The Modern Stage of Capitalism: the Drama of Markets and Money (1870-1930)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Modern Stage of Capitalism: the Drama of Markets and Money (1870-1930) The Modern Stage of Capitalism: The Drama of Markets and Money (1870-1930) The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Sniderman, Alisa. 2015. The Modern Stage of Capitalism: The Drama of Markets and Money (1870-1930). Doctoral dissertation, Harvard University, Graduate School of Arts & Sciences. Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:17467505 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA The Modern Stage of Capitalism: The Drama of Markets and Money (1870-1930) A dissertation presented by Alisa Sniderman to The Department of Comparative Literature in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the subject of Comparative Literature Harvard University Cambridge, Massachusetts April 2015 © 2015 Alisa Sniderman All rights reserved. Dissertation Adviser: Martin Puchner Alisa Sniderman The Modern Stage of Capitalism: The Drama of Markets and Money (1870-1930) Abstract The Modern Stage of Capitalism tells the story of why and how modern drama captured the spirit of capitalism in all its contradictions. Although the bourgeois novel has long been considered the definitive genre of capital, at the end of the nineteenth century, Western theatre was in the perfect position to explore the ambiguous impact of capitalist culture. It was at the zenith of the economic hierarchy of the arts and at the nadir of the aesthetic hierarchy. Even with the serious drama of the day, modern theatre could not entirely purge itself of the tarnish of commerce. This enmeshment in commerce and the market economy generated a wealth of formal innovations and a wide range of responses to capitalist culture that went beyond moral outrage. Dramatists from Ibsen and Shaw to Brecht and O’Neill were neither apologists for, nor mere detractors of capitalism; they explored the bonds and clashes between religious values and secular economic virtues, drawing parallels between the institution of theatre and the brave new world of capitalist modernity. Besides dramatic texts, this interdisciplinary project relies on archival research of theatre productions, socio-economic theories that the playwrights responded to (Smith, Marx, Weber, Morris, Taylor), and critical theory that examines the relationship between economics and literary studies (Bourdieu, Jameson, Moretti). The present study takes modern theatre as a case study to show that products of culture engage with capitalism in a network of both promotional and antagonistic relations. The modern stage became a testing ground for the ideas of capitalist culture including the work ethic, competition, and the accumulation of capital. iii Table of Contents Part One: Capital I. Introduction 1 II. Play the Market: Representations of Capitalist Economy in Henrik Ibsen, Adam Smith, and Émile Zola 21 III. The Invisible Stage Hand, or the Drama of Capitalist Realism 94 Part Two: Labor IV. Machine Art: From German to American Expressionist Theatre 145 V. It’s a Jungle Out There: Human, Animal, and Capital in the Early Drama of Brecht and O’Neill 209 VI. Conclusion 252 VII. Bibliography 258 iv Figures 1.1 View of the Paris Bourse, an illustration from Edmond Texier, Tableau de Paris, vol. 2 (Paris: Pauli et Le Chevalier, 1853), 9 1.2 Book cover of Coulisses de Bourse et de Théâtre (1882) by Edmond Benjamin and Henry Buguet, 10 v Acknowledgements I thank Martin Puchner for his generous guidance and invaluable feedback from the onset of my dissertation to its completion. He believed in and encouraged the project before a word was written. His mentorship has been a gift throughout my graduate study. William Mills Todd III has provided continual guidance, kind support, and words of wisdom throughout my years at Harvard, first when I was an undergraduate and then a graduate student. His course, Literature as Institutions, has had a profound influence on the way I think about literary and dramatic texts and their relationship to history and economics. David Damrosch’s sharp eye and critical insights have greatly enriched the project and made me consider questions and problems I would not have otherwise noticed. I could not have asked for a more supportive committee, and I owe its members the deepest thanks. For intellectual conversation, encouragement, and mentorship, I thank Justin Weir, Svetlana Boym, David Rodowick, John Hamilton, Karen Thornber, Christie McDonald, and Marc Shell. Many thanks to Wanda Di Bernardo and Isaure Mignotte for administrative support and words of kindness. Something more than a thank you goes out to Zachary Sniderman for his support, patience, and every meal cooked in the past six years. Parts of this dissertation were written with the generous support of the Whiting Foundation, The