<<

Dialogues in http://dhg.sagepub.com/

Geography, nature, and the question of development Eric Sheppard Dialogues in 2011 1: 46 DOI: 10.1177/2043820610386334

The online version of this article can be found at: http://dhg.sagepub.com/content/1/1/46

Published by:

http://www.sagepublications.com

Additional services and information for Dialogues in Human Geography can be found at:

Email Alerts: http://dhg.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts

Subscriptions: http://dhg.sagepub.com/subscriptions

Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav

Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav

Citations: http://dhg.sagepub.com/content/1/1/46.refs.html

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Article

Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1) 46–75 ª The Author(s) 2011 Geography, nature, and the Reprints and permission: sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav question of development DOI: 10.1177/2043820610386334 dhg.sagepub.com

Eric Sheppard University of Minnesota, USA

Abstract During the last decade, geography has gained new salience as a development factor in the public imagination and policy realms, through the work of scholars located outside the discipline. Jared Diamond and have popularized the idea that a physical geographic backcloth, first nature, profoundly shapes the conditions of possibility for global economic prosperity or poverty, and . Geographical have built microfoundational accounts of second nature: how uneven emerge on a uniform biophysical backcloth. ‘New’ development economists, now profoundly critical of neoliberal , argue for both Keynesian and Hayekian alternatives. Notwithstanding their differences, these communities of scholarship share a sociospatial ontology that underwrites a stageist, teleological conception of , to be made possible by globalizing capitalism. A geographical, relational/dialectical conception of the relationship between the , space/time and socionature, within a broadly political economic conception of societal change, creates space for multiple development trajectories and livelihood assemblages, deconstructing the global North as the natural locus of definitions of the good life and expertise about what constitutes development.

Keywords assemblage, contestation, development, , geography, nature, positionality, spatialities

Introduction 1990s, which rejected a proposal by economists to study geography and economic development. Any Geography continues to struggle to control its own Schadenfreude at telling economists how geography destiny. When presenting a lecture on -led should be done was short-lived. Within months, this globalization at the Center for Advanced Study in approach was featured in discussions the Behavioral Sciences in 2005, to the most chal- on development (cf. Henderson, 1999). In August lenging and engaged interdisciplinary social science 2006, the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City and humanities audience I have faced, I thought hosted a symposium on economists’ economic geo- long and hard about how to convey what geogra- graphy addressed by US Federal Reserve chairman phers do. It became clear in the questions posed dur- ing and after the talk, however, that the audience already had a strong conception of Geography, namely that publicized by Diamond and Sachs, and Corresponding author: Department of Geography, University of Minnesota, Minnesota, wanted me to explain how my work related to theirs. MN 55455, USA I recalled my on a funding panel in the late Email: [email protected]

