Rev. of Econ. 82/2

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Rev. of Econ. 82/2 DOES FINANCIAL REFORM RAISE OR REDUCE SAVING? Oriana Bandiera, Gerard Caprio, Patrick Honohan, and Fabio Schiantarelli* Abstract—The effect of financial liberalization on private saving is may differ substantially from the impact effect. Lastly, theoretically ambiguous, not only because the link between interest rate levels and saving is itself ambiguous, but also because financial liberaliza- financial liberalization is a process rather than a one-shot tion is a multidimensional and phased process, sometimes involving event. reversals. Using principal components, we construct 25-year time-series The purpose of this paper is to provide an empirical indices of financial liberalization for each of eight developing countries: Chile, Ghana, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Turkey, and Zim- examination of the total effect of the financial reform on babwe. These are employed in an econometric analysis of private saving in aggregate private saving based on eight case studies: Chile, these countries. Our results cannot offer support for the hypothesis that Ghana, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Turkey, and financial liberalization will increase saving. On the contrary, the indica- tions are that liberalization overall—and in particular those elements that Zimbabwe. These countries have all significantly liberalized relax liquidity constraints—may be associated with a fall in saving. their financial sector policies, but they differ in the nature and phasing of financial liberalization, in other aspects of I. Introduction their policy reform program, and in the macroeconomic context in which liberalization took place. This variety WAVE OF liberalization of financial markets has swept allows us to explore the degree to which the saving response over much of the developing world, especially since the A differs from country to country, as well as to test whether the mid-1980s. This liberalization has been characterized by greater scope being granted to market forces in determining response is a common one. interest rates and in allocating credit (Caprio, Atiyas, and Financial reform typically comprises several key phases Hanson (1994)). Although this has occurred under the that are often separated by several years. Reform measures pressure of increased globalization of financial markets and are introduced in a number of different dimensions: interest following the example of many industrial countries, there rates, credit allocation, bank ownership, prudential regula- has been an expectation that financial liberalization would tion, security markets, and openness of the capital account. help economic development. In particular, the early litera- The best sequencing of these various elements is frequently ture on financial repression, following McKinnon (1973) debated. In practice, reform has not been a monotonic and Shaw (1973), stressed the potential role of higher process: In some cases, setbacks have involved temporary interest rates in mobilizing savings that could be put to policy reversals. productive use. A thorough quantitative assessment of the impact of such But it is far from clear that financial liberalization actually a process must take account of its gradual and reversible does increase private saving. One obvious and important nature. Based on an analysis of the historical evolution in consideration is that the effect of interest rates on saving is each case, we have identified the timing of major moves on itself ambiguous, as the income effect might offset substitu- eight different dimensions towards a more liberalized sys- tion effects. In addition, one must recognize that financial tem. Using the principal components of the resulting matri- liberalization involves more than just a change in interest ces of 0–1 variables (1’s correspond to the years after a rates. Other dimensions of financial liberalization, such as particular reform is introduced), we obtain a single continu- increased household access to consumer credit or housing ous financial liberalization index for each of our countries. finance, might also work to reduce private saving (Muell- As an alternative, we also construct for each country a pair bauer and Murphy (1990), Jappelli and Pagano (1994)).1 of subindices that capture different aspects of the liberaliza- Furthermore, the long-term effect of liberalization on saving tion process. Our data extends over a quarter of a century—a period long enough to allow us to model the response to liberalization in each country separately—but in addition to Received for publication February 2, 1999. Revision accepted for the country-by-country results, we also present panel data publication November 29, 1999. evidence. * London School of Economics, World Bank, World Bank and CEPR, Visual inspection of the time series of the main relevant and Boston College, respectively. We would like to thank Pierre-Richard Age´nor, Craig Burnside, Bruce variables—the financial liberalization index, the real interest Hansen, Tullio Jappelli, Peter Pedroni, Deborah Wetzel, Stephen Zeldes, rate, monetary depth (either M2 or total credit to the private participants in seminars at Boston College and the World Bank, and sector expressed as a percentage of GNDI), and the private especially Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, Luis Serve´n and John Campbell as well as three anonymous referees for useful suggestions. The findings, interpre- saving ratio—reveals little evidence of a clear-cut relation- tations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the ship between saving and liberalization. authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its We estimate an econometric relationship expressing the executive directors, or the countries they represent. 