Documents.Worldbank.Org

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Documents.Worldbank.Org WPS5580 Policy Research Working Paper 5580 Public Disclosure Authorized On Multidimensional Indices of Poverty Martin Ravallion Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized The World Bank Public Disclosure Authorized Development Research Group Director’s office February 2011 Policy Research Working Paper 5580 Abstract There has been a growing interest in what have come for, should it be done in the space of “attainments,” to be termed “multidimensional indices of poverty.” using prices when appropriate, or that of “deprivations,” Advocates for these new indices correctly point out that using weights set by the analyst? The paper argues that command over market goods is not all that matters to the goal for future poverty monitoring efforts should be peoples’ well-being, and that other factors need to be to develop a credible set of multiple indices, spanning considered when quantifying the extent of poverty and the dimensions of poverty most relevant to a specific informing policy making for fighting poverty. However, setting, rather than a single multidimensional index. the author argues that there are two poorly understood When weights are needed, they shouldn’t be set solely by issues in assessing these indices. First, does one believe an analyst measuring poverty. Rather, they should be, as that any single index can ever be a sufficient statistic for much as possible, consistent with well-informed choices poverty assessments? Second, when aggregation is called made by poor people. This paper is a product of the Director’s office, Development Research Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at [email protected]. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team On Multidimensional Indices of Poverty Martin Ravallion1 1 The author is Director of the Development Research Group, World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC, 20433, USA. For helpful discussions on this topic and comments on this paper the author is grateful to Sabina Alkire, Kathleen Beegle, Gabriel Demombynes, Quy-Toan Do, Jean-Yves Duclos, Francisco Ferreira, James Foster, Garance Genicot, Stephan Klasen, Peter Lanjouw, Michael Lokshin, Nora Lustig, Branko Milanovic, Mead Over, Dominique van de Walle, Roy Van der Weide and Hassan Zaman. These are the views of the author, and need not reflect those of the World Bank or any affiliated organization. 1. Introduction There has been a growing interest in what have come to be termed “multidimensional indices of poverty.” There are many issues one might discuss related to these indices, including the choice of the functional form, the choice of poverty lines, and the robustness of the implied rankings to those choices.2 However, these issues are essentially generic to all poverty measures (though with some more technical differences). The present discussion will focus instead on how multidimensional indices differ from more familiar approaches. This is a logical starting point for potential users trying to understand and apply these new measures; to assess their contribution we must first understand how they differ from standard measures. Multidimensionality per se cannot be what distinguishes a multidimensional index of poverty (MIP). There is an obvious sense in which almost every poverty measure found in practice is “multidimensional.” Indeed, to my knowledge, the only truly one-dimensional indices are the rice-based measures once found in some countries in Asia, but no longer used.3 The main measures now found in practice use a composite measure of consumption or income with many components, relying heavily on market prices in aggregation. Nor does the difference lie in the recognition of the fact that poverty is not just about low consumption of market commodities. It is widely agreed that there are also important non-market goods relevant to welfare, such as access to public services. Poverty is multidimensional. However, that does not imply that one needs a MIP. It is one thing to recognize that something is missing from a given measure, and needs to be considered, and quite another to create a single composite index. The more common approach is to collect multiple indicators of the various dimensions of poverty, invariably including an index of command over market goods, but also including indicators for health and education attainments and access to services. A well-known example is the United Nations’ Millennium Development Goals, which span multiple 2 For example, in the case of poverty measurement, where there is almost always a degree of arbitrariness about the poverty line, best practice tests the robustness of poverty comparisons to the choices made, invoking the theory of stochastic dominance. For expositions in the standard “unidimensional” case see Atkinson (1987) and Ravallion (1994). Duclos et al. (2006) provide dominance tests for “multidimensional poverty.” 3 For example, the government of Vietnam measured poverty by rice consumption prior to the early 1990s. This was in part at least because of high inflation in the 1980s, and inadequate price indices. More standard multi-commodity poverty measures emerged soon after. 