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 47

Ben Bernanke. Now, drawing as much on Paul than we are willing to admit? Do such Krugman as Sachs, the World Bank’s World Devel- shared political criticisms imply convergent views opment Report 2009, subtitled ‘reshaping economic on geography and development? geography’, signals that global policy-makers are In exploring these questions, I critically assess highlighting this relationship (World Bank, 2008). the narratives of geography and economy promoted Krugman himself was awarded the 2008 Nobel by these authors, and the development imaginaries Medal in Economics, in part for his formulations that these entail. The answers to these questions are of how geography, trade and development are of much more than Ivory Tower, ‘how many angels interrelated. can dance on the head of a pin’, import. At the center As these experiences illustrate, a tension has of these authors’ narratives is the notion that nature emerged between conceptions of geography and and space create unequal conditions of possibility development circulating in society at large, and the for economic prosperity, accounting to a significant dominant forms of knowledge produced within and extent for the historical persistence of global circulating through academic human geography. inequality before and since the era of European The emerging consensus that geography matters to colonialism. As the anthropologist Deborah global development has been shaped by the Gewertz has put it, such arguments imply that arguments of Krugman, Diamond and Sachs. The ‘[t]he haves are not to be blamed for the condition publicity that they have brought to geography has of the have-nots’.1 They also reinforce a conception, been avidly exploited within parts of the discipline, held by western thinkers and policy-makers at least including plenary lectures as ‘honorary geogra- since colonial days, of development as a teleological phers’ at AAG meetings. Nevertheless, these argu- sequence of stages, pioneered by wealthy capitalist ments have been repeatedly criticized by leading nations, that all nations should pursue. Human human geographers for their dated conceptions of geographic theory has articulated very different geography, for regressing toward what has been geographical narratives, entailing very different described as spatial fetishism and environmental views on development. , and for endorsing a Rostowian trium- The paper is organized as follows. First, I analyze phal vision of the stages of capitalist development Sachs’ and Diamond’s geographical imaginary. (Rostow, 1960). As I argue below, such criticisms I conclude that their reliance on first nature, when are grounded within the relational and dialectical examined through the lens of economic and sociospatial ontology framing much of contempo- biological theories of development, leans toward a rary economic geography. This raises the prospect, teleological account of economic development in once again, that external beliefs about why geogra- which ‘geography’ disrupts the otherwise flattening phy matters not only diverge from but also are in playing field of globalizing capitalism. Second, danger of overwhelming geographers’ own beliefs. I turn to the geographical imaginary mobilized by Yet the issues are more complicated than a sim- geographical economists’ conceptions of geography ple disagreement about what Geography is and how and development. This departs from Sachs by focus- society should develop. Diamond and Sachs have ing on second rather than first nature. I conclude that become prominent in discussions about how to here, too, a fixed geographical backcloth is intervene to make the world more sustainable. presumed, on the basis of which spatial economic Beyond this, Sachs, and prominent US ‘new’ devel- patterns are deduced (as equilibrium outcomes opment economists Joseph Stiglitz, Dani Rodrik and from spatial ): a backcloth generally William Easterly, offer many of the same criticisms characterized by isotropic configurations, given of neoliberal globalization (notwithstanding their transportation costs, and fixed national boundaries earlier complicity with neoliberal interventions) that (Garretsen and Martin, 2010). A number of circulate in human geography, development studies, geographical economists have pointed to ways in and alternative globalization social movements. Are which space undermines the putative benefits mainstream economists more like critical economic of spatial competition, and to the problems of

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 48 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1) triumphalism. Nevertheless, methodological contemporary geographic theory is deeply shaped territorialism favors the conceptualization of terri- by, as well as shaping, knowledge production tories as subject to a common development trajec- beyond the discipline. Indeed this paper assays an tory, whereas connectivities between places are engagement that transcends any such boundaries. presumed, on balance and after appropriate inter- I highlight the differences between geographical vention, to be mutually beneficial and functional for and economic imaginaries of nature, geography and advancement along this trajectory. development as a first step toward what I hope will Third, I examine the ‘new’ development econo- be engagement between different perspectives crit- mists, whose criticisms of this most recent era of ical of neoliberal globalization. Engaged pluralism neoliberal globalization are strongly reminiscent first requires clearing space for different ‘local epis- of those popular in critical human geography. From temologies’ to be taken seriously (cf. Longino, this shared critical stance, these economists bifur- 2002); which is what I attempt, here, through a form cate into two subgroups; one advocating for various of strategic essentialism that highlights epistemo- kinds of Keynesian interventions, with the other tak- logical differences. ing the Hayekian neoliberal position that states and the development industry need to conform with ‘First’ nature, geography and market principles. Notwithstanding such disagree- ments, I find that there is a shared belief in univer- development sally applicable economic laws, in the capacity of As is well known, Diamond and Sachs argue that globalizing capitalism to bring prosperity to all, and nature, taken to include both biophysical processes in a teleological development path. Indeed, I argue and the morphology of the landscape, has been that Keynes and Hayek share this view, for all their overlooked as a factor that has long shaped the policy disagreements. conditions of possibility for human development, Fourth, I compare and contrast the sociospatial and thereby global inequality. In so doing, they ontologies underlying the conceptualizations of stress geography as ‘first nature’: as a pre-existing and Anglophone geographi- uneven geographical backcloth.2 Writing as an cal , and the imaginaries of devel- evolutionary biologist, in Guns, Germs and Steel opment that these mobilize. Economics, I contend, Diamond provides what he terms a short of is characterized by methodological territorialism, the world since 11,000 BC (Diamond, 1997). He bottom-up scalar hierarchies and ubiquitous eco- asserts that the biophysical environment and the nomic laws, underwriting a teleological, stageist morphology of continents are the ultimate explana- conception of capitalist development. Geographical tion of agricultural , technological political economy has developed a very different, dynamism and other crucial aspects of societal dialectical and relational, ontology, implying a multi- change (a set of proximate causes that includes faceted and indeterminist conception of livelihood capitalism, and science). Two features assemblages – one for which the term development of the biophysical environment receive particular hardly suffices. I conclude by reflecting on the prob- attention: differences between the tropical and lem of engaging between alternative livelihood temperate latitudes in the biophysical capacity to assemblages and development imaginaries. produce an annual agricultural surplus; and the Before proceeding, however, I wish to dispel one shape and directional orientation of continents. possible misconception. It is not my intent to Societal innovations and human movements are suggest that the intellectual community should be argued to diffuse more readily East–West, within divided into geographers and non-geographers, with the same latitudinal zone, than North–South (for a only the former deemed qualified to produce critique, see Blaut, 1999). He concludes that the adequate geographical knowledge. Such boundary- contemporary prosperity of the global North is making is, of course, inimical to the health of any rooted in historical environmental inequalities, discipline, and it is demonstrably the case that stressing this environmentalist explanation as an

