Effort and Selection Effects of Performance Pay In

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Effort and Selection Effects of Performance Pay In EFFORT AND SELECTION EFFECTS OF PERFORMANCE PAY IN KNOWLEDGE CREATION∗ y Erina Ytsma It is well-documented that performance pay has positive effort and selection effects in routine, easy to measure tasks, but its effect in knowledge creation is much less understood. This paper studies the effects of explicit and implicit, market-based incentives commonly found in knowledge work industries in a multi-tasking model and estimates the causal effort and selection effects of performance incentives in knowledge creation by exploiting the introduction of performance pay in German academia as a natural experiment, and using a newly constructed dataset of the universe of German academics. I find that performance incentives attract more productive academics, and research quantity increases by 14 to 18%, but there is no increase in the highest quality output. JEL J33, M52, O31 1 INTRODUCTION Knowledge work is an important pillar of present-day economies. It has become rapidly more prevalent over the last four decades and exhibited consistent growth in occupational employment share1(Autor, 2019). Furthermore, knowledge creation has long been considered an important driver of economic growth (Romer, 1986; Lucas, 1988). Yet much is still unclear about how to motivate knowledge workers, including how they respond to performance pay. This paper sheds ∗I would like to thank Laurence Ales, Pierre Azoulay, Oriana Bandiera, Tim Besley, Jordi Blanes-i-Vidal, Kenneth Corts, Pablo Casas-Arce, Baran Duzce, Florian Englmaier, Jeff Furman, Maitreesh Ghatak, Bob Gibbons, De Gruyter, Rosario Macera, Bentley Macleod, Michal Matejka, Bob Miller, Steve Pischke, Andrea Prat, Carol Propper, John van Reenen, Mark Schankerman, Axel Schniederjuergen, Ananya Sen, Chris Stanton, Scott Stern, Neil Thompson, Fabian Waldinger, the ministries of education of the German states and seminar and conference participants at DRUID 2016, the 31st EEA Congres, ESNASM 2017, ESEM 2017, ESEWM 17, IOEA 18, SIOE 18, BePE 2018, AEA 2019, GEIRC 2019, EAA 2019, GSE-OE 2019, AAA 2019, NBER Personnel Economics Summer Institute 2019, MAS Midyear 2020, CMU MAC 2019, MIT TIES, MIT IDE, MIT OE Lunch, Universidad Carlos III, Copenhagen Business School, Carnegie Mellon Tepper, UANDES, Universite Laval and MPI Munich for helpful comments, information or data. A previous version of this paper was titled “Career Concerns in Knowledge Creation”. yCarnegie Mellon University, Tepper School of Business. Tepper Building Room 4123, 5000 Forbes Avenue, Pittsburgh, PA 15213. e-mail: [email protected]. Phone: +1-412-268-1117. 1Knowledge work is defined here as non routine cognitive jobs that comprise a host of intellectual tasks. 1 light on the effect of performance pay on knowledge creation by causally identifying the effort and selection effects of performance incentives in academia. It is by now well-understood that performance pay increases productivity in routine tasks and settings in which output is readily measurable (e.g. car window replacement, fruit picking, students’ test scores), through increases in effort or by attracting the most productive individuals (Lazear, 2000; Shearer, 2004; Bandiera, Barankay and Rasul, 2005; Leuven et al., 2011; Dohmen and Falk, 2011). However, it is not clear that performance pay would have the same effects in the context of knowledge work. For one, knowledge work generally comprises multiple, complex tasks, the output of which is often not measurable or only a noisy signal of effort. Multi-tasking problems are therefore likely to arise (Holmstrom and Milgrom, 1991; Hellmann and Thiele, 2011). Secondly, because quality dimensions such as impact and novelty are valuable outcome characteristics for many types of knowledge work, incentive systems may need to be structured differently, with a longer time-horizon and allowing for (early) exploration and experimentation (Azoulay, Graff Zivin and Manso, 2011; Manso, 2011; Ederer and Manso, 2013). Finally, knowledge workers may be particularly highly intrinsically motivated. Higher-powered extrinsic incentives may crowd-out this intrinsic motivation, thus potentially reducing knowledge output (Benabou and Tirole, 2003; Bénabou and Tirole, 2006; Besley and Ghatak, 2005, 2018). In this paper, I study the effect of performance incentives on the quantity and quality of knowl- edge output