1 There is also the view, stressed in the neostructuralist contributions of private saving ratio as a function of the real interest rate and Taylor (1983) and Van Wijnbergen (1982) that the effect of reduced of the index of financial liberalization (or its subcompo- taxation on formal financial intermediaries might actually reduce the flow nents), along with income, inflation, and government saving. of credit to the private sector to the extent that reserve requirements captured funds for the government that had been substituted away from the In addition to directly measuring the contribution of liberal- curb market. ization to the volume of aggregate saving, our procedure The Review of Economics and Statistics, May 2000, 82(2): 239–263 ௠ 2000 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/003465300558768 by guest on 28 September 2021 240 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS improves on earlier estimates of the saving-interest relation, The process of financial liberalization also unleashes a which omitted any role for financial-sector liberalization series of short-run effects. Not only can the process of other than the real interest rate channel. domestic portfolio adjustment lead to transitory changes in Although they cannot be solved-out for a net effect on the the volume of domestic saving, but (especially when com- level of saving, Euler equations can be helpful in detecting bined with liberalization of the foreign exchange market) it the extent of credit rationing. In this spirit, we also assess the may also induce large capital inflows, largely but not impact of financial reform on the extent of liquidity con- exclusively attributable to a return flow of past flight capital. straints by estimating an augmented Euler equation for If not sterilized, such inflows can result in a credit boom consumption, in which it is assumed (in an extension of the leading to real income surges, which in turn have a direct, model of Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1991)) that the but transitory, effect on the volume of saving. Modeling of fraction of the consumers are liquidity constrained varies the effect of financial liberalization on saving needs to take with the degree of financial liberalization. account of these short-run effects, as well as the long-run The structure of the paper is as follows. Section II effect. It is also important to recognize that some of the describes the main channels through which financial liberal- overall effects can come through the effect of income on ization may affect saving and briefly reviews the relevant saving. empirical literature. Section III describes the financial reform process as it occurred in each of the eight countries A. Steady-State Effects being studied here. This section also explains and graphs our index of financial liberalization and examines the prima If financial liberalization improves the rate of return for facie evidence about its effects. Sections IV and V present savers, then knowledge of the interest elasticity of saving the econometric results based on the saving function and on can help predict the long-term impact of liberalization on the augmented Euler equation for consumption, respec- saving. However, because of the wealth and current income tively. Section VI concludes. effects that will generally be present, there is no presumption as to the direction of the aggregate saving response to an II. Financial Liberalization and Saving: Theoretical exogenous interest rate change. Despite many studies, this Background and Review of the Empirical Evidence remains an empirically controversial area, partly because of a surprising shortage of reliable and comparable cross- Although financial liberalization can enhance the effi- country
Recommended publications
  • African Successes, Volume II: Human Capital
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: African Successes, Volume II: Human Capital Volume Author/Editor: Sebastian Edwards, Simon Johnson, and David N. Weil, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBNs: 978-0-226-31605-5 (cloth) Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/afri14-2 Conference Dates: December 11–12, 2009; July 18–20, 2010; August 3–5, 2011 Publication Date: September 2016 Chapter Title: Comparing Economic and Social Interventions to Reduce Intimate Partner Violence: Evidence from Central and Southern Africa Chapter Author(s): Radha Iyengar, Giulia Ferrari Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c13379 Chapter pages in book: (p. 165 – 214) 6 Comparing Economic and Social Interventions to Reduce Intimate Partner Violence Evidence from Central and Southern Africa Radha Iyengar and Giulia Ferrari 6.1 Introduction Empowerment of women within households and reduction in domestic violence remains a major issue around the world, including Africa. Despite this, there is a lack of broad evidence and little consensus among scholars or practitioners as to what programs or policies are effective. In particular, the debate remains as to whether economic conditions, such as wage rates or labor market opportunities, affect bargaining power and reduction in vio- lence or whether specific gender- based programs are required. This chapter describes an impact evaluation of a financial skills and negotiation- training program in conjunction with microfinancing in Burundi compared to data from a previously published study on gender- based training for women receiving microfinancing in South Africa. The Burundi program coupled discussion groups for both women and Radha Iyengar is a senior economist at RAND.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Financial Reform Raise Or Reduce Savings?