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 49 alternative to Eurasian-centric human . development institutions and states must intervene Like critical geographers, then, Diamond finds the in order to level an economic playing field perma- latter problematic because they explain underdeve- nently distorted by Geography.3 lopment as due to the cultural idiosyncrasies and Diamond and Sachs have each been accused of inadequacies of non-Eurasian societies. the heinous crime of environmental determinism This causal framework is reprised in Collapse, (Blaut, 1999; Peet, 2006), since nature plays the albeit with a different purpose (Diamond, 2005). significant causal role in their accounts, as society’s Collapse is a Malthusian morality play: a warning eminence grise. Nevertheless, apprised of their to his US audience that our lifestyles are unsustain- criminality, each has vehemently pled innocence. able. Examining societies around the world, he Admitting to some initial naivety ‘that [Collapse] argues that the occasional collapse and disappear- would just be about environmental damage’, ance of human societies is shaped by a combination Diamond argues that he has learned otherwise. of five factors: societal response to environmental Exhibit A is his comparative study of Haiti and the problems; damage that inadvertently inflict , where ‘environmental differ- on their biophysical environment; climate change; ences [are] the smaller part of the explanation. Most hostile neighbors; and friendly trading partners. ... has instead to do with differences between the Of these five, only the first ‘always proves two peoples’ (Diamond, 2005: 11, 333). Sachs seeks significant’ (p. 11) – although Diamond admits to to ‘banish the bogeyman of geographical determin- a selectivity in his choice of cases, excluding soci- ism, the false accusation that ... geographical etal collapses (e.g. the Soviet Union and Carthage) disadvantage ... single handedly and irrevocably where the environment does not matter. In this determines the economic outcome of nations’ view, collapse (whether on a thousand (Sachs, 2005: 58). years ago, in the Yucatan 500 years ago, or Rwanda Neither Sachs nor Diamond accepts the a decade ago) is triggered when societies exceed racialized version of environmental determinism their natural limits. of Ellsworth Huntingdon and Ellen Churchill Jeffrey Sachs takes a different approach, while Semple, popular a century ago: the view, once used coming to similar conclusions. Utilizing fine- to justify colonial rule and the white man’s burden, resolution geospatial data measuring population that climate determines human nature (Hart, 2002). density, and (GDP) per Each believes passionately in the equal capacity of capita and per square mile worldwide, Sachs and his all humans. Diamond’s respect for the indigenous colleagues compute a regression, in which tropical- knowledge and skills of inhabitants of ity and distance from navigable water are statisti- (a place he knows well from his ornithological field- cally significant predictors of levels and rates of work) matches Blaut’s respect for peasant farmers growth of GDP (and population density) (Gallup in Latin America (cf. Blaut, 1987; Diamond, et al., 1999). The regression specification is derived 2005), and Sachs is deeply opposed to those who in reduced form from a standard neoclassical would blame the poor for their own impoverish- single-sector model in dynamic ment. Further, both Sachs and Diamond accept that equilibrium, augmented with possibilities of humans transform the non-human world (making increasing returns, in which differences in transport them environmental probabilists rather than deter- costs (measured by distance to navigable water) and minists). Advocating a less exploitative relationship lower productivity (measured by tropicality) are with nature is the central theme of Collapse, and hypothesized to reduce equilibrium growth rates, Sachs has argued that many real problems still faced ceteris paribus. In Ricardo Hausmann’s felicitous in societies located near the equator (disease vec- term, countries are ‘prisoners of [their] geography’ tors, pests and vermin, poor transportation, limited (Hausmann, 2001). Differences in natural endow- agricultural innovation) are a result of inappropriate ments prevent rates of economic growth from global socio-economic priorities rather than envir- equalizing across places, with the implication that onmentally caused. He notes, for example, how drug