2 dimensions, but without forming a single composite index. At the country level, the World Bank’s Poverty Assessments and the Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers of individual governments have typically drawn on multiple indicators (though naturally with varying emphasis), without forming a single composite index.4 This paper argues that the real differences between the recent measures that are called “multidimensional” and standard approaches lie elsewhere. The first difference is in whether one believes that a single index of poverty could ever be a sufficient statistic, or whether multiple indices are required, each measuring different things using the best data available for that task— presenting us with a “large and eclectic dashboard” (Stiglitz et al., 2009, p.62). A second difference is also evident on closer inspection, namely how the analyst chooses to collapse multiple dimensions into one, recognizing that some degree of aggregation will probably be called for even in the “dashboard” approach. In elaborating these two differences I will illustrate the arguments using the most well- developed and broadly applied MIP to date, namely that developed by Alkire and Santos (2010a), which is a special case of the class of measures proposed by Alkire and Foster (2007). The following section discusses the Alkire-Santos index, and whether it can be considered sufficient for measuring poverty and informing policy making. Section 3 turns to the issue of how one can go about aggregating across multiple dimensions when a degree of aggregation is called for to reduce the dimensionality. Section 4 concludes. 2. Can we measure poverty adequately with any single index? There are countless possibilities for forming composite indices by some form of essentially ad hoc aggregation—giving what I term elsewhere “mashup indices” (Ravallion, 2010a). The issue in this section is not how this can be done but whether it is useful to do so. One can easily imagine situations in which one would not want a mashup index. Imagine you go for your annual medical checkup. Your doctor does all the usual tests, but tells you that she will base her assessment solely on a single composite index—rescaling and averaging all the test 4 The Bank’s Poverty Assessments (significant analytic reports covering virtually all developing countries) typically cover education, health and nutrition and access to infrastructure, in addition to income poverty. 3 results. You would be well advised to get a new doctor!5 Or imagine that a new car comes on the market that collapses all those dials on the dashboard into just one composite index, on which you are supposed to decide what to do (slow down or get fuel). You would surely not buy this car! Essentially the same point applies to the task of prioritizing policies for fighting poverty in a given country (or other geographic area). We will naturally want to look at the country’s attainments in various dimensions, rather than focusing on its performance with respect to a single composite index. Should we be focus on promoting job creation (say) or better health and education services? Such an approach does not deny that poverty is “multidimensional.” Rather it says that forming a single (uni-dimensional) index may not be particularly useful for sound development policy making. Consider now the MIP developed by Alkire and Santos (2010a) for the 2010 Human Development Report (UNDP, 2010). They choose 10 variables for their MIP under the same three headings—health, education and living standards—as the UNDP’s Human Development Index (HDI). There are two variables for health (malnutrition, and child mortality), two for education (years of schooling and school enrolment), and six for deprivation in “living standards” (namely cooking with wood, charcoal or dung; not having a conventional toilet; lack of easy access to safe drinking water; no electricity; dirt, sand or dung flooring and not owning at least one of a radio, TV, telephone, bike or car).
Recommended publications
  • Comprehensive Vulnerability Monitoring Exercise Multidimensional Poverty Index
    Comprehensive Vulnerability Monitoring Exercise Multidimensional Poverty Index May 2019 Background: What is a Multidimensional Poverty Index? Poverty is usually measured based on the money-metric concept which considers someone as poor if they do not have enough economic resources. This implies that the indicators used to measure poverty are only related to prices and expenditures on goods and services (UNICEF, 2014). However, since the 1990s, multiple methods have been developed to measure poverty. In this paper the focus will be on the Alkire-Foster (AF) Method, developed by Sabina Alkire and James Foster at Oxford Poverty & Human Development Initiative (OPHI). The AF method is a flexible technique for measuring poverty or well- being, (OPHI, 2015). It can incorporate different dimensions and indicators to create measures specific to particular contexts. Within the AF method, there are several steps required to construct a Multidimensional Poverty Index (MPI) which vary based on the exact methodology used for the creation of the MPI: Choice of purpose for the index (monitor, target, etc) Choice of Unit of Analysis (individual, household etc) Choice of Dimensions Choice of Variables/Indicator(s) for dimensions Choice of Poverty Lines / thresholds for each indicator/dimension Choice of Weights for indicators within dimensions Choice of Weights across dimensions Within the Comprehensive Vulnerability Monitoring Exercise (CVME), WFP Turkey has developed an MPI following the AF method, which is used to assess the poverty levels of different groups of households. The CVME data was collected from March to August 2018. It includes responses from 1,301 households; the sampling methodology ensures the data is representative of all refugees living in Turkey.
