Frankfurt School – Working Paper Series Naturalizing Institutions

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Frankfurt School – Working Paper Series Naturalizing Institutions Frankfurt School – Working Paper Series No. 182 Naturalizing Institutions: Evolutionary Principles and Application on the Case of Money by Prof. Dr. Carsten Herrmann-Pillath November 2011 Sonnemannstr. 9 – 11 60314 Frankfurt an Main, Germany Phone: +49 (0) 69 154 008 0 Fax: +49 (0) 69 154 008 728 Internet: www.frankfurt-school.de Abstract In recent extensions of the Darwinian paradigm into economics, the replicator-interactor dual- ity looms large. I propose a strictly naturalistic approach to this duality in the context of the theory of institutions, which means that its use is seen as being always and necessarily de- pendent on identifying a physical realization. I introduce a general framework for the analysis of institutions, which synthesizes Searle’s and Aoki’s theories, especially with regard to the role of public representations (signs) in the coordination of actions, and the function of cogni- tive processes that underly rule-following as a behavioral disposition. This allows to conceive institutions as causal circuits that connect the population-level dynamics of interactions with cognitive phenomena on the individual level. Those cognitive phenomena ultimately root in neuronal structures. So, I draw on a critical restatement of the concept of the ‘meme’ by Aunger to propose a new conceptualization of the replicator in the context of institutions, namely, the replicator is a causal conjunction between signs and neuronal structures which undergirds the dispositions that generate rule-following actions. Signs, in turn, are outcomes of population-level interactions. I apply this framework on the case of money, analyzing the emotions that go along with the use of money, and presenting a stylized account of the emer- gence of money in terms of the naturalized Searle-Aoki model. In this view, money is a neu- ronally anchored metaphor for emotions relating with social exchange and reciprocity. Money as a meme is physically realized in a replicator which is a causal conjunction of money arte- facts and money emotions. Keywords: Generalized Darwinism; institutions; replicator/interactor; Searle; Aoki; natural- ism; memes; emotions; money JEL classification: B52; D02; D87; E40; Z1 ISSN: 14369753 Contact: Prof. Dr. Carsten Herrmann-Pillath Academic Director, East-West Centre for Business Studies and Cultural Science Frankfurt School of Finance and Management Sonnemannstraße 9-11 60314 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Email [email protected] This article was published in Frankfurt. Naturalizing Institutions: Evolutionary Principles and Application on the Case of Money Inhalt 1 Introducing naturalism into the evolutionary approach to institutions..................................4 2 Institutions, distributed cognition and neuromemes: Outline of a naturalistic approach to institutions............................................................................................................................10 2.1 Institutions and functions in evolutionary causal circuitry: Merging Searle’s and Aoki’s theories of institutions..............................................................................................11 2.2 Status functions and the neuronal theory of metaphor: Establishing the larger framework of Neuronal Darwinism.....................................................................................16 3 Darwinizing money..............................................................................................................25 3.1 The pivotal role of emotions in the naturalistic approach to institutions .................25 3.2 Money emotions.......................................................................................................27 3.3 Money, signal selection and the human instinct to social exchange ........................31 3.4 The emergence of money as the creation of a new metaphor ..................................35 4 Conclusion and outlook .......................................................................................................41 Frankfurt School of Finance & Management Working Paper No. 182 3 Naturalizing Institutions: Evolutionary Principles and Application on the Case of Money 1 Introducing naturalism into the evolutionary approach to institutions One of the major challenges in generalizing the theory of evolution is to include human cul- ture and institutions into the picture. In economics, this research agenda has been launched by Thorstein Veblen (1899) for the first time and was lost out of sight even in the so-called ‘Old Institutionalism’, after the cultural turn triggered by the strong impact of American pragma- tism. The co-evolution of human biology and culture received considerable attention in an- thropology and biology after sociobiology had attacked the foundations of the social sciences and humanities as independent research traditions. Meanwhile, different approaches to gene- culture evolution are at hand which avoid fully-fledged reductionism but also extend the evo- lutionary concepts into the realm of culture (e.g. Richerson and Boyd 2005; Jablonka and Lamb 2006). In economics, unified approaches are only back on the research agenda with the recent claims of a Universal Darwinism (Hodgson and Knudsen 2010). One fundamental conceptual problem in all these extensions is the question of ontology, in the specific sense of social ontology. The major ontological difference between old and new institutionalism in economics lies in the much richer social ontology of the former, especially in accepting institutions as ‘real’, i.e. as ‘facts’, whereas new institutionalisms mostly follow the standard assumption of methodological individualism in economics, which would only treat ‘individuals’ as ‘real’ units of larger social systems. For evolutionary approaches and Darwinism in particular, this applies as well, in the context of the tensions between claims of genetic reductionism and the possible role of alternative approaches which would highlight the role of higher-level units in evolution. I reduce these complexities to one question: Can we construct an extension of evolutionary theory that treats institutions as units of evolution? This question would lead to a number of other questions, which I just notice, but cannot pur- sue in this paper (for more, see Herrmann-Pillath 2010/11), such as: Could we possibly imag- ine an evolutionary theory in which human individuals emerge as a phenomenon at the inter- face of two different ontological levels of evolution, i.e. genetic and institutional? Can we analyze evolution in the context of human beings in terms of complex interactions of different ontological domains of evolution, i.e. biological, cultural, and even individual? In this paper, I present an argument in favour of treating institutions as ‘real’ and as units of evolution on an ontological level which is independent from the genetic level. As such, the Frankfurt School of Finance & Management 4 Working Paper No. 182 Naturalizing Institutions: Evolutionary Principles and Application on the Case of Money paper picks up a distinction which is currently seen as obsolete by the vast majority of re- searchers, namely the distinction between genes and memes, which was posited in one early universalization of Darwinism by Dawkins (1989). One reason is that defining the concept of the ‘meme’ faces the same difficulties as recent generalizations of another Dawkins concept, that underlies the notion of meme, i.e. the ‘replicator’ (Knudsen 2002; Hull and Wilkins 2005). This is the question of the physical realization of the replicator beyond chemical mechanisms such as genetics. I argue that this empirical question is in fact an ontological one, which implies that we can develop a number of principled ideas about the structure of reality that would also enable us to formulate hypotheses about the physical nature of replicators in the domain of institutions. I will put together different theoretical resources from different disciplines to offer my solu- tion to this quandary. There is one pivotal point that I make in following John Searle’s (1995, 2005, 2010) approach to social ontology. This is that institutions are a special kind of facts, namely observer-relative facts. Being facts, however, they are conceived in naturalistic terms, i.e. as having autonomous causal powers beyond the beliefs and attitudes of individuals who act in a certain institutional setting (Bhaskar 1989). The question is how we can empirically specify this status of institutions as facts. In answering this question, I go far beyond Searle’s approach. I wish to present a conceptual framework for the Darwinian analysis of institutions and present an application on one of the most important institutions of the economy, money. This framework builds on two ideas borrowed from the literature. The first starts out from Aunger’s (2002) theory of (neuro)memes. Aunger, too, posits that one of the intricate questions of the generalization of Darwinism is the distinction between replicators and interactors. Although it is possible to make sense of this distinction in purely information-theoretic terms (as in Hodgson and Knudsen 2010), this approach is methodol- ogically problematic because it implicitly gives up the naturalistic ontology underlying Dar- winism. In fact, the purely information-theoretic approach is a disguised Cartesian substance dualism of mind vs. matter which builds the universalization of the theory on the distinction between a material domain, where biology reigns, and an abstract
Recommended publications
  • Exchange Theory in Classical Sociology Thought John Hamlin Department of Sociology and Anthropology UMD
    Exchange Theory in Classical Sociology Thought John Hamlin Department of Sociology and Anthropology UMD Warshay, in The Current State of Sociological theory (1975), characterizes exchange theory as one of the “eight large theories.” Yet Heath (1971:91) informs us that the only agreement sociologists have concerning which particular theorists should be considered under this heading are, G.C. Homans, Social Behavior: Its Elementary Forms (1961) and P.M. Blau, Exchange an Power in Social Life (1964). The problem with concentrating on these specific works of Homans and Blau are that they result in a view of exchange theory as uniquely individualistic, totally ignoring collectivistic exchange theory. It is indeed interesting that very little of significance has been added to this approach in since Homans classic statement. Milan Zafirovski (2003) has provided a good summery of the updates of exchange theory. For the most part, the theory has changed very little. One reason collectivistic exchange theory is ignored in the United States stems from the fact that it is primarily found in European Anthropology. Another reason derives out of the focus given the examination of exchange theory. At times it is seen as an extension of or in contrast to, economic exchange al la Adam Smith. Or as a reaction of dominate theories in the U.S. during the 1950s and 1960s. Mulkay, for example, interprets Homans’ exchange theory as developing in reaction to the functionalist theories of Parsons and others (1971:3). Blau’s attempts at theory construction are perceived as an extension and further development of Homans’ theory (Mulkay 1971:3).