Krupp Family Foundation, and the Harvard—École Normale Superieure Exchange Program. vi For my mother vii Introduction “Money is a kind of poetry.” –Wallace Stevens. “There is the capitalist art and the capitalist style of life.” —Joseph A. Schumpeter. Theatre and commerce. The coupling of these words might strike us as obvious and embarrassing, conjuring up images of second-rate Victorian melodramas and lavish Broadway spectacles. As American playwright Tina Howe puts it, “of all the arts, the theatre is the most conservative, because you have that ghastly problem of having to sell all the tickets every night.”1 As a result, when discussing modern theatre as art, critics tend to remember the noble ventures of the Independent Theatre movement in Europe and the Little Theatre movement in the United States that sprang up at the end of the nineteenth century to defy the boorish commercialism of conventional theatre. To talk about money and the material conditions of theatre making is often deemed so self-evident as to be uninteresting. This dismissive attitude is evident even in the economic histories of the theatre, such as The Business of the Theatre (1932) that covers American theatre from 1750 to 1932 and that the American Actors’ Equity Association commissioned Alfred L. Bernheim and the Staff of the Labor Bureau. Bernheim notes that “in modern times theatre has always been commercial” and lists Shakespeare as a prominent example of an artist who catered to his audience and to the tastes of his day.2 Yet instead of contemplating the relationship between modern theatre and the economic world in which it developed, Bernheim simply suggests that as long as profit-making doesn’t override aesthetic considerations, theatre is in the clear as far as artistic integrity goes. Yet artistic 1 Qtd. in Richard Toscan, Playwriting Seminars 2.0: A Handbook on the Art and Craft of Dramatic Writing with an Introduction to Screenwriting (Franz Press, 2012), 18. 2 Alfred L. Bernheim, The Business of the Theatre: An Economic History of the American Theatre 1750-1932, assisted by Sara Harding and the Staff of the Labor Bureau, Inc. (New York: Benjamin Blom, 1932), 3. 1 integrity and the question of respectability were at the center of modern drama. At the end of the nineteenth century, Western theatre was in the perfect position to explore the ambiguous impact of capitalist culture: it was at the zenith of the economic hierarchy of the arts and at the nadir of the aesthetic hierarchy. But even with the serious drama of the day, theatre could not entirely purge itself of the tarnish of commerce. It is easy to forget how uneasy the fathers of modern drama such as Ibsen, Chekhov, and O’Neill initially felt toward their attraction to an art deemed low by their contemporaries. “A play is a pension fund,” writes Anton Chekhov in a letter to his brother where he advises the latter to start scribbling for the stage because it doesn’t require much talent.3 Chekhov, who first begins his playwriting career by penning popular vaudevilles, would continue to have a love-hate relationship with the theatre. His ambivalent attitude eventually produced a masterpiece of modern drama—Чайка (1896; The Seagull)—a dramatic work that lays bare the inherent commercial values behind the façade of the art world and the social construction of “talent.” This sense of complicity and enmeshment in the market economy is precisely what elicited a rich variety of responses to capitalist culture in modern drama that went beyond apology or moral outrage. The History of the Drama of Capital To be sure, the history of the theatre, once divorced from ritual, has long been bound up with money and capital. In early modern Europe, professional theatre companies were already proto-capitalist joint stock companies that depended on large-scale credit made available by the 1571 usury statue. No wonder so many of Shakespeare’s plays, such as The Merchant of Venice 3 Chekhov to Al. P. Chekhov, 21 February 1899, in A. P. Chekhov, Polnoe sobranie sochinenii i pisem: Pis’ma [Complete Works and Letters: Letters], vol. 3 (Moscow: Nauka, 1976), 164. Translations from original are my own. 2 (1605) and The Life of Timon of Athens (1607), dramatize the vicissitudes of credit and debt.4 The last two decades in particular have witnessed significant scholarly attention paid to economic issues in Shakespeare and early modern English drama, a time when drama faced little competition from prose fiction.5 During the Restoration and early eighteenth century, morality plays about the perils of avarice and financial speculation were popular with the audiences. Thomas Shadwell’s The Volunteers, or the Stockjobbers (1693) predicted the crash of the South Sea Bubble that came in 1720. Caryl Churchill includes a scene from Shadwell’s play in Act One of her Serious Money (1987), which takes place at the London Stock Exchange.