and the productivity of knowledge workers attracted by high-powered incentives both empirically and theoretically. I present a simple multi-tasking model with explicit and implicit, market-based incentives commonly found in knowledge work industries and use this to derive testable implications for both average incentive effects and heterogeneous responses across ability types. I test the model’s predictions by exploiting the introduction of performance pay in German academia as a natural experiment, and using a newly constructed dataset of the universe of German academics2. The specifics of the roll-out of the performance-related pay scheme give rise to a differential incidence of performance incentives across tenure and age cohorts. This allows me to causally and separately identify the effort and selection effects in a difference-in-differences framework. The theoretical model presented in this paper builds on Gibbons and Murphy (1992) and features both explicit performance incentives (bonuses for performance on the job) and implicit, market-based incentives (wage supplements negotiated in contract talks). This combination of explicit and implicit incentives is a common feature of pay structures in knowledge work industries3. The model also incorporates multi-tasking issues as output has two dimensions, quantity and quality, the latter of which is less precisely measured (c.f. Holmstrom and Milgrom (1991)). Both output dimensions increase with effort as well as agent ability and agent ability is imperfectly known by the market and the agent (i.e. there is symmetric uncertainty about agent 2This dataset is also used in Ytsma (2021). 3Market-based wages determined in contract negotiations (career concerns) and on-the-job performance bonuses are common performance incentives in academia and knowledge creation jobs more generally (Bonatti and Hörner, 2017), as well as managerial jobs (Gibbons and Murphy, 1992) and professional jobs such as in law (Ferrer, 2016), finance (Hong, Kubik and Solomon, 2000; Chevalier and Ellison, 1999) and software development (Lerner and Wulf, 2007). 2 ability). The market then uses output measures as signals of both effort and agent ability, to inform agent pay. This, in turn creates incentives for the agent to exert effort. Because quality is less precisely measured, the incentives to exert effort toward quality are relatively weaker. Yet because the market takes both quantity and quality output into account to update believes about agent ability, incentives to exert quality are not absent either and they are stronger for higher ability academics, for whom exerting effort towards both quantity and quality is assumed to be relatively less costly. In equilibrium, and relative to a flat wage, output quantity goes up unambiguously in response to performance pay, but output quality increases only if the quality output measure is sufficiently precise. These responses are not uniform across ability types. Performance pay increases quantity effort the most for the lowest ability workers, and least for workers of intermediate ability. Quality effort on the other hand increases the most or decreases the least for the most able workers and decreases the most for those of intermediate ability. That is, there is no simple substitution of quantity for quality, rather the degree to which there is substitution varies across ability types and depends on the noise with which output dimensions are measured. Furthermore, the higher-powered incentives attract workers of higher ability (in expectation), since they can expect to earn more under performance pay. In order to empirically analyze the effect of performance pay in academia, I constructed a data set comprising the affiliations, research productivity measures and related information of the universe of academics in Germany by consolidating information from various, unstructured data sources. To estimate the effort effect, I use the fact that any contract signed or renegotiated after the implementation of the reform necessarily falls under the new performance pay scheme, while any existing contract continues to fall under the old age-related pay scheme. Academics who start their first tenured affiliation before the reform therefore fall under the age-related pay scheme, while those who start their first tenured affiliation after the reform are paid according to the performance pay scheme. If the timing of the start of the first tenured affiliation is exogenous, any difference in