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 50 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1) companies have failed to address tropical diseases Thinking about development because lifestyle drugs for well-heeled customers in The different disciplinary backgrounds that Sachs theglobalNortharemoreprofitable(Sachs,2001). and Diamond bring to these debates bring with them Yet their accounts of global development still distinct disciplinary conceptions of development. rely on the idea of first nature: a conceptualization In Biology, debates about evolutionary theory have of geography as an exogenous backcloth (so slow- revolved around two contrasting conceptions. moving, by comparison to the dynamics of societal On the one hand are teleological accounts of evolu- change, that it can be taken as fixed). In this view, tion, placing humans at the top of an evolutionary geography is a set of natural features that are ‘reso- trajectory of ever increasing complexity.6 On the lutely external to society’ (Castree and Braun, 1998: other hand, Stephen Jay Gould has argued that the 7; cf. Krugman, 1993). ‘Geography is as exogenous fossil record undermines such teleological accounts: a determinant as an can ever hope to get’ that chance, rather than complexity, shapes (Rodrik et al., 2004: 134). For the general equili- – that humans’ dominance of the globe brium theory that mainstream development econo- is not a symptom of their evolutionary superiority mists aspire to, exogenous variables are as rare as – hypothesizing that simple bacteria are evolutiona- hens’ teeth, so this has generated a minor industry rily more successful than complex humans (Gould, of econometric studies seeking to estimate the statis- 1989) (for a related argument, see Davis, 1996). tical effect of tropicality and distance to navigable In short, evolution has no built-in directionality – water on mean rates of GDP growth; largely at the although emergent directionality through international scale, but also at the subnational scale co-evolutionary interactions is possible or even (focusing on access to water, cf. De´murger et al., likely. While the debate about whether evolutionary 2002; Sachs et al., 2002). This has been dominated fitness is correlated with trends toward complexity by a debate about whether exogenous ‘geography’ continues in Biology (cf. Conway-Morris, 2006), dominates institutions as the determinant of eco- current consensus is that evolution is characterized nomic growth.4 Acemoglu et al. argue that institu- by many branching paths, rather than a teleological tions dominate ‘geography’: that the eventual sequence of stages. Gould likens evolution to a prosperity of more temperate colonies by compari- labyrinthine pathway, akin to a ‘bush’ of multiple, son to tropical colonies, notwithstanding lower co-existing variation, rather than a teleological urbanization and population density in the former, sequence (Gould, 1996).7 is explained by the white settlers who dominated In this alternative view, development is the (and eliminated) indigenous populations and unfolding of the potential immanent in an organ- brought the right (European) institutions with them ism’s genes, shaped by the environment in which (Acemoglu et al., 2002). In short, European super- it finds itself (necessarily including interspecies iority is the key – an argument that is fraught with, interaction). Whereas teleological accounts of evo- presumably unwitting, stereotypes about Europeans lution stress a predictable, common development civilizing the backward tropics.5 Rodrik et al. trajectory, with less fit species giving way to fitter (2004) and Easterly and Levine (2003) reach a sim- ones, these alternative non-teleological accounts are ilar conclusion. By contrast, Faye et al. (2004), more akin to the dynamics associated with complex- Nordhaus (2006), Olsson and Hibbs (2005), and ity theory, with its path dependencies, bifurcations Presbitero (2006) conclude that ‘geography’ trumps and unpredictabilities. Richard Norgaard pinpoints institutions. Przeworski (2004a, 2004b) is com- an important difference between these two biological pelled by neither position, arguing simply that narratives of development: endogeneity matters, implying that it is logically fallacious to seek one or the other principal cause (he implicitly rejects ‘geography’ as the cause With more emphasis on coevolutionary processes, because he takes it to be exogenous, but without the directionality of evolution is no longer deter- accepting the alternative of institutions). mined by a steady advance toward perfect fitness