Recommended publications
  • The Economy: Cover
    UNIT 17 THE GREAT DEPRESSION, GOLDEN AGE, AND GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS ECONOMISTS HAVE LEARNED DIFFERENT LESSONS FROM THREE PERIODS OF DOWNTURN AND INSTABILITY THAT HAVE INTERRUPTED OVERALL IMPROVEMENTS IN LIVING STANDARDS IN HIGH INCOME ECONOMIES SINCE THE END OF THE FIRST WORLD WAR • There have been three distinctive economic epochs in the hundred years following the First World War—the roaring twenties and the Great Depression, the golden age of capitalism and stagflation, and the great moderation and subsequent financial crisis of 2008. • The end of each of these epochs—the stock market crash of 1929, the decline in profits and investment in the late 1960s and early 1970s culminating in the oil shock of 1973, and the financial crisis of 2008, respectively—was a sign that institutions that had governed the eco- nomy to that point had failed. • The new institutions marking the golden age of capitalism—increased trade union strength and government spending on social insurance— addressed the aggregate demand problems highlighted by the Great Depression and were associated with rapid productivity growth, invest- ment, and falling inequality. • Nevertheless, the golden age ended with a crisis of profitability, invest- ment, and productivity, followed by stagflation. • The policies adopted in response to the end of the golden age restored high profits and low inflation at the cost of rising inequality, but did not restore the investment and productivity growth of the previous epoch, and made economies vulnerable to debt-fuelled financial booms. One of these booms precipitated a global financial crisis in 2008. Before dawn on Saturday, 7 February 2009, 3,582 firefighters began deploying across the Australian state of Victoria.
    [Show full text]
  • Rebellion of Osvald Alving Reflected in Henrik Ibsen's
    REBELLION OF OSVALD ALVING REFLECTED IN HENRIK IBSEN’S GHOSTS DRAMA (1881): PSYCHOANALYTIC APPROACH PUBLICATION ARTICLE Submitted as a Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for Getting Bachelor Degree of Education in English Departmen by: ANANDA DHIRA ANORAGA A320110085 DEPARTMENT OF ENGLISH EDUCATION SCHOOL OF TEACHER TRANING AND EDUCATION MUHAMMADIYAH UNIVERSITY OF SURAKARTA 2016 REBELLION OF OSVALD ALVING REFLECTED IN HENRIK IBSEN’S GHOSTS DRAMA (1881): PSYCHOANALYTIC APPROACH ANANDA DHIRA ANORAGA School of Teacher Training and Education Muhammadiyah University of Surakarta Abstrak Penelitian ini bertujuan untuk menganalisis pemberontakan yang ada dalam drama Henrik Ibsen yang berjudul Ghosts dengan Pendekatan Psikoanalitik. Penelitian ini bertujuan untuk menganalisis drama berdasarkan Pendekatan Psikoanalitik. Penelitian ini adalah penelitian kualitatif dengan menggunakan drama Henrik Ibsen Ghosts (1881) sebagai objek. Ada dua jenis sumber data: primer dan sekunder. Sumber data primer adalah naskah drama Henrik Ibsen Ghosts dan sumber data sekunder adalah beberapa buku sastra dan beberapa artikel yang berhubungan dengan drama. Metode pengumpulan data dalam penelitian ini adalah studi pustaka dengan membaca dan meringkas data. Dalam menganalisis data, penulis menggunakan analisis deskriptif. Hasil dari penelitian ini adalah Osvald memiliki kondisi psikologi yang buruk. Hal ini dibuktikan dengan pemberontakannya yang telah dilakukan. Meskipun ia tahu bahwa berhubungan seks bebas dan penyalahgunaan obat-obatan terlarang yang menyebabkan sifilis, tetapi dia masih mencoba untuk menggunakan itu. pemberontakan lain yang telah Osvald dilakukan adalah ketika ibunya melarang dia untuk menikah Regina yang sebenarnya saudara tirinya, Osvald bersikeras untuk menikah Regina karena dia mencintai Regina dan ia tidak pernah tahu bahwa Regina adalah saudara tirinya karena ibunya tidak pernah mengatakan kepada fakta-fakta yang terjadi di antara ayahnya dan ibu Regina.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Divergence the Princeton Economic History