the change of productivity from before to after the reform between academics who start their first tenured position just before the reform and those who start a first tenured position directly after the reform can be interpreted as the causal effect of performance pay on effort. I find that performance pay increases research quantity and quality-adjusted quantity by at least 14 to 18% on average4. At the same time, the average quality of publications5 decreases by 9 to 10% in response to performance pay. The response in output quantity is equivalent to treated academics publishing almost one extra paper every three years, while the decline in average quality is equivalent to a decrease of almost 0.22 in the
Recommended publications
  • African Successes, Volume II: Human Capital
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: African Successes, Volume II: Human Capital Volume Author/Editor: Sebastian Edwards, Simon Johnson, and David N. Weil, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBNs: 978-0-226-31605-5 (cloth) Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/afri14-2 Conference Dates: December 11–12, 2009; July 18–20, 2010; August 3–5, 2011 Publication Date: September 2016 Chapter Title: Comparing Economic and Social Interventions to Reduce Intimate Partner Violence: Evidence from Central and Southern Africa Chapter Author(s): Radha Iyengar, Giulia Ferrari Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c13379 Chapter pages in book: (p. 165 – 214) 6 Comparing Economic and Social Interventions to Reduce Intimate Partner Violence Evidence from Central and Southern Africa Radha Iyengar and Giulia Ferrari 6.1 Introduction Empowerment of women within households and reduction in domestic violence remains a major issue around the world, including Africa. Despite this, there is a lack of broad evidence and little consensus among scholars or practitioners as to what programs or policies are effective. In particular, the debate remains as to whether economic conditions, such as wage rates or labor market opportunities, affect bargaining power and reduction in vio- lence or whether specific gender- based programs are required. This chapter describes an impact evaluation of a financial skills and negotiation- training program in conjunction with microfinancing in Burundi compared to data from a previously published study on gender- based training for women receiving microfinancing in South Africa. The Burundi program coupled discussion groups for both women and Radha Iyengar is a senior economist at RAND.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Financial Reform Raise Or Reduce Savings?
    Does Financial Reform Raise or Reduce Savings? Authors: Oriana Bandiera, Gerard Caprio Jr., Patrick Honohan, Fabio Schiantarelli This work is posted on eScholarship@BC, Boston College University Libraries. Boston College Working Papers in Economics, 1998 Originally posted on: http://ideas.repec.org/p/boc/bocoec/413.html DOES FINANCIAL REFORM RAISE OR REDUCE SAVINGS? By Oriana Bandiera (Boston College) Gerard Caprio Jr. (World Bank) Patrick Honohan (World Bank and CEPR) Fabio Schiantarelli (Boston College) This draft: September 1998 We would like to thank Pierre-Richard AgŽnor, Craig Burnside, Bruce Hansen, Tullio Jappelli, Peter Pedroni, Deborah Wetzel, Stephen Zeldes, participants in seminars at Boston College and the World Bank, and especially Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, and Luis ServŽn for useful suggestions. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. DOES FINANCIAL REFORM RAISE OR REDUCE SAVING? By Oriana Bandiera*, Gerard Caprio Jr.**, Patrick Honohan** and Fabio Schiantarelli* (*Boston College, **World Bank) Abstract The effect of financial liberalization on private saving is theoretically ambiguous, not only because the link between interest rate levels and saving is itself ambiguous, but also because financial liberalization is a multi-dimensional and phased process, sometimes involving reversals. Some dimensions, such as increased household access to consumer credit or housing finance, might also work to reduce private savings rather than increasing them. Furthermore, the long-term effect of liberalization on savings may differ substantially from the impact effect. Using Principal Components, we construct a 25-year time series index of financial liberalization for each of eight developing countries: Chile, Ghana, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Turkey and Zimbabwe.