    [Show full text]
  • Dimensional and Distributional Contributions to Multidimensional Poverty
    Oxford Poverty & Human Development Initiative (OPHI) Oxford Department of International Development Queen Elizabeth House (QEH), University of Oxford OPHI WORKING PAPER NO. 100 Dimensional and Distributional Contributions to Multidimensional Poverty Sabina Alkire* and James Foster** March 2016 Abstract The adjusted headcount ratio M0 of Alkire and Foster (2011a) is increasingly being adopted by countries and international organizations to measure poverty. Three properties are largely responsible for its growing use: Subgroup Decomposability, by which an assessment of subgroup contributions to overall poverty can be made, facilitating regional analysis and targeting; Dimensional Breakdown, by which an assessment of dimensional contributions to overall poverty can be made after the poor have been identified, facilitating coordination; and Ordinality, which ensures that the method can be used in cases where variables only have ordinal meaning. Following Sen (1976), a natural question to ask is whether sensitivity to inequality among the poor can be incorporated into this multidimensional framework. We propose a Dimensional Transfer axiom that applies to multidimensional poverty measures and specifies conditions under which poverty must fall as inequality among the poor decreases. An intuitive transformation is defined to obtain multidimensional measures with desired properties from unidimensional FGT measures having analogous properties; in particular, Dimensional Transfer follows from the standard Transfer axiom for # unidimensional measures. A version of the unidimensional measures yields the M-gamma class !" containing the multidimensional headcount ratio for γ = 0, the adjusted headcount ratio M0 for γ = 1, and a squared count measure for γ = 2, satisfying Dimensional Transfer. Other examples show the ease with which measures can be constructed that satisfy Subgroup Decomposability, Ordinality, and Dimensional Transfer.
    [Show full text]
  • Person Equivalent Headcount Measures of Poverty
    IZA DP No. 9402 Person Equivalent Headcount Measures of Poverty Tony Castleman James Foster Stephen C. Smith October 2015 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Person Equivalent Headcount Measures of Poverty Tony Castleman Catholic Relief Services and IIEP, George Washington University James Foster George Washington University Stephen C. Smith George Washington University and IZA Discussion Paper No. 9402 October 2015 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character.
    [Show full text]
  • Breaking out of the Poverty Trap
    CHAPTER THREE Breaking Out of the Poverty Trap Lindsay Coates and Scott MacMillan Introduction In 2018, one of us visited a rural village in Bangladesh to speak to participants in a “graduation program,” a term used to describe programs designed to break the poverty trap with a boost of multiple, sequenced interventions. When we asked one woman what the program had changed for her, she brought out a piece of paper inviting her to a village event. Before she went through the program, her neighbors barely knew she existed, she said. Now she was a member of the com- munity, invited to people’s homes and weddings. One hears echoes of this senti- ment from participants in similar graduation programs worldwide. Such stories illustrate just one of the many cruel aspects of ultra- poverty: those afflicted by it tend to be invisible— to neighbors, distant policymakers, and nearly everyone in between. The ultra- poor need to stop being invisible to policymakers. We need to pay closer attention to the poorest and the unique set of challenges they face, for without a better understanding of the lived reality of ultra- poverty, we will fail to live up to the promise of “leaving no one behind.” Without programs tai- lored for people in these circumstances, the extreme poverty rate will become increasingly hard to budge. We are already starting to see this reflected in global poverty data. For decades, the global extreme poverty rate, defined as the portion of humanity living below the equivalent of $1.90 per day, fell rapidly, from 36 percent in 1990 to 10 percent in 2015.