    THE GREAT DIVERGENCE THE PRINCETON ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE WESTERN WORLD Joel Mokyr, Editor Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside, 1450–1815, by Philip T. Hoffman The Vanishing Irish: Households, Migration, and the Rural Economy in Ireland, 1850–1914, by Timothy W. Guinnane Black ’47 and Beyond: The Great Irish Famine in History, Economy, and Memory, by Cormac k Gráda The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy, by Kenneth Pomeranz THE GREAT DIVERGENCE CHINA, EUROPE, AND THE MAKING OF THE MODERN WORLD ECONOMY Kenneth Pomeranz PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON AND OXFORD COPYRIGHT 2000 BY PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PUBLISHED BY PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS, 41 WILLIAM STREET, PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY 08540 IN THE UNITED KINGDOM: PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS, 3 MARKET PLACE, WOODSTOCK, OXFORDSHIRE OX20 1SY ALL RIGHTS RESERVED LIBRARY OF CONGRESS CATALOGING-IN-PUBLICATION DATA POMERANZ, KENNETH THE GREAT DIVERGENCE : CHINA, EUROPE, AND THE MAKING OF THE MODERN WORLD ECONOMY / KENNETH POMERANZ. P. CM. — (THE PRINCETON ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE WESTERN WORLD) INCLUDES BIBLIOGRAPHICAL REFERENCES AND INDEX. ISBN 0-691-00543-5 (CL : ALK. PAPER) 1. EUROPE—ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—18TH CENTURY. 2. EUROPE—ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—19TH CENTURY. 3. CHINA— ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—1644–1912. 4. ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT—HISTORY. 5. COMPARATIVE ECONOMICS. I. TITLE. II. SERIES. HC240.P5965 2000 337—DC21 99-27681 THIS BOOK HAS BEEN COMPOSED IN TIMES ROMAN THE PAPER USED IN THIS PUBLICATION MEETS THE MINIMUM REQUIREMENTS OF ANSI/NISO Z39.48-1992 (R1997) (PERMANENCE OF PAPER) WWW.PUP.PRINCETON.EDU PRINTED IN THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 3579108642 Disclaimer: Some images in the original version of this book are not available for inclusion in the eBook.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tension Between Illusion and Reality in H. Ibsen's the Wild Duck
    Global Journal of HUMAN-SOCIAL SCIENCE: A Arts & Humanities - Psychology Volume 19 Issue 8 Version 1.0 Year 2019 Type: Double Blind Peer Reviewed International Research Journal Publisher: Global Journals Online ISSN: 2249-460x & Print ISSN: 0975-587X The Tension between Illusion and Reality in H. Ibsen’s The Wild Duck By Dr. Mahmoud Nayef Baroud Islamic University of Gaza Abstract- Much of contemporary criticism of Ibsen plays has examined one of two concerns: Ibsen and Feminism, or Ibsen as a realist and a pioneer of modern theatre and drama. Articles on the first matter are often critical of universalizing readings of Ibsen that would have the dramatist concerned with the ills of humanity; articles on the latter theme tend to rejoice Ibsen’s assumed anti-theatrical overcoming of melodrama. Both topics can be found in his masterpiece The Wild Duck which is more honoured and received well in the study more than the other plays. Like Hamlet, The Wild Duck can be interpreted by each one in his own image; one day it will be read as a tragedy or tragicomedy, the next as the harshest irony; parts of it are clumsy, in other parts are embedded old controversies of that time. So searching yet so delicate is the touch, that these flaws and notions seem in themselves to strengthen the play. In this work, Ibsen perfected his own special power to infuse the particular, dull, limited fact with a halo and a glory. This paper is an attempt to examine the tension between illusion and reality in the play.