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 51

with an unchanging environment. Species are no (Smith, 1776: I.2.1–2). Diamond’s resonance with longer thought to get better and better at anything. mainstream economic thinking about development And ... changes in the physical environment are reflects a long tradition of interchange between the important explanatory variables in evolutionary two disciplines. Darwin’s own formulation of evo- history. (Norgaard, 1994: 84) lution as being driven by competition, ‘survival of the fittest’, was influenced by his extensive reading Recognizing that species co-evolve with their in British political economy (particularly Malthus environment is central, then, to non-teleological and Smith), and these trajectories of thought remain conceptualizations of evolution. connected (Hodgson, 2002).8 Interestingly, this is not the position favored by In Economics, teleological accounts of develop- Diamond in his world historical narratives. Guns, ment, as a common series of stages that societies Germs and Steel treats nature as a relatively fixed must go through, dominate the mainstream canon.9 forcing factor, rather than as co-evolving with soci- Rostow’s thesis that all societies follow the USA ety. ‘Geography’ thus is largely ‘out there’, driven through a series of stages from ‘traditional’ to by its own biophysical logics, with global patterns ‘beyond mass ’ capitalism, his self- whose pace of change can be neglected within the styled ‘non communist manifesto’, remains influen- timeframe of human life. Notwithstanding his con- tial (Rostow, 1960). Indeed Sachs explicitly adopts cern, in Collapse, with human-induced environmen- Rostow’s position, and its implication that US-style tal change, his comparative place-based case studies capitalism is the best available model for economic are deployed to illustrate what are presented as a development, with the implication that other ways common Malthusian environmental dilemma. of organizing economic systems are inferior and While he values the variegated indigenous practices should be abandoned. Sachs notes that he has that he encountered during his fieldwork in New learned from the immense difficulties that ensued Guinea, his analysis falls back on a Eurocentric from implementing this imaginary through ‘shock imaginary of development when it comes to therapy’ for transitioning state socialism into capit- places with which he is less familiar (Diamond, alism in the former Soviet Union. He now argues 2005).4 that local conditions can result in very different tra- Indeed, as detailed below, Diamond follows jectories from those predicted by free market mainstream economists in emphasizing economic proponents. Thus the ‘prison of geography’ requires interactions (i.e. trade) as a positive relationship supranational intervention into markets, so that the (‘friendly trade partners’) enabling development for global playing field can be leveled and competitive all places, whereas negative relationships are equa- capitalism can realize its potential as the ubiquitous with the political (‘hostile neighbors’). When he tide of development that will lift all boats. Neverthe- conceptualizes conditions of possibility as rooted in less, the laws of mainstream economics are invoked place, arguing that success or failure is a choice that to justify a Rostowian imaginary, with shock societies make, he also adopts the methodological therapy remaining a valuable tool in the right territorialism and voluntarism common in econom- circumstances, including China (Sachs, 2005: 160). ics (Diamond, 2005). Deploying this geographical Notably absent from both accounts is any atten- imaginary has consequences. It directs attention tion to enduring consequences stemming from the away from societal causes of uneven development. geo-historical legacies of colonialism. Both Sachs When nature is conceived of as external and gov- and Diamond recognize the negative effects of erned by natural laws, it is easy to romanticize it colonialism at the time, but its ongoing significance as something pure that humans sully at their peril, as a cause of contemporary impoverishment in the and to see humans as constrained by immutable laws global South is brushed aside. It is, at best, an inter- – not least of which are those of ‘human nature’, as vening factor between natural geographies and in ’s invocation of ‘a certain propensity development. As noted above, in this view, the divi- in human nature ... to truck, barter, and exchange’ sion of the world into colonizers and the colonized