    [Show full text]
  • CEPR/University of Milan Annual Symposium in Labour Economics
    CEPR/University of Milan Annual Symposium In Labour Economics 10 and 11 June 2021, online conference* Programme Thursday, 10 June 11.55 -12.00 Welcome address 12:00 - 13:00 Keynote: Eliana La Ferrara (U Bocconi) Apart but Connected: Online Tutoring and Student Outcomes during the COVID- 19 Pandemic (with Michela Carlana, Harvard Kennedy School) 13:00 - 13.45 Matteo Bobba (U Toulouse), Tim Ederer (U Toulouse), Gianmarco Leon-Ciliotta (UPF, Barcelona GSE), Christopher Neilson (Princeton U) and Marco Nieddu (U Cagliari) Teacher Compensation and Structural Inequality: Evidence from Centralized Teacher School Choice in Peru 13.45 - 14:30 Erika Deserranno (Northwestern U), Philipp Kastrau (UPF) and Gianmarco Leon Ciliotta (UPF, Barcelona GSE) Promotions and Productivity: The Role of Meritocracy and Pay Progression in the Public Sector 14:30 - 15:00 Break 15.00 – 15.45 Girum Abebe (Ethiopian Development Research Institute), Stefano Caria (U Warwick), Marcel Fafchamps (Stanford U), Paolo Falco (U Copenhagen), Simon Franklin (QMUL), Simon Quinn (U Oxford) and Forhad Shilpi (World Bank) Matching Frictions and Distorted Beliefs: Evidence from a Job Fair Experiment 15.45 – 16.30 Simon Franklin (QMUL), Clement Imbert (U Warwick), Girum Abebe (Ethiopian Development Research Institute) and Carolina Mejia-Mantilla (World Bank) Urban Public Works in Spatial Equilibrium: Experimental Evidence from Ethiopia 16.30 – 17.15 Oriana Bandiera (LSE), Vittorio Bassi (USC), Robin Burgess (LSE), Imran Rasul (UCL), Munshi Sulaiman (BRAC) and Anna Vitali (UCL) Worker Heterogeneity and Job Search: Evidence from a Six-Year Experiment in Uganda 17.15 - 17:30 Break 17.30 – 18.15 Marius Faber (U of Basel), Andrés Sartoz (Princeton U) and Marco Tabellini (Harvard Business School) Local Shocks and Internal Migration: The Disparate Effects of Robots and Chinese Imports in the US Keynote: Sandy Black (Columbia U) 18.15 – 19.15 Where Does Wealth Come From? Presenters are marked in bold.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cost of Doing Nothing: the Price of Inaction in Response to the COVID-19 Crisis
    The cost of doing nothing: The price of inaction in response to the COVID-19 crisis Version: 10 July 2020 Authors: Dirk-Jan Omtzigt, Head, Humanitarian Financing Strategy and Analysis Unit, OCHA Ashley Pople, University of Oxford and consultant for OCHA Introduction The global crisis induced by the COVID-19 pandemic is unprecedented in nature. Emerging as a health crisis, the pandemic has become a threat to global prosperity and stability. Keeping in mind the fundamental uncertainty about the trajectory of the pandemic and the economic forecasts, there is common consensus that the global economy will experience the deepest recession since the Great Depression and the broadest collapse in per capita income since 1870. As of 24 June, the IMF projects a -4.9 percent contraction in global GDP in 2020, followed by a protracted and uneven recovery due to the persistence of the shock. The extent to which these downturns are synchronised and spill over across borders makes this crisis relatively unique. Domestically, the OECD and the G20 countries have responded with a large stimulus package estimated at over $11 trillion (approximately 10% of world GDP). In comparison, the cost of protecting the most vulnerable 10 percent of the world from the worst primary and secondary impacts of COVID-19 today is an additional $90 billion – less than 1 percent of the current stimulus package. Relative to high-income countries, “whatever it takes” is a fundamentally different concept in low-income countries due to limited forex reserves, central bank dollar swap lines and fiscal space. Strong multilateral coordination is required to meet the shortfall in financing and support the strengthening of health, education and other social safety nets – now, rather than later.