    [Show full text]
  • Bubbles, Manias and Market Failures
    7 February 2019 Bubbles, Manias and Market Failures PROFESSOR D’MARIS COFFMAN transcribed by Mr Imad Uddin Ahmed Thank you all, it’s a great honour to be here. This is actually my second time lecturing in this hall. I was first here about 5 years ago in 2013 when I was talking about something else entirely. I’m thrilled to be back, and I would like to thank Michael Mainelli, who is not here, for in fact convincing me to do this for a second time. Tonight, I’ll talk about bubbles, manias and market failures and particularly about the unintended consequences of regulatory responses to these events. And I think when you begin talking about the subject, it’s almost imperative that you start with Tulipmania which is the paradigmatic early-modern financial crisis. Some of you may recognise this wonderful print from 1637/38 by Peter Nolpe which shows a fool’s cap in which people are playing a gambling game that was played in the inns near the flower markets. It was a kind of auction game, bit of a spread-betting game in which they bid up the price of tulips. And this print shows the devastation that Tulipmania was supposed to have caused to the morals and the economic welfare of the Dutch republic. Now most of when we actually see copies of this print, don’t see the copies from the 1636-37 but rather recycled copies from the 1720s in a much different context. We’ll talk in a moment about that context.
    [Show full text]
  • The Ethics of Wealth Creation
    The Ethics of Wealth Creation Contents Page Preface 3 Part 1 – Introduction 5 Part 2 – Rudiments of the market system 6 Part 3 – Today’s economy 9 Part 4 – A critique of market capitalism 11 Part 5 – Values and the current controversy 15 Part 6 – Conclusion 23 Appendix 25 Questions and Further Reading 29 1 Preface Our church has a good record for what it has had to say about wealth distribution over the years. It has pressed Governments for Overseas Aid to become a larger part of the Gross National Product and has continually made representation on behalf of the poor. The Mission Alongside the Poor Programme was partly to ensure we had our own priorities right at the same time as we were urging a fairer distribution from others. But you cannot distribute wealth unless you have it to distribute. It has to be created, and we do not seem to have paid as much attention to the methods of creating wealth as we might have done. There have been small groups doing excellent work on this both through the Division of Social Responsibility and the Luton Industrial College, but it is surely important that it develops into a more public debate in our church. Until very recent times we have seen the collapse of much of what was called the “Command Economy” of Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union. We have also seen our own Government easing away from a rigid monetarism because it seemed so uncaring, even though it remains committed, as do the Opposition Parties, to a Market Economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Howwas Ibsen's Modern Drama Possible?
    Journal of World Literature 1 (2016) 449–465 brill.com/jwl How Was Ibsen’s Modern Drama Possible? Narve Fulsås University of Tromsø—The Arctic University of Norway [email protected] Tore Rem University of Oslo [email protected] Abstract One of the major renewals in the history of drama is Henrik Ibsen’s “modern tragedy” of the 1880s and 1890s. Since Ibsen’s own time, this renewal has been seen as an achievement accomplished in spite, rather than because, of Ibsen’s Norwegian and Scandinavian contexts of origin. His origins have consistently been associated with provinciality, backwardness and restrictions to be overcome, and his European “exile” has been seen as the great liberating turning point of his career. We will, on the contrary, argue that throughout his career Ibsen belonged to Scandinavian literature and that his trajectory was fundamentally conditioned and shaped by what happened in the intersection between literature, culture and politics in Scandinavia. In particular, we highlight the continued association and closeness between literature and theatre, the contested language issue in Norway, the superimposition of literary and political cleavages and dynamics as well as the transitory stage of copyright. Keywords Ibsen – tragedy – printed drama – The Modern Breakthrough – Georg Brandes – national literature – copyright On several occasions, Franco Moretti has highlighted the reverse relation between the geography of the novel and the geography of “modern tragedy.” Ibsen, whom he holds to be the key figure in this respect, is seen as belonging “to a Scandinavian culture which had been virtually untouched by the novel,” © koninklijke brill nv, leiden, 2016 | doi: 10.1163/24056480-00104003 Downloaded from Brill.com09/26/2021 08:35:18AM via free access 450 fulsås and rem and as causing the most heated controversies exactly in the “great powers” of novelistic production, France and England (Moretti “Moment” 39).