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 52 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1) was itself in good part a consequence of the natural economists’ statistical models are mis-specified; disadvantages of tropical and distant places. Coloni- they fail to account for such reciprocal causal effects alism may have enhanced contemporary impover- by treating ‘geography’ as exogenous. ishment across Asia, Africa and Latin America, By contrast, geographical economists see but is not an ‘ultimate cause’ (Acemoglu et al., themselves as incorporating second nature into their 2002, 2003). It is seen as having little relevance in analysis. Krugman’s paradigmatic neoclassical a contemporary world of sovereign nation states, explanations of why spatial economic structures accorded the autonomy, and responsibility, to make emerge from a homogeneous geographical back- choices that will determine their residents’ well-being cloth, paralleling the morphogenetic accounts of (methodological nationalism). 1960s on an isotropic plain, are framed in terms of second nature (Krugman, 10 ‘Second’ nature, space and 1993). This is by far the more popular approach among mainstream economists, who see Sachs as geographical economics tackling the much easier and more mundane task Recognizing that an important factor shaping how of explaining why geographical inequality begets development is imagined in Diamond’s and Sachs’ economic inequality. Utilizing Dixit-Stiglitz accounts of geography and global development is mathematical models of their reliance on first nature, it is important to superimposed on a ‘flat’ world with no locational interrogate the consequences of abandoning this advantage (e.g. two locations as either end of a line, inevitably somewhat determinist account. Second or points equally separated around a circle), nature, the view that nature co-evolves with, Krugman and his followers show that there are partially constituted through and inseparable from, plausible equilibrium outcomes in which some societal change (hybrid, or more-than-human places specialize as industrial clusters whereas geographies; cf. Whatmore, 2001), is a far more others remain agricultural. These have been adequate conception of nature-society relations. described as north–south models by analogy to a Thus it can be readily pointed out that Sachs’ (once) industrialized global North versus an agricul- principal surrogates of ‘geographical’ disadvantage, tural global South (Krugman and Venables, 1995). the geographical distribution of malaria (for The only uncertainty is which places become indus- tropicality) and access to navigable waters, are trial: several equilibrium outcomes are possible, themselves continually shaped by societal change depending on small initial differences.11 (the elimination of malaria from subtropical To pre´cis what is a finely tuned argument, of the first world; the colonial of industrial agglomeration happens when transport transportation systems, navigational improvements costs are neither too high nor too low. This theoretical and national boundaries). Gaza’s temperate and deduction has been applied directly to explaining the coastal location has hardly been a source of long of global development, as prosperity. transport costs fall (Baldwin, 2006; Crafts and This does not mean, of course, that biophysical Venables, 2001; Venables, 2006). According to this processes are irrelevant: temperate climates are narrative, when transport costs were high, there was better suited for producing grain-based annual no specialization. As they fell in the 17th and 18th agricultural surpluses, third world environmental centuries, during ‘globalization 1’, specialization health problems like malaria receive inadequate became the stable equilibrium outcome. Richard attention, and tropical conditions pose very specific Baldwin puts it this way: ‘as history would have it, the conditions that local agricultural knowledge and North won at the South’s expense’ (Baldwin, 2006: practices, and cultural norms, have found ways to 13). In this formulation, either might have address (Sheppard et al., 2009a). Nevertheless, ‘won’ during this period, but for some historical recognizing more-than-human geographies implies, contingencies shaping the equilibrium outcome in technical terms, that Sachs’ and others (Sachs and Diamond stress ‘geography’). Now, after

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 53 a ‘counter-globalization’ interregnum between 1929 Economic Geography), and stresses the importance and 1945, ‘globalization 2’ has unleashed a combina- of communications infrastructure development at tion of further falling communications costs and the national and subnational scales, confining spatially disaggregated global production networks, consideration of Sachs’ discussion to the economic with transport costs falling to the point where regional costs of a landlocked nation (Sheppard et al., specialization no longer pays. This is why, it is 2009b). Landlockedness has become a widely argued, we are currently experiencing the (re)indus- discussed determinant of national economic trialization of the global South, presumably until stagnation, to which have been added such geo- industrialization diffuses to all regions as the new graphic measures as population size and ethnic equilibrium outcome. diversity (a proxy for intranational divisiveness) This neoclassical theorization of geography, (Collier, 2006, 2007; Sachs, 2005; Venables, morphogenesis and global development has been 2006). Yet these, allegedly geographical, character- repeatedly critiqued within economic geography istics again are treated as largely exogenous. Thus, (e.g. Martin, 1998; Plummer and Sheppard, 2006; Austrian and Swiss success as landlocked countries Sheppard, 2000), and there is no space here to detail is attributed to their proximity to wealthy European these arguments. Yet two criticisms are vital. First, markets, part of a given global geography of notwithstanding the apparent historicism of the inequality – whose emergence at the expense of above account, these models presume that the world African colonies (landlocked, small and ethnically always approximates a market-clearing general diverse by dint of European boundary drawing) is equilibrