts, excises, and, in general, all duties upon articles of consumption, may be compared to a fluid, which will, in time, find its level with the means of paying them. The amount to be contributed by each citizen will in a degree be at his own option, and can be regulated by an atten- tion to his resources. The rich may be extravagant, the poor can be frugal; and private oppression may always be avoided by a judicious se lection of objects proper for such impositions. It is a signal advantage of taxes on articles of consumption, that they contain in their own nature a security against excess. They prescribe their own limit; which cannot be exceeded without defeating the end proposed, that is, an extension of the revenue. When applied to this object, the saying is as just as it is witty, that, “in po liti cal arithmetic, two and two do not always make four.” If duties are too high, they lessen the consumption; the collection is eluded; and the product to the trea sury is not so great as when they are confined within proper and moderate bounds. — Alexander Hamilton, Federalist No. 21 19 William F. SHUGHART II ntil the ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment to the US Constitution in 1913, which authorized the collection of taxes on incomes, the federal government of the United States relied heavi ly Uon indirect taxes (import duties and selective excises) to generate revenue.1 In 1912, for example, internal tax receipts (90.4 percent of which were generated by vari ous excise taxes) represented just over half (50.8 percent) of all federal revenues; customs duties accounted for most of the rest (40.8 percent of the total) (Yelvington 1997, 44, 47).
    [Show full text]
  • Looking to the Past in Planning for the Future: Does the Modern Estate Tax Fit Within the Ideals of the Founding Fathers?
    LOOKING TO THE PAST IN PLANNING FOR THE FUTURE: DOES THE MODERN ESTATE TAX FIT WITHIN THE IDEALS OF THE FOUNDING FATHERS? Alica Lerud* I. INTRODUCTION In recent years, the federal estate tax has garnered a great deal of attention from lawmakers, the media, and the general public.' Dubbed the "death tax," the federal estate tax is levied upon estates that exceed a certain value.2 The estate tax has been attacked as being immoral and unfair by opponents.3 Sup- porters of the estate tax have argued that it is essential in the preservation of democracy.4 Regarding this debate, one commentator has said: Never in the course of human taxation has so much furor been generated by so many about a tax that affects so few. While only 2 percent of estates in this country are taxed and account for slightly more than 1 percent of all federal revenues, tempers over the estate tax continue to flare in a strange combustion of moral indignation and 5 economic erudition. Essentially, the estate tax debate has become one of inherent freedoms, societal obligations, and fundamental fairness. The federal estate tax finds its constitutional basis in Article I, Section 8 of the United States Constitution, which reads, "The Congress shall have Power To lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Imposts and Excises, to pay the Debts and provide for the common Defence and general Welfare of the United States."6 * J.D. candidate 2006, University of Nevada, Las Vegas, William S. Boyd School of Law. B.S., University of Nevada, Reno, 2003.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Income Inequality in the United States
    University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Doctoral Dissertations Dissertations and Theses Summer November 2014 Understanding Income Inequality in the United States Mark J. Stelzner University of Massachusetts Amherst Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umass.edu/dissertations_2 Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Stelzner, Mark J., "Understanding Income Inequality in the United States" (2014). Doctoral Dissertations. 268. https://doi.org/10.7275/5714260.0 https://scholarworks.umass.edu/dissertations_2/268 This Open Access Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Dissertations and Theses at ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. It has been accepted for inclusion in Doctoral Dissertations by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Understanding Inequality A Dissertation Presented by MARK STELZNER Submitted to the Graduate School of the University of Massachusetts Amherst in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY SEPTEMBER 2014 Economics © Copyright by Mark Stelzner 2014 All Rights Reserved Understanding Inequality A Dissertation Presented by MARK STELZNER Approved as to style and content by _______________________________________________ Gerald Friedman, Chair _______________________________________________ Peter Skott, Member _______________________________________________ Dan Clawson, Member ______________________________________________ Michael
    [Show full text]
  • The Tax Court's Execution of the Family Entity: the Tax Court's Application of Internal Revenue Code Section 2036(A) to Family Entities
    North Dakota Law Review Volume 80 Number 1 Article 3 2004 The Tax Court's Execution of the Family Entity: The Tax Court's Application of Internal Revenue Code Section 2036(a) to Family Entities Daniel H. Ruttenberg Follow this and additional works at: https://commons.und.edu/ndlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Ruttenberg, Daniel H. (2004) "The Tax Court's Execution of the Family Entity: The Tax Court's Application of Internal Revenue Code Section 2036(a) to Family Entities," North Dakota Law Review: Vol. 80 : No. 1 , Article 3. Available at: https://commons.und.edu/ndlr/vol80/iss1/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the School of Law at UND Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in North Dakota Law Review by an authorized editor of UND Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE TAX COURT'S EXECUTION OF THE FAMILY ENTITY: THE TAX COURT'S APPLICATION OF INTERNAL REVENUE CODE SECTION 2036(a) TO FAMILY ENTITIES DANIEL H. RUITrENBERG* The United States Tax Court (Tax Court) has increasingly applied section 2036(a) of the Internal Revenue Code' to family entities in a man- ner that greatly reduces, if not virtually eliminates, their usefulness for estate planning purposes. Section 2036(a) includes in a decedent's gross estate, for estate tax purposes, assets transferred during his2 life if he re- tained certain rights over or benefits from the assets.3 Section 2036(a) has two main components- (a)(1) and (a)(2).4 Section 2036(a)(1) deals with a donor-decedent's direct retention of the possession or enjoyment of or right to income from transferred property.
    [Show full text]