    [Show full text]
  • The Allocation of Authority in Organizations: a Field Experiment with Bureaucrats
    The Allocation of Authority in Organizations: A Field Experiment with Bureaucrats∗ Oriana Bandiera, Michael Carlos Best, Adnan Qadir Khan, & Andrea Prat January 2020 To view the latest version, please go to https://bit.ly/2UItDXP Abstract We design a field experiment to study how the allocation of authority between frontline procurement officers and their monitors affects performance both directly and through the response to incentives. In collaboration with the government of Pun- jab, Pakistan, we shift authority from monitors to procurement officers and introduce financial incentives to a sample of 600 procurement officers in 26 districts. We find that autonomy alone reduces prices by 9% without reducing quality and that the effect is stronger when the monitor tends to delay approvals for purchases until the end of the fiscal year. In contrast, the effect of performance pay is muted, except when agents face a monitor who does not delay approvals. The results illustrate that organizational de- sign and anti-corruption policies must balance agency issues at different levels of the hierarchy. ∗Bandiera: London School of Economics [email protected], Best: Columbia University and NBER [email protected], Khan: London School of Economics [email protected], Prat: Columbia Uni- versity [email protected]. This experiment was preregistered in the Social Science Registry at https://www.socialscienceregistry.org/trials/610. We are grateful to the World Bank, the Interna- tional Growth Centre, and the JPAL Governance Initiative for financial support. We thank Ahsen Omar Majid, Sher Afghan Asad, Maha Rehman, Ameera Jamal, Omar Gondal, Khawaja Hussain Mahmood, Sub- han Khalid, Sophia Tahir Mir, Ovais Siddiqui, Noor Sehur, Zain ul Abideen, Ahsan Farooqui, Natasha Ansari and Reem Hasan for outstanding research assistance in Lahore, and Hamza Husain, Sakshi Gupta and Advitha Arun for outstanding research assistance at Columbia.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper
    WORKING PAPER 20-14 Public Procurement in Law and Practice Erica Bosio, Simeon Djankov, Edward Glaeser, and Andrei Shleifer August 2020 ABSTRACT In this paper we examine a new dataset of laws and practices governing public Erica Bosio is procurement, as well as procurement outcomes, in 187 countries. We measure a researcher at the World Bank. regulation as restrictions on the discretion of the procuring agents. We find that Simeon Djankov is laws and practices are highly correlated with each other across countries, and a senior research fellow at the better practices are correlated with better outcomes, but laws themselves are Peterson Institute not correlated with outcomes. To shed light on this puzzle, we present a model for International of procurement in which both regulation and public sector capacity determine Economics. Andrei Shleifer is John L. the efficiency of procurement. In the model, regulation is effective in countries Loeb Professor of with low public sector capacity, and detrimental in countries with high public Economics at Harvard sector capacity because it inhibits the socially optimal exercise of discretion. We University. Ed Glaeser is Fred and Eleanor find evidence broadly consistent with this prediction: Regulation of procurement Glimp Professor improves outcomes but only in countries with low public sector capacity. of Economics in the Faculty of Arts and Sciences at JEL codes: H40, H57, K42 Harvard University. Keywords: Procurement, Law, Practice, Corruption 1750 Massachusetts Avenue, NW | Washington, DC 20036-1903
    [Show full text]
  • Royal Economic Society
    Newsletter Issue no. 184 January 2019 A new look Correspondence As we anticipated in the October 2018 of this Letter from France p.3 Newsletter, the Society now has a new website, edited and maintained within the RES Office. The Society’s Chief Executive explains the reasons for overhauling the website, and plans for its future development on p.22 of this issue. From the Newsletter’s point of view, one of its immediate Features benefits is to release us from the obligation to Was Domar Right? Serfdom and Factor reflect the rather insipid orange house style of its Endowments in Bohemia p.5 predecessor. The new website is altogether more Doreen Warriner and Winter in Prague, 1938-39 p.10 colourful (in all senses) and established readers will recognise the hard copy Newsletter’s return to Professorial Salaries and Research Performance in a shade of blue that dates from its origin, nearly the REF, 2014 p.13 fifty years ago, in 1972. Robert Peston echoes RES complaint p.15 A rather more significant novelty for this issue is Video competitions for students p.17 that it almost fails to mention Brexit. It would have succeeded entirely were it not for Robert Pro Bono Economics — a notable milestone p.20 Peston’s allegations at last year’s Cheltenham A new website for the RES p.22 Literary Festival that the BBC had failed to report accurately the economics of the Brexit debate. This is exactly the same complaint made by the Society and reported in Newsletter no. 179. Another contribution with strong links to earlier issues is Ian Preston’s feature on the activities of RES office news p.23 Doreen Warriner and her associates in pre-war Prague.