    [Show full text]
  • Generalized Exchange1
    Generalized Exchange1 Peter Bearman University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Generalized exchange, in which sections of a tribe exchange women in a cycle and thus guarantee social solidarity, was induced from models of the norms governing classi®catory kinship systems. A blockmodel analysis of one aboriginal tribe yields sections that serve as marriage classes in a generalized exchange system, though the norms that govern kinship would fail to manifest, if followed, a cycle for exchange. Generalized exchange systems emerge from inequali- ties exogenous to the kinship system, speci®cally gerontocracy. Mod- els of norms are weak predictors of actual exchange structures. Mod- els of relations yield insight into the etiology of systems that build social solidarity from social exchange. When I was in my mother's womb, social structure seemed a simple thing. (Gang of Four) INTRODUCTION This article focuses on identifying the conditions under which social soli- darity emerges from exchange relations. The empirical focus is on the observed behaviors of persons whose exchanges induce a stable social or- der. The setting (Groote Eylandt, an island off Australia), the persons (Aborigines), the language in which exchange is conducted (kinship), the relevant theoretical literature (classi®catory kinship theory), and the val- ues exchanged (women) are exotic for most sociologists. But many of the issues involvedÐthe relationship between normative orders governing action and actual behaviors, the identi®cation of micromechanisms that yield stable emergent structures, and the relationship between solidarity, exchange, and inequalityÐare central to problems we encounter in more familiar settings. 1 Harrison White, Richard Simpson, Sally Falk Moore, Eric Leifer, Charles Lindholm, Gerald Marwell, John Paul Boyd, Roger Gould, Peter Blau, Ron Breiger, Douglas White, and the AJS reviewers provided helpful advice on earlier drafts.
    [Show full text]
  • Between Exchange and Reciprocity: the Interplay of Institutions and Social Networks in the Russian Labor Market
    Between Exchange and Reciprocity: The Interplay of Institutions and Social Networks in the Russian Labor Market Valery Yakubovich Stanford University Chapter 7. Hiring as Reciprocity 7.1. Introduction If we limit the scope of possible allocation mechanism to redistribution and market exchange then the only implication of the key finding in the previous chapter, which is that dense networks decrease the probability of bargaining and alternative job opportunities for a worker, is negative. That is to say, dense personal networks circumvent market exchange. Workers embedded in such networks do not make any real choices and end up in the first job delivered by a close kin or friend. In fact, such behavior is reasonable and well documented. Workers do not choose among alternatives because working with acquaintances is a value in itself; it makes work more satisfying and nurtures trust and loyalty which both employers and employees highly appreciate. In this way, the social fabric resists the marketization of economic activities. At the same time, if we follow consistently the theoretical framework developed in Chapter 2, economic reciprocity comes up naturally as an alternative positive logic underlying hiring through dense social networks. In general, this claim looks trivial; probably, there are very few people who would disagree that mutual help is one of the backbones of social relations. However, equally few people try to dissect this phenomenon systematically in a real-life setting; it is usually buried in discussions of social networks which take the presence of reciprocity for granted. Untangling reciprocity from the complex web of emotions and motives which govern personal relationships appears to be a Sisyphean task, in particular, if it is handled with large-scale survey instruments.