    [Show full text]
  • Andrea Lopez-Luzuriaga Education Research Interests Publications In
    Andrea Lopez-Luzuriaga George Washington University Email: afl[email protected] Department of Economics Website: aflopezluzuriaga.github.io/website/ 2115 G St NW Suite 340, Washington, DC 20052 Phone: +1.202.656.0235 Education Ph.D. in Economics, George Washington University 2020 (expected) M.A. in Economics, George Washington University 2016 M.A. in Public Administration and International Development, Harvard University 2014 M.A. in Economics and Development, Facultad Latinoamericana Ciencias Sociales 2012 B.A. in Economics, Pontificia Universidad Catolica del Ecuador 2008 Research Interests Public Economics, Development Economics, Applied Microeconomics. Publications in Refereed Journals “Compliance spillovers across taxes: The role of penalties and detection” with Carlos Scartascini. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 164, p518-534, Aug 2019 “Pollution or crime: The effect of driving restrictions on criminal activity” with Paul E. Carrillo and Arun S. Malik. Journal of Public Economics 164, p50-69, Aug 2018 Working Papers “Less is more? Limits to itemized deductions and tax evasion” (Job Market Paper) “Financial literacy among high school students in the United States: Evidence from the 2012 Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA)” with Annamaria Lusardi Works In Progress “Willing but unable to pay? The role of gender in tax compliance” with Carlos Scartascini “When the taxman shutters the store next door” “Measuring income tax evasion using electronic billing” with Angelica Trujillo and Nestor Villacres Awards and Scholarships Graduate Research Assistantship, George Washington University 2016-2017 Graduate Teaching Assistantship, George Washington University 2014-2016 Harvard Kennedy School HIID Scholarship (Full Tuition) 2012-2014 SENACYT Excellence Scholarship 2012-2014 Scholarship, Facultad Latinoamericana de Ciencias Sociales 2009-2011 Cultural Scholarship, Pontificia Universidad Catolica del Ecuador 2007-2008 1 Teaching George Washington University.
    [Show full text]
  • External Capabilities1
    OPHI WORKING PAPER SERIES External Capabilities1 James E. Foster, Vanderbilt University2 Christopher Handy, Cornell University3 The capability approach of Amartya Sen evaluates well-being in terms of an individual’s achievements and abilities to function. The traditional view of capabilities is that they are discernable as part of an individual’s own set of characteristics, or as part of a package of socially provided services. We argue that individuals also have access to a broad array of capabilities through their family, friends and other persons with whom they have relationships. We introduce the concept of “external capabilities”, which are defined as those abilities to function that are conferred by direct connection or relationship with another person. Several examples are provided, and we distinguish between our new concept and other existing notions of capabilities originating in groups. The perspective of external capabilities can be especially valuable in formulating development policies or understanding how existing policies work. As an illustration of this, we show how information and communications technologies (ICT) can enhance development by augmenting external capabilities. Key Words: Capabilities, well-being, freedom, development, social networks, ICT January 2008 1This paper is based on the honors thesis of Chris Handy, written under the direction of James Foster at Vanderbilt University. We are grateful to Sabina Alkire, Kaushik Basu, and John Siegfried for helpful comments, and to the Vanderbilt Undergraduate Summer Research Program for financial support. 2Department of Economics, Box 1611 Station B, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN 37235, USA +1 615 322 2192, [email protected] and Oxford Poverty & Human Development Initiative, University of Oxford.