    [Show full text]
  • Nava Ashraf and Oriana Bandiera Altruistic Capital
    Nava Ashraf and Oriana Bandiera Altruistic capital Article (Published version) (Refereed) Original citation: Ashraf, Nava and Bandiera, Oriana (2017) Altruistic capital. American Economic Review, 107 (5). pp. 70-75. ISSN 0002-8282 DOI: 10.1257/aer.p20171097 © 2017 American Economic Association This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/81953/ Available in LSE Research Online: June 2017 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2017, 107(5): 70–75 https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20171097 Altruistic Capital† By Nava Ashraf and Oriana Bandiera* To better understand human behavior, econ- We illustrate our ideas in an industry that is omists have enriched the private utility maxi- perceived to be highly selfish: banking. Two mization model with altruism and prosociality, observations motivate us. First, bankers affect reciprocity and fairness, identity, and values social welfare through many channels, most Akerlof and Kranton 2005; Benabou and Tirole importantly by allocating credit to productive 2003;( Besley and Ghatak 2005; Fehr and Schmidt rather than predatory or speculatory activities.
    [Show full text]
  • Andrea Prat Graduate School of Business Columbia University 3022 Broadway, Uris 624 New York, NY 10027-6902 212-854-6176 [email protected]
    June 2015 Andrea Prat Graduate School of Business Columbia University 3022 Broadway, Uris 624 New York, NY 10027-6902 212-854-6176 [email protected] ACADEMIC POSITIONS . Richard Paul Richman Professor of Business, Columbia Business School, Columbia University, 2012 –. Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Columbia University, 2012 –. Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, London School of Economics, 2004 – 2013. Visiting Scholar, Department of Economics, Stern School of Business, Fall 2006. Reader, Department of Economics, London School of Economics, 2002 – 2004. Lecturer, Department of Economics, London School of Economics, 2000 – 2002. Assistant Professor, Tilburg University, 1997 – 2000. OTHER POSITIONS . Program Director, CEPR, London (Industrial Organization), 2012-. Member, Organizing Committee, European Summer Symposium in Economic Theory, Gerzensee (ESSET), 2007-. Principal Investigator, Executive Time Use Project, 2008-. Council Member, Royal Economic Society, 2010-2014. Council Member, European Economic Association, 2008-2012. EDITORIAL ACTIVITY Associate Editor, Theoretical Economics. 2007-. Chair, Review of Economic Studies, 2010-13. Managing Editor, Review of Economic Studies, 2005-2009. RESEARCH INTERESTS Organizational Economics Game Theory Political Economy EDUCATION . Ph.D., Department of Economics, Stanford University, June 1997: advisor: Kenneth Arrow co-advisors: Masahiko Aoki, Dimitri Vayanos Thesis: “Team Theory and Information Processing: Organizations in Which Agents Have Endogenous
    [Show full text]
  • L'économie Politique De L'étalon Dollar
    UNIVERSITE GRENOBLE II UNIVERSITE DU QUEBEC PIERRE MENDES FRANCE A MONTREAL Faculté Économie, Stratégies, Entreprise Faculté de Science Politique et de Droit THESE Doctorat en Économie Internationale PhD en Science Politique L’ÉCONOMIE POLITIQUE DE L’ÉTALON DOLLAR Les États-Unis et le nouveau régime financier international Présentée et soutenue publiquement par Grégory VANEL Le 17 novembre 2005 Sous la cotutelle de : Bernard GERBIER / Christian DEBLOCK Membres du Jury Monsieur André CARTAPANIS Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université d’Aix-Marseille II (Président du Jury) Monsieur Christian DEBLOCK Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université du Québec à Montréal (Codirecteur) Monsieur Bernard ÉLIE Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université du Québec à Montréal Monsieur Bernard GERBIER Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université Grenoble II (Codirecteur) Monsieur Dominique PLIHON Professeur de Sciences Économiques, Université Paris XIII (Rapporteur) Monsieur Geoffrey R.D. UNDERHILL Professor of International Governance, Universiteit Van Amsterdam (Rapporteur) L’Université Pierre Mendès France et l’Université du Québec à Montréal n’entendent donner aucune approbation ou improbation aux opinions particulières du candidat : ces opinions doivent être considérées comme propres à leur auteur. 