    [Show full text]
  • Structural Anthropology by Claude Lévi-Strauss
    Structural Anthropology CLAUDE LÉVI-STRAUSS Structural Anthropology Translated from the French by Claire Jacobson and Brooke Grundfest Schoepf BASIC BOOKS, In c ., Publishers, New York COPYRIGHT © 1963 BY BASIC BOOKS, INC. LIBRARY OF CONGRESS CATALOG CARD NUMBER 63-17344 sb n : 465-08229-7 PRINTED IN THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 74 75 7<5 77 1098765432 May an inconstant disciple dedicate this book which appears in 1958, the year of Émile Durk- heim’s centenary, to the memory of the founder of Année Sociologique: that famed workshop where modem anthropology fashioned part of its tools and which we have abandoned, not so much out of disloyalty as out of the sad convic­ tion that the task would prove too much for us. Xpwrtov fKv πρωτιστα ytvoç. Author’s Preface to the French Edition I n a recent study, Jean Pouillon wrote a sentence w hich, with his permission, I shall cite at the beginning of this work, since it corresponds perfectly to all that I hoped to accomplish in the scientific realm, though often doubtful of having been successful: “ Lévi-Strauss is certainly not the first nor the only one to have emphasized the structural character of social phenomena, but his originality consists in taking that character seriously and in serenely deriving all the consequences from it.” * M y hopes would be ful­ filled if this book could induce other readers to share this judgment. One will find here a collection of seventeen of some one hun­ dred papers written during the past thirty years. A few have been lost; others can profitably remain in oblivion.
    [Show full text]
  • Generalized Exchange Orientation
    Generalized exchange orientation: conceptualization and scale development LSE Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/101478/ Version: Accepted Version Article: Yoshikawa, Katsuhhiko, Wu, Chia-Huei and Lee, Hyun-Jung (2020) Generalized exchange orientation: conceptualization and scale development. Journal of Applied Psychology, 105 (3). 294 - 311. ISSN 0021-9010 https://doi.org/10.1037/apl0000438 Reuse Items deposited in LSE Research Online are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved unless indicated otherwise. They may be downloaded and/or printed for private study, or other acts as permitted by national copyright laws. The publisher or other rights holders may allow further reproduction and re-use of the full text version. This is indicated by the licence information on the LSE Research Online record for the item. [email protected] https://eprints.lse.ac.uk/ GENERALIZED EXCHANGE ORIENTATION 1 Generalized Exchange Orientation: Conceptualization and Scale Development Katsuhiko Yoshikawa Antai College of Economics and Management Shanghai Jiao Tong University 1954 Hua Shan Road, Shanghai, People’s Republic of China +86 021 5230 1132 [email protected] Chia-Huei Wu Durham University Business School Durham University Mill Hill Lane, Durham DH1 3LB +44 019 334 5988 [email protected] Hyun-Jung Lee Department of Management London School of Economics and Political Science Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, United Kingdom +44 020 7955 7918 h.lee @lse.ac.uk This paper is accepted for publication in Journal of Applied Psychology GENERALIZED EXCHANGE ORIENTATION 2 Abstract We conceptualize generalized exchange orientation, and develop and validate a scale assessing individual orientations toward generalized exchange as well as reciprocal and negotiated exchange for offering a full set of measurements for social exchange orientation.
    [Show full text]
  • A Social Exchange Theory of Network Retention
    SPQ SNAPS Should I Stay or Should I Go? Reciprocity, Negotiation, and the Choice of Structurally Disadvantaged Actors to Remain in Networks Scott V. Savage and Zachary L. Sommer Abstract We consider how the two forms of direct exchange influence whether structurally disadvantaged actors choose to stay in the micro-structures that disadvantage them. We posit that a history of reciprocal, as opposed to negotiated, exchange should increase the likelihood of an exit opportunity resulting in disadvantaged actors defining themselves as members of a group rather than as unique individuals in a network, and that this should increase the likelihood of actors choosing to remain in reciprocal exchange networks. Findings from two laboratory experiments generally support our argument that for disadvantaged actors, psychological group formation mediates the relationship between exchange form and staying in networks. Keywords social exchange, self-categorization theory, network dynamics, group formation Why might someone remain committed to a romantic partnership when the possibility exists of finding a more meaningful relationship elsewhere? Similarly, why might people bypass alternative job opportunities and stay with the companies that exploit them? Questions like these motivate research on the stability of network exchange structures that privilege some actors and disadvantage others (e.g., Cook and Gillmore 1984; Leik 1992; Willer and Willer 2000; Dogan et al. 2009; Rand, Arbesman, and Christakis 2011). For the most part, this research has focused on how adding and/or deleting linkages to others in a network can improve or worsen one’s relative power. Willer and Willer (2002), for example, concluded that because adding links generally benefits those in low power positions, rational actors in low power positions should try to add linkages in an attempt to balance power in the network.
    [Show full text]
  • Accepted Manuscript, Trends in Cognitive Sciences
    Mere Membership Yarrow Dunham* Department of Psychology Yale University * Correspondence: [email protected] (Yarrow Dunham) Keywords: intergroup cognition; prejudice; minimal groups Accepted manuscript, Trends in Cognitive Sciences 1 Abstract Human social groups are central to social organization and pervasively impact interpersonal interactions. While immensely varied, all social groups can also be considered specific instantiations of a common and abstract ingroup-outgroup structure. How much of the power of human social groups stems from learned variation versus abstract commonality? I review evidence demonstrating that from early in development a wide range of intergroup phenomena, most prominently many ingroup biases, follow solely from simple membership in an abstract social collective. Such effects cannot be attributed to rich social learning and so: a) constrain theories seeking to explain or intervene on ingroup bias, and b) provide reason to think that our species is powerfully predisposed towards ingroup favoritism from early in development. 2 Centrality of the group and the prevalence of ingroup bias No account of human psychology would be complete without recognizing that other people are as central to our natural ecology as is the physical environment. In particular, social groups—collections of people united by commonality—form the backdrop against which human culture emerges in all its diversity. While many species recognize a small set of social groups such as sex, kin, and band [1,2], human social groupings are enigmatic in their variety. We not only accept but embrace, act upon, and structure social arrangements around a range of groups that on the face of it have almost nothing in common.
    [Show full text]
  • Cultural Investigation of Trust and Reciprocity in Social Exchange
    University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Operations, Information and Decisions Papers Wharton Faculty Research 7-2002 Swift Neighbors and Persistent Strangers: A Cross‐Cultural Investigation of Trust and Reciprocity in Social Exchange Nancy. R. Buchan Rachel Croson University of Pennsylvania Robyn. M. Dawes Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.upenn.edu/oid_papers Part of the Biology Commons, Civic and Community Engagement Commons, and the Other Sociology Commons Recommended Citation Buchan, N. R., Croson, R., & Dawes, R. M. (2002). Swift Neighbors and Persistent Strangers: A Cross‐Cultural Investigation of Trust and Reciprocity in Social Exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 108 (1), 168-206. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/344546 This paper is posted at ScholarlyCommons. https://repository.upenn.edu/oid_papers/246 For more information, please contact [email protected]. Swift Neighbors and Persistent Strangers: A Cross‐Cultural Investigation of Trust and Reciprocity in Social Exchange Abstract In four countries, levels of trust and reciprocity in direct-reciprocal exchange are compared with those in network-generalized exchanges among experimentally manipulated groups’ members (neighbors) or random experimental participants (strangers). Results show that cooperation decreases as social distance increases; and, that identical network-generalized exchanges generate different amounts of trusting behavior due solely to manipulated social identity between the actors. This study demonstrates the interaction of culture
    [Show full text]
  • Claude Lévi-Strauss—Anthropologist and Philosopher
    Edmund Leach Claude Lévi-Strauss— Anthropologist and Philosopher As with Darwin and Freud and many other famous men Claude Lévi-Strauss, Professor of Social Anthropology at the Collège de France, needs to be judged on two quite different levels. First we may ask: ‘What has he contributed to the particular scientific discipline in which he is a professional expert?’ and secondly: ‘What is the basis of his public celebrity?’ The treatment which is now being accorded to Lévi-Strauss’ work in French intellectual journals suggests that he should be looked upon as an original thinker of the first rank. He is beginning to be spoken of as a philosopher, the founder of ‘structuralism’, on a par with Sartre, the founder of existentialism. 1How should we judge him in this role? A fellow anthropologist like myself is not perhaps the best kind of person to answer this sort of question. I can make judgments about Lévi-Strauss’ skill as an analyst of ethnographic materials, but when it comes to his still embryonic but potentially much more grandiose reputation as a philosopher I am not only out of my depth but somewhat unsympathetic to his position. 12 In this 20th century, ‘idealist’ attitudes are not at all respectable and Lévi-Strauss, himself emphatically rejects any suggestion that his arguments must imply an idealist foundation. But this is awkward. The elements in Lévi-Strauss, thought which I find most interesting all seem to me to be idealist in tone; yet these are precisely the points at which Lévi-Strauss feels that I misunderstand his intentions.
    [Show full text]
  • Generalized Social Exchange and Its Relevance to New Era Workplace Relationships
    Katsuhiko Yoshikawa, Chia-Huei Wu, Hyun-Jung Lee Generalized social exchange and its relevance to new era workplace relationships Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Lee, Hyun-Jung and Yoshikawa, Katsuhiko and Wu, Chia-huei (2018) Generalized social exchange and its relevance to new era workplace relationships. Industrial and Organizational Psychology. ISSN 1754-9426 © 2018 Cambridge University Press This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/90155/ Available in LSE Research Online: August 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. GENERALIZED SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND ITS RELEVANCE 1 Generalized Social Exchange and Its Relevance to New Era Workplace Relationships Katsuhiko Yoshikawa Shanghai Jia Tong University Email: [email protected] Chia-Huei Wu University of Durham Email: [email protected] Hyun-Jung Lee London School of Economics Email: [email protected] *This commentary is accepted for publication in the Industrial and Organizational Psychology.
    [Show full text]
  • Anthropology, Family History, and the Concept of Strategy
    IRSH 47 (2002), pp. 423–452 DOI: 10.1017/S002085900200072X # 2002 Internationaal Instituut voor Sociale Geschiedenis Anthropology, Family History, and the Concept of Strategy Pier Paolo Viazzo and Katherine A. Lynch INTRODUCTION In this essay, we consider family history as a common field of substantive and theoretical interest shaped by contacts among several disciplines. These disciplines obviously include social history and population studies, but also – and rather prominently – social anthropology. One major component of the growth of family history has been the increasing amount of attention that historians pay to topics such as marriage, kinship, and the family, which have long been of central significance in the anthropological investigation of social structure. On the other hand, anthropologists have become aware of the serious limitations of synchronic, present-oriented field research, and most of them now probably agree that historical analysis is essential if they are to understand social and cultural processes. This realization has gradually changed many anthropologists from reluctant consumers of historical work into active and often quite enthusiastic producers.1 The fruitfulness of this rapprochement was perhaps best demonstrated as early as the 1970s by the advances made possible by the adoption in family history of the anthropological concept of developmental cycle of the domestic group. Although Chayanov’s work already foreshadowed this concept, it was independently formulated in 1949 by Meyer Fortes, one of the leading British social anthropologists, and further refined by Fortes himself and by his colleagues and pupils in Cambridge in the 1950s.2 When its potentialities were revealed to the nascent field of family history by the works of anthropologists like Goody and Hammel and, 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Generalized Exchange Within Investment Accelerators Brad Bernthal Colorado Law
    Marquette Law Review Volume 100 Article 9 Issue 3 Spring 2017 Who Needs Contracts? Generalized Exchange Within Investment Accelerators Brad Bernthal Colorado Law Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.marquette.edu/mulr Part of the Contracts Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Repository Citation Brad Bernthal, Who Needs Contracts? Generalized Exchange Within Investment Accelerators, 100 Marq. L. Rev. 997 (2017). Available at: http://scholarship.law.marquette.edu/mulr/vol100/iss3/9 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at Marquette Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Marquette Law Review by an authorized editor of Marquette Law Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 39285-mqt_100-3 Sheet No. 168 Side A 06/19/2017 09:53:44 7BERNTHAL-FINAL.DOCX (DO NOT DELETE) 6/12/17 2:03 PM WHO NEEDS CONTRACTS? GENERALIZED EXCHANGE WITHIN INVESTMENT ACCELERATORS BRAD BERNTHAL* Abstract This Article investigates why an expert volunteers on behalf of startups that participate in a novel type of small venture capital (“VC”) fund known as a mentor-driven investment accelerator (“MDIA”). A MDIA organizes a pool of seasoned individuals – called “mentors” – to help new companies. An obvi- ous organizational strategy would be to contract with mentors. Mentors in- stead voluntarily assist. Legal studies of norm-based exchanges do not explain what this Article calls the “mentorship conundrum”—i.e., the puzzling moti- vation of a mentor to volunteer within otherwise for-profit environments. This Article is the first to bridge the insights of generalized exchange theory with law and entrepreneurship.
    [Show full text]