    [Show full text]
  • Download in Reusable Format for Free So Sites
    WPS8693 Policy Research Working Paper 8693 Public Disclosure Authorized Measuring the Statistical Capacity of Nations Grant J. Cameron Public Disclosure Authorized Hai-Anh H. Dang Mustafa Dinc James Foster Michael M. Lokshin Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Development Economics Development Data Group January 2019 Policy Research Working Paper 8693 Abstract The international development community has used the paper reviews measurement methodologies, posits desired World Bank’s Statistical Capacity Index since its incep- attributes, and presents theoretical and empirical frame- tion in 2004. The Sustainable Development Goals create works for the new, improved index to monitor progress in new challenges for national statistical systems to produce the statistical capacity of nations. The paper illustrates the high-quality and internationally comparable data. This properties of the updated index with global data from 2016. This paper is a product of the Development Data Group, Development Economics. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://www.worldbank.org/research. The authors may be contacted at [email protected] and [email protected]. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors.
    [Show full text]
  • Beyond Aid: the Integration of Sustainable Development in A
    JANUARY 2016 1616 Rhode Island Avenue NW Washington, DC 20036 202-887-0200 | www.csis.org Lanham • Boulder • New York • London 4501 Forbes Boulevard Lanham, MD 20706 301- 459- 3366 | www.rowman.com Cover photo: Ambika Adhikari/USAID Beyond Aid The Integration of Sustainable Development in a Coherent International Agenda A Report of the CSIS Project on Prosperity and Development ISBN 978-1-4422-5906-5 Ë|xHSLEOCy259065z AUTHOR v*:+:!:+:! James Michel Blank Beyond Aid The Integration of Sustainable Development in a Coherent International Agenda AUTHOR James Michel A Report of the CSIS Proj ect on Prosperity and Development January 2016 Lanham • Boulder • New York • London 594-64135_ch00_3P.indd 1 1/9/16 8:25 AM About CSIS For over 50 years, the Center for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS) has worked to develop solutions to the world’s greatest policy challenges. ­Today, CSIS scholars are providing strategic insights and bipartisan policy solutions to help decisionmakers chart a course toward a better world. CSIS is a nonprofit organ ization headquartered in Washington, D.C. The Center’s 220 full- time staff and large network of affiliated scholars conduct research and analy sis and develop policy initiatives that look into the future and anticipate change. Founded at the height of the Cold War by David M. Abshire and Admiral Arleigh Burke, CSIS was dedicated to finding ways to sustain American prominence and prosperity as a force for good in the world. Since 1962, CSIS has become one of the world’s preeminent international institutions focused on defense and security; regional stability; and transnational challenges ranging from energy and climate to global health and economic integration.
    [Show full text]
  • Leaving Poverty Behind – Using Multidimensional Poverty Measures to Tackle Poverty and Achieve the Sdgs in Asia and the Pacific
    A Guidance Note Empowered lives. Resilient nations. Leaving poverty behind – Using multidimensional poverty measures to tackle poverty and achieve the SDGs in Asia and the Pacific A Guidance Note Empowered lives. Resilient nations. Leaving poverty behind – Using multidimensional poverty measures to tackle poverty and achieve the SDGs in Asia and the Pacific A Guidance Note Leaving poverty behind: using multidimensional poverty measures to tackle poverty and achieve the SDGs in Asia and the Pacific This is the second in a series of two reports prepared to support UNDP country offices in Asia and the Pacific in their efforts to end poverty in all its forms, everywhere. The first report takes stock of the calculation and use of multidimensional poverty measures in countries of the region. This accompanying guidance note backs the practical application of multidimensional poverty measures as a policy tool. ISBN: 978-974-680-433-2 Author: Bishwa Nath Tiwari, UNDP Bangkok Regional Hub Editing: Gretchen Luchsinger Design: www.minhdesigns.com Published by: United Nations Development Programme Bangkok Regional Hub 3rd Floor, United Nations Service Building Rajdamnern Nok Avenue, Bangkok 10200, Thailand. Email: [email protected] Tel: +66 (0)2 304-9100 Fax: +66 (0)2 280-2700 Copyright © UNDP Bangkok Regional Hub, 2020 Disclaimer: The views expressed in this publication are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the United Nations, including the United Nations Development Programme or UN Member States. Reproduction and dissemination of material in this report for educational or other non-commercial purposes are authorized without prior written permission from the copyright holder, provided that the source is fully acknowledged.