    [Show full text]
  • Codes of Finance Engineering Derivatives in a Global Bank
    Codes of Finance Engineering Derivatives in a Global Bank Vincent Antonin Lepinay Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Sociology in the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY 2011 © 2011 Vincent Antonin Lepinay All rights reserved Abstract Codes of Finance Engineering Derivatives in a Global Bank Vincent Antonin Lepinay Codes of Finance is an ethnography of a global bank inventing new derivative products. It describes the multiple languages invented to describe and control these new products. It analyzes the recent discussions about financial derivatives and offers a new framework to understand financial innovation. Contents Acknowledgments Preface: Financial Innovation from within the Bank Prologue: A Day in a Trader’s Life Introduction: Accessing the Organization of the Bank and Asking Questions about It Part I. From Models to Books Chapter 1. Thinking Financially and Exploring the Code Chapter 2. Hedging and Speculating with Portfolios Part II. Topography of a Secret Experiment Chapter 3. The Room as a Market Chapter 4. The Memory of Banking Part III. Porous Banking: Clients and Investors in Search of Accounts Chapter 5. Selling Finance and the Promise of Contingency Chapter 6. The Costs of Price Chapter 7. Reverse Finance Conclusion: What Good Are Derivatives? Notes Bibliography i Acknowledgments Michel Callon and Bruno Latour generously read versions of this book. Its felicitous moments owe them much: in different styles, they have always been present, extending their supervision to a protective attention that nurtured a unique environment and great relationships. At the Centre de Sociologie de l’Innovation, other scholars also were helpful readers; Fabian Muniesa stands out as a great intellectual companion.
    [Show full text]
  • Columbia University, Master in Financial Engineering
    My Life as a Quant Student: Reflections on Studying Financial Engineering at Columbia University (Disclaimer: google Emanuel Derman) After finishing my bachelor’s studies at IES and MFF UK I decided to attend Master of Science in Financial Engineering program at Columbia University. As it was quite a journey, I’d like to share my experience and hopefully inspire someone to pursue their goals in the future. About the program The Financial Engineering program at Columbia is a cornerstone program of the Industrial Engineering and Operations Research department at the Fu Foundation School of Engineering and Applied Science. It is a 36 credits program (which basically means 12 subjects) and it runs from September to either May, August or the following December, depending on how fast you want to finish. Most students choose to finish in December as it gives them enough time to have summer internship. There are six mandatory courses in the first two semesters and students can take another six electives according to their interests and/or concentration. As part of the program you can choose to concentrate in either Finance and Economics, Asset Management, Derivatives, Computation and Programming and Trading Systems. Financial Engineering itself is a multidisciplinary field involving financial theory, the methods of engineering, the tools of mathematics and the practice of programming. If you want to inspect more about the program, you can find all the information here: http://ieor.columbia.edu/ms-financial-engineering If you are interested in quant programs in general, I would suggest to take a look at this forum: www.quantnet.com You can find there plenty of resources about quant programs, applications, schools, jobs, etc.