    Does Financial Reform Raise or Reduce Savings? Authors: Oriana Bandiera, Gerard Caprio Jr., Patrick Honohan, Fabio Schiantarelli This work is posted on eScholarship@BC, Boston College University Libraries. Boston College Working Papers in Economics, 1998 Originally posted on: http://ideas.repec.org/p/boc/bocoec/413.html DOES FINANCIAL REFORM RAISE OR REDUCE SAVINGS? By Oriana Bandiera (Boston College) Gerard Caprio Jr. (World Bank) Patrick Honohan (World Bank and CEPR) Fabio Schiantarelli (Boston College) This draft: September 1998 We would like to thank Pierre-Richard AgŽnor, Craig Burnside, Bruce Hansen, Tullio Jappelli, Peter Pedroni, Deborah Wetzel, Stephen Zeldes, participants in seminars at Boston College and the World Bank, and especially Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, and Luis ServŽn for useful suggestions. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. DOES FINANCIAL REFORM RAISE OR REDUCE SAVING? By Oriana Bandiera*, Gerard Caprio Jr.**, Patrick Honohan** and Fabio Schiantarelli* (*Boston College, **World Bank) Abstract The effect of financial liberalization on private saving is theoretically ambiguous, not only because the link between interest rate levels and saving is itself ambiguous, but also because financial liberalization is a multi-dimensional and phased process, sometimes involving reversals. Some dimensions, such as increased household access to consumer credit or housing finance, might also work to reduce private savings rather than increasing them. Furthermore, the long-term effect of liberalization on savings may differ substantially from the impact effect. Using Principal Components, we construct a 25-year time series index of financial liberalization for each of eight developing countries: Chile, Ghana, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Turkey and Zimbabwe.
    [Show full text]
  • CEPR/University of Milan Annual Symposium in Labour Economics
    CEPR/University of Milan Annual Symposium In Labour Economics 10 and 11 June 2021, online conference* Programme Thursday, 10 June 11.55 -12.00 Welcome address 12:00 - 13:00 Keynote: Eliana La Ferrara (U Bocconi) Apart but Connected: Online Tutoring and Student Outcomes during the COVID- 19 Pandemic (with Michela Carlana, Harvard Kennedy School) 13:00 - 13.45 Matteo Bobba (U Toulouse), Tim Ederer (U Toulouse), Gianmarco Leon-Ciliotta (UPF, Barcelona GSE), Christopher Neilson (Princeton U) and Marco Nieddu (U Cagliari) Teacher Compensation and Structural Inequality: Evidence from Centralized Teacher School Choice in Peru 13.45 - 14:30 Erika Deserranno (Northwestern U), Philipp Kastrau (UPF) and Gianmarco Leon Ciliotta (UPF, Barcelona GSE) Promotions and Productivity: The Role of Meritocracy and Pay Progression in the Public Sector 14:30 - 15:00 Break 15.00 – 15.45 Girum Abebe (Ethiopian Development Research Institute), Stefano Caria (U Warwick), Marcel Fafchamps (Stanford U), Paolo Falco (U Copenhagen), Simon Franklin (QMUL), Simon Quinn (U Oxford) and Forhad Shilpi (World Bank) Matching Frictions and Distorted Beliefs: Evidence from a Job Fair Experiment 15.45 – 16.30 Simon Franklin (QMUL), Clement Imbert (U Warwick), Girum Abebe (Ethiopian Development Research Institute) and Carolina Mejia-Mantilla (World Bank) Urban Public Works in Spatial Equilibrium: Experimental Evidence from Ethiopia 16.30 – 17.15 Oriana Bandiera (LSE), Vittorio Bassi (USC), Robin Burgess (LSE), Imran Rasul (UCL), Munshi Sulaiman (BRAC) and Anna Vitali (UCL) Worker Heterogeneity and Job Search: Evidence from a Six-Year Experiment in Uganda 17.15 - 17:30 Break 17.30 – 18.15 Marius Faber (U of Basel), Andrés Sartoz (Princeton U) and Marco Tabellini (Harvard Business School) Local Shocks and Internal Migration: The Disparate Effects of Robots and Chinese Imports in the US Keynote: Sandy Black (Columbia U) 18.15 – 19.15 Where Does Wealth Come From? Presenters are marked in bold.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cost of Doing Nothing: the Price of Inaction in Response to the COVID-19 Crisis
    The cost of doing nothing: The price of inaction in response to the COVID-19 crisis Version: 10 July 2020 Authors: Dirk-Jan Omtzigt, Head, Humanitarian Financing Strategy and Analysis Unit, OCHA Ashley Pople, University of Oxford and consultant for OCHA Introduction The global crisis induced by the COVID-19 pandemic is unprecedented in nature. Emerging as a health crisis, the pandemic has become a threat to global prosperity and stability. Keeping in mind the fundamental uncertainty about the trajectory of the pandemic and the economic forecasts, there is common consensus that the global economy will experience the deepest recession since the Great Depression and the broadest collapse in per capita income since 1870. As of 24 June, the IMF projects a -4.9 percent contraction in global GDP in 2020, followed by a protracted and uneven recovery due to the persistence of the shock. The extent to which these downturns are synchronised and spill over across borders makes this crisis relatively unique. Domestically, the OECD and the G20 countries have responded with a large stimulus package estimated at over $11 trillion (approximately 10% of world GDP). In comparison, the cost of protecting the most vulnerable 10 percent of the world from the worst primary and secondary impacts of COVID-19 today is an additional $90 billion – less than 1 percent of the current stimulus package. Relative to high-income countries, “whatever it takes” is a fundamentally different concept in low-income countries due to limited forex reserves, central bank dollar swap lines and fiscal space. Strong multilateral coordination is required to meet the shortfall in financing and support the strengthening of health, education and other social safety nets – now, rather than later.