    [Show full text]
  • Benchmarking the Effective Literacy Rate
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Lee, Travis Working Paper Benchmarking the effective literacy rate CAE Working Paper, No. 07-13 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for Analytical Economics (CAE), Cornell University Suggested Citation: Lee, Travis (2007) : Benchmarking the effective literacy rate, CAE Working Paper, No. 07-13, Cornell University, Center for Analytical Economics (CAE), Ithaca, NY This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/70458 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu ISSN 1936-5098 CAE Working Paper #07-13 Benchmarking the Effective Literacy Rate by Travis Lee July 2007 . BENCHMARKING THE EFFECTIVE LITERACY RATE TRAVIS LEE Abstract. By now the importance of literacy in the process of development is widely accepted.
    [Show full text]
  • The Samaritan's Curse Kaushik Basu
    November 20, 2020 The Samaritan’s Curse Moral Individuals and Immoral Groups Kaushik Basu Department of Economics Uris Hall Cornell University Ithaca, New York 14853 Email: [email protected] Abstract In this paper, I revisit the question of how and in what sense can individuals comprising a group be held responsible for morally reprehensible behavior by that group. The question is tackled by posing a counterfactual: what would happen if selfish individuals became moral creatures? A game called the Samaritan’s Curse is developed, which sheds light on the dilemma of group moral responsibility, and raises new questions concerning ‘conferred morality’ and self-fulfilling morals, and also forces us to question some implicit assumptions of game-theory. Key words: Samaritan’s Curse, moral responsibility, conferred morality, Nash equilibrium JEL Numbers: D62, D64, K13 Acknowledgement This paper began as an informal talk in the Philosophy Department of Cornell University, and developed as versions of it were later presented at a game theory conference in IIT Bombay, a conference in honor of Jorgen Weibull at the Stockholm School of Economics, and the Moral Psychology Brown Bag at Cornell. I also benefited from my seminar and discussions as part of the Hamburg Lecures in Law and Economics. I would like to thank Richard Ashley, Abhijit Banerjee, Chris Barrett, Karna Basu, Larry Blume, Matthew Braham, Tad Brennan, Utteeyo Dasgupta, Frederik Van De Putte, Avinash Dixit, Robert Duval, James Foster, Meir Friedenberg, Nicole Hassoun, Karla Hoff, Rachana Kamtekar, Peter Katzenstein, Theodore Korzukhin, Rajlakshmi Mallik, Ajit Mishra, Diganta Mukherjee, Derk Pereboom, Ariel Rubinstein, Sudipta Sarangi, Eric Van Damme and Joseph Zeira.
    [Show full text]
  • Lunch Keynote – Professor James Foster, the Institute for International Economic Policy, Elliott School of International Affairs, the George Washington University
    Lunch Keynote – Professor James Foster, The Institute for International Economic Policy, Elliott School of International Affairs, The George Washington University Making Meaningful Numbers I design measures, I don’t focus on implementation, but a lot of people who interact with me are focused on it and try to make sure it’s designed correctly. An axiom is simply precise representation of policy. It’s a policy that describes what you think should be measured and, more importantly, what shouldn’t be measured. Things I have been looking at: Literacy – where you take into account the local access to literacy given to you by someone in your household, even if you’re not o Polarization and the spread of incomes… Inequality and self-reported health – fair/poor/etc. Size Spread Base of distribution MPI is an example of that… First case study: income base measures Sen brought home the fact that poverty was not being considered at a deep enough or nuanced enough level and has two stages o 1. Identification . Who is poor? o 2. Aggregation . How poor are people? use something that reflects depth of poverty o Introduced axiomatic structure which helped in putting that forward… o You could decrease poverty in the South and increase in the North and overall it could rise! . Put together a measure that did not have that problem. o FTT indices… . Include poverty-gap measure (depth as well as frequency) . Squared gap measure Multidimensional Poverty Everyone says it is multidimensional o World Bank Development Report emphasized this point and showed how hard the measurement was; they didn’t include measures, just discussions of each dimension What does this mean? Contract to unidimensional.
    [Show full text]