    [Show full text]
  • The Relationship Between Culture and Policy Has Long Been a Major Topic
    Abstract The er lationship between culture and policy has long been a major topic for media and cultural studies. With this issue, we hope to broaden the meaning of cultural policy, from policies that are explicitly regulating something we call the “cultural” (including media or traditional rituals or symbols) to include the practice of policy-making and the cultural legitimation of law and policy itself, regardless of the object or dimension of social life it regulates. The se says in this issue argue for (or at least accept) an understanding of policy as a cultural production representing certain ideological outlooks, and thus implicitly suggest that cultural policy studies should encompass a wide range of policies; at the same time, the essays are interested in the cultural mechanisms and means through which policies are promulgated and enforced - from think tanks to social media flak, from the global circulation of ideologies to the local practices of appropriation/resistance. Cover Page Footnote We also appreciate and thank the reviewers for this issue, whose close readings and detailed suggestions made the works presented here even stronger. Creative Commons License This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-Share Alike 4.0 License. This article is available in communication +1: http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cpo/vol6/iss1/1 Johnson Andrews et al.: Editorial Introduction Editorial Introduction The idea for this issue grew out of a panel at the 2016 Cultural Studies Association Conference. The relationship between culture and policy has long been a major topic for media and cultural studies, but we hoped to broaden the meaning of cultural policy, from policies that are explicitly regulating something we call the “cultural” (including media or traditional rituals or symbols) to include the practice of policy-making and the cultural legitimation of law and policy itself, regardless of the object or dimension of social life it regulates.
    [Show full text]
  • To Read an Excerpt from Claiming the Land
    CONTENTS S List of Illustrations / ix Preface / xi INTRODUCTION Fraser River Fever on the Pacific Slope of North America / 1 CHAPTER 1 Prophetic Patterns: The Search for a New El Dorado / 13 CHAPTER 2 The Fur Trade World / 36 CHAPTER 3 The Californian World / 62 CHAPTER 4 The British World / 107 CHAPTER 5 Fortunes Foretold: The Fraser River War / 144 CHAPTER 6 Mapping the New El Dorado / 187 CHAPTER 7 Inventing Canada from West to East / 213 CONCLUSION “The River Bears South” / 238 Acknowledgements / 247 Appendices / 249 Notes / 267 Bibliography / 351 About the Author / 393 Index / 395 PREFACE S As a fifth-generation British Columbian, I have always been fascinated by the stories of my ancestors who chased “the golden butterfly” to California in 1849. Then in 1858 — with news of rich gold discoveries on the Fraser River — they scrambled to be among the first arrivals in British Columbia, the New El Dorado of the north. To our family this was “British California,” part of a natural north-south world found west of the Rocky Mountains, with Vancouver Island the Gibraltar-like fortress of the North Pacific. Today, the descendants of our gold rush ancestors can be found throughout this larger Pacific Slope region of which this history is such a part. My early curiosity was significantly moved by these family tales of adventure, my great-great-great Uncle William having acted as fore- man on many of the well-known roadways of the colonial period: the Dewdney and Big Bend gold rush trails, and the most arduous section of the Cariboo Wagon Road that traversed and tunnelled through the infamous Black Canyon (confronted by Simon Fraser just a little over 50 years earlier).
    [Show full text]
  • Promise Beheld and the Limits of Place
    Promise Beheld and the Limits of Place A Historic Resource Study of Carlsbad Caverns and Guadalupe Mountains National Parks and the Surrounding Areas By Hal K. Rothman Daniel Holder, Research Associate National Park Service, Southwest Regional Office Series Number Acknowledgments This book would not be possible without the full cooperation of the men and women working for the National Park Service, starting with the superintendents of the two parks, Frank Deckert at Carlsbad Caverns National Park and Larry Henderson at Guadalupe Mountains National Park. One of the true joys of writing about the park system is meeting the professionals who interpret, protect and preserve the nation’s treasures. Just as important are the librarians, archivists and researchers who assisted us at libraries in several states. There are too many to mention individuals, so all we can say is thank you to all those people who guided us through the catalogs, pulled books and documents for us, and filed them back away after we left. One individual who deserves special mention is Jed Howard of Carlsbad, who provided local insight into the area’s national parks. Through his position with the Southeastern New Mexico Historical Society, he supplied many of the photographs in this book. We sincerely appreciate all of his help. And finally, this book is the product of many sacrifices on the part of our families. This book is dedicated to LauraLee and Lucille, who gave us the time to write it, and Talia, Brent, and Megan, who provide the reasons for writing. Hal Rothman Dan Holder September 1998 i Executive Summary Located on the great Permian Uplift, the Guadalupe Mountains and Carlsbad Caverns national parks area is rich in prehistory and history.
    [Show full text]