    [Show full text]
  • The Allocation of Authority in Organizations: a Field Experiment with Bureaucrats
    The Allocation of Authority in Organizations: A Field Experiment with Bureaucrats∗ Oriana Bandiera, Michael Carlos Best, Adnan Qadir Khan, & Andrea Prat January 2020 To view the latest version, please go to https://bit.ly/2UItDXP Abstract We design a field experiment to study how the allocation of authority between frontline procurement officers and their monitors affects performance both directly and through the response to incentives. In collaboration with the government of Pun- jab, Pakistan, we shift authority from monitors to procurement officers and introduce financial incentives to a sample of 600 procurement officers in 26 districts. We find that autonomy alone reduces prices by 9% without reducing quality and that the effect is stronger when the monitor tends to delay approvals for purchases until the end of the fiscal year. In contrast, the effect of performance pay is muted, except when agents face a monitor who does not delay approvals. The results illustrate that organizational de- sign and anti-corruption policies must balance agency issues at different levels of the hierarchy. ∗Bandiera: London School of Economics [email protected], Best: Columbia University and NBER [email protected], Khan: London School of Economics [email protected], Prat: Columbia Uni- versity [email protected]. This experiment was preregistered in the Social Science Registry at https://www.socialscienceregistry.org/trials/610. We are grateful to the World Bank, the Interna- tional Growth Centre, and the JPAL Governance Initiative for financial support. We thank Ahsen Omar Majid, Sher Afghan Asad, Maha Rehman, Ameera Jamal, Omar Gondal, Khawaja Hussain Mahmood, Sub- han Khalid, Sophia Tahir Mir, Ovais Siddiqui, Noor Sehur, Zain ul Abideen, Ahsan Farooqui, Natasha Ansari and Reem Hasan for outstanding research assistance in Lahore, and Hamza Husain, Sakshi Gupta and Advitha Arun for outstanding research assistance at Columbia.
    [Show full text]
  • Effort and Selection Effects of Performance Pay In
    EFFORT AND SELECTION EFFECTS OF PERFORMANCE PAY IN KNOWLEDGE CREATION∗ y Erina Ytsma It is well-documented that performance pay has positive effort and selection effects in routine, easy to measure tasks, but its effect in knowledge creation is much less understood. This paper studies the effects of explicit and implicit, market-based incentives commonly found in knowledge work industries in a multi-tasking model and estimates the causal effort and selection effects of performance incentives in knowledge creation by exploiting the introduction of performance pay in German academia as a natural experiment, and using a newly constructed dataset of the universe of German academics. I find that performance incentives attract more productive academics, and research quantity increases by 14 to 18%, but there is no increase in the highest quality output. JEL J33, M52, O31 1 INTRODUCTION Knowledge work is an important pillar of present-day economies. It has become rapidly more prevalent over the last four decades and exhibited consistent growth in occupational employment share1(Autor, 2019). Furthermore, knowledge creation has long been considered an important driver of economic growth (Romer, 1986; Lucas, 1988). Yet much is still unclear about how to motivate knowledge workers, including how they respond to performance pay. This paper sheds ∗I would like to thank Laurence Ales, Pierre Azoulay, Oriana Bandiera, Tim Besley, Jordi Blanes-i-Vidal, Kenneth Corts, Pablo Casas-Arce, Baran Duzce, Florian Englmaier, Jeff Furman, Maitreesh Ghatak, Bob
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper
    WORKING PAPER 20-14 Public Procurement in Law and Practice Erica Bosio, Simeon Djankov, Edward Glaeser, and Andrei Shleifer August 2020 ABSTRACT In this paper we examine a new dataset of laws and practices governing public Erica Bosio is procurement, as well as procurement outcomes, in 187 countries. We measure a researcher at the World Bank. regulation as restrictions on the discretion of the procuring agents. We find that Simeon Djankov is laws and practices are highly correlated with each other across countries, and a senior research fellow at the better practices are correlated with better outcomes, but laws themselves are Peterson Institute not correlated with outcomes. To shed light on this puzzle, we present a model for International of procurement in which both regulation and public sector capacity determine Economics. Andrei Shleifer is John L. the efficiency of procurement. In the model, regulation is effective in countries Loeb Professor of with low public sector capacity, and detrimental in countries with high public Economics at Harvard sector capacity because it inhibits the socially optimal exercise of discretion. We University. Ed Glaeser is Fred and Eleanor find evidence broadly consistent with this prediction: Regulation of procurement Glimp Professor improves outcomes but only in countries with low public sector capacity. of Economics in the Faculty of Arts and Sciences at JEL codes: H40, H57, K42 Harvard University. Keywords: Procurement, Law, Practice, Corruption 1750 Massachusetts Avenue, NW | Washington, DC 20036-1903
    [Show full text]
  • Royal Economic Society
    Newsletter Issue no. 184 January 2019 A new look Correspondence As we anticipated in the October 2018 of this Letter from France p.3 Newsletter, the Society now has a new website, edited and maintained within the RES Office. The Society’s Chief Executive explains the reasons for overhauling the website, and plans for its future development on p.22 of this issue. From the Newsletter’s point of view, one of its immediate Features benefits is to release us from the obligation to Was Domar Right? Serfdom and Factor reflect the rather insipid orange house style of its Endowments in Bohemia p.5 predecessor. The new website is altogether more Doreen Warriner and Winter in Prague, 1938-39 p.10 colourful (in all senses) and established readers will recognise the hard copy Newsletter’s return to Professorial Salaries and Research Performance in a shade of blue that dates from its origin, nearly the REF, 2014 p.13 fifty years ago, in 1972. Robert Peston echoes RES complaint p.15 A rather more significant novelty for this issue is Video competitions for students p.17 that it almost fails to mention Brexit. It would have succeeded entirely were it not for Robert Pro Bono Economics — a notable milestone p.20 Peston’s allegations at last year’s Cheltenham A new website for the RES p.22 Literary Festival that the BBC had failed to report accurately the economics of the Brexit debate. This is exactly the same complaint made by the Society and reported in Newsletter no. 179. Another contribution with strong links to earlier issues is Ian Preston’s feature on the activities of RES office news p.23 Doreen Warriner and her associates in pre-war Prague.
    [Show full text]
  • Nava Ashraf and Oriana Bandiera Altruistic Capital
    Nava Ashraf and Oriana Bandiera Altruistic capital Article (Published version) (Refereed) Original citation: Ashraf, Nava and Bandiera, Oriana (2017) Altruistic capital. American Economic Review, 107 (5). pp. 70-75. ISSN 0002-8282 DOI: 10.1257/aer.p20171097 © 2017 American Economic Association This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/81953/ Available in LSE Research Online: June 2017 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2017, 107(5): 70–75 https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20171097 Altruistic Capital† By Nava Ashraf and Oriana Bandiera* To better understand human behavior, econ- We illustrate our ideas in an industry that is omists have enriched the private utility maxi- perceived to be highly selfish: banking. Two mization model with altruism and prosociality, observations motivate us. First, bankers affect reciprocity and fairness, identity, and values social welfare through many channels, most Akerlof and Kranton 2005; Benabou and Tirole importantly by allocating credit to productive 2003;( Besley and Ghatak 2005; Fehr and Schmidt rather than predatory or speculatory activities.
    [Show full text]
  • Andrea Prat Graduate School of Business Columbia University 3022 Broadway, Uris 624 New York, NY 10027-6902 212-854-6176 [email protected]
    June 2015 Andrea Prat Graduate School of Business Columbia University 3022 Broadway, Uris 624 New York, NY 10027-6902 212-854-6176 [email protected] ACADEMIC POSITIONS . Richard Paul Richman Professor of Business, Columbia Business School, Columbia University, 2012 –. Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Columbia University, 2012 –. Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, London School of Economics, 2004 – 2013. Visiting Scholar, Department of Economics, Stern School of Business, Fall 2006. Reader, Department of Economics, London School of Economics, 2002 – 2004. Lecturer, Department of Economics, London School of Economics, 2000 – 2002. Assistant Professor, Tilburg University, 1997 – 2000. OTHER POSITIONS . Program Director, CEPR, London (Industrial Organization), 2012-. Member, Organizing Committee, European Summer Symposium in Economic Theory, Gerzensee (ESSET), 2007-. Principal Investigator, Executive Time Use Project, 2008-. Council Member, Royal Economic Society, 2010-2014. Council Member, European Economic Association, 2008-2012. EDITORIAL ACTIVITY Associate Editor, Theoretical Economics. 2007-. Chair, Review of Economic Studies, 2010-13. Managing Editor, Review of Economic Studies, 2005-2009. RESEARCH INTERESTS Organizational Economics Game Theory Political Economy EDUCATION . Ph.D., Department of Economics, Stanford University, June 1997: advisor: Kenneth Arrow co-advisors: Masahiko Aoki, Dimitri Vayanos Thesis: “Team Theory and Information Processing: Organizations in Which Agents Have Endogenous
    [Show full text]
  • L'économie Politique De L'étalon Dollar
    UNIVERSITE GRENOBLE II UNIVERSITE DU QUEBEC PIERRE MENDES FRANCE A MONTREAL Faculté Économie, Stratégies, Entreprise Faculté de Science Politique et de Droit THESE Doctorat en Économie Internationale PhD en Science Politique L’ÉCONOMIE POLITIQUE DE L’ÉTALON DOLLAR Les États-Unis et le nouveau régime financier international Présentée et soutenue publiquement par Grégory VANEL Le 17 novembre 2005 Sous la cotutelle de : Bernard GERBIER / Christian DEBLOCK Membres du Jury Monsieur André CARTAPANIS Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université d’Aix-Marseille II (Président du Jury) Monsieur Christian DEBLOCK Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université du Québec à Montréal (Codirecteur) Monsieur Bernard ÉLIE Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université du Québec à Montréal Monsieur Bernard GERBIER Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université Grenoble II (Codirecteur) Monsieur Dominique PLIHON Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université Paris XIII (Rapporteur) Monsieur Geoffrey R.D. UNDERHILL Professor of International Governance, Universiteit Van Amsterdam (Rapporteur) L’Université Pierre Mendès France et l’Université du Québec à Montréal n’entendent donner aucune approbation ou improbation aux opinions particulières du candidat : ces opinions doivent être considérées comme propres à leur auteur. 2 REMERCIEMENTS Les remerciements sont comme des fleurs fraîchement coupées : chacun sait qu’elles sècheront vite, mais en recevoir fait toujours plaisir. Les miens seront brefs, mais j’ose espérer qu’ils sauront rester le plus longtemps possible dans le cœur de leurs destinataires. Tout d’abord, je tiens à remercier les professeurs Bernard GERBIER et Christian DEBLOCK. Leurs encouragements et leur clairvoyance m’ont été d’un grand secours, surtout dans les nombreux moments de doute et de remise en question jonchant ce parcours, oh combien tumultueux, de la cotutelle.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Economy of Institutions and Development
    14.773: Political Economy of Institutions and Development Daron Acemoglu and Benjamin Olken Spring 2020. This course is intended as an introduction to the newly emerging field of political econ- omy of institutions and development. Its purpose is to give you both a sense of the frontier research topics and a good command of the tools in the area. The reading list is inten- tionally long, to give those of you interested in the field an opportunity to dig deeper into some of the topics in this area. The lectures will cover the material with *'s in detail and also discuss the material without *'s, but in less detail. Grading: The course grade will be a combination of a final exam and approximately 6 problem sets, with 25% weight on problem sets. Course Information: Professors Daron Acemoglu: [email protected] Benjamin Olken: Teaching Assistant Cory Smith: [email protected] Office Hours: Tue 4-5, E52-416 Lecture TTh 10:30-12, E51-376 Recitation F 4-5:30, E51-376 1 1 Introduction 1.1 Does Political Economy Matter? (DA, 1 lecture) 1. *Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon and Robinson, James (2006) \Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth" in Handbook of Economic Growth, Aghion, Philippe and Durlauf, Steven, eds. Amsterdam; North-Holland. 2. *Acemoglu, Daron (2003) \Why Not a Political Coase Theorem?" Journal of Com- parative Economics, 31, 620-652. 3. Demsetz, Harold (1967) \Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review, 57, 61-70. 4. Taylor, M Scott (2011) “Buffalo Hunt: International Trade and the Virtual Extinction of the North American Bison." American Economic Review, 101(7), 3162-95.
    [Show full text]