2 REMERCIEMENTS Les remerciements sont comme des fleurs fraîchement coupées : chacun sait qu’elles sècheront vite, mais en recevoir fait toujours plaisir. Les miens seront brefs, mais j’ose espérer qu’ils sauront rester le plus longtemps possible dans le cœur de leurs destinataires. Tout d’abord, je tiens à remercier les professeurs Bernard GERBIER et Christian DEBLOCK. Leurs encouragements et leur clairvoyance m’ont été d’un grand secours, surtout dans les nombreux moments de doute et de remise en question jonchant ce parcours, oh combien tumultueux, de la cotutelle.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Economy of Institutions and Development
    14.773: Political Economy of Institutions and Development Daron Acemoglu and Benjamin Olken Spring 2020. This course is intended as an introduction to the newly emerging field of political econ- omy of institutions and development. Its purpose is to give you both a sense of the frontier research topics and a good command of the tools in the area. The reading list is inten- tionally long, to give those of you interested in the field an opportunity to dig deeper into some of the topics in this area. The lectures will cover the material with *'s in detail and also discuss the material without *'s, but in less detail. Grading: The course grade will be a combination of a final exam and approximately 6 problem sets, with 25% weight on problem sets. Course Information: Professors Daron Acemoglu: [email protected] Benjamin Olken: Teaching Assistant Cory Smith: [email protected] Office Hours: Tue 4-5, E52-416 Lecture TTh 10:30-12, E51-376 Recitation F 4-5:30, E51-376 1 1 Introduction 1.1 Does Political Economy Matter? (DA, 1 lecture) 1. *Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon and Robinson, James (2006) \Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth" in Handbook of Economic Growth, Aghion, Philippe and Durlauf, Steven, eds. Amsterdam; North-Holland. 2. *Acemoglu, Daron (2003) \Why Not a Political Coase Theorem?" Journal of Com- parative Economics, 31, 620-652. 3. Demsetz, Harold (1967) \Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review, 57, 61-70. 4. Taylor, M Scott (2011) “Buffalo Hunt: International Trade and the Virtual Extinction of the North American Bison." American Economic Review, 101(7), 3162-95.
    [Show full text]
  • Tackling Youth Unemployment: Evidence From
    Tackling Youth Unemployment: Evidence from a Labor Market Experiment in Uganda¤ Livia Alfonsi Oriana Bandiera Vittorio Bassi Robin Burgess Imran Rasul Munshi Sulaiman Anna Vitaliy December 2017 Abstract We design a labor market experiment to compare demand-side and supply-side policies to tackle youth unemployment, a key issue in low-income countries. The experiment tracks 1700 workers and 1500 …rms over four years to contrast the e¤ects of o¤ering workers vocational training (VT) to o¤ering …rms wage subsidies to train workers on-the-job (FT). Both treat- ments lead to skill accumulation but whilst VT workers learn sector-speci…c skills, FT workers learn more …rm-speci…c skills. This is associated with higher employment rates for each type of worker but the e¤ect is 50% larger for VT (21% vs 14%) and their total earnings increase by more (34% vs 20%). Structurally estimating a job ladder model reveals the mechanisms: VT workers receive higher rates of unemployment-to-job o¤ers and higher rates of job-to-job o¤ers. This greater labor market mobility stems from the certi…ability and transferability of their skills, and causes the wage pro…les of VT workers to diverge away from FT workers. Evidence from the …rm-side of the experiment complements these …ndings: we …nd that some of the higher returns to VT are driven by workers matching to higher productivity …rms. Our evidence shows both …rms and workers are constrained in this setting and that subsidies to either side of the labor market would increase workers’ employment and earnings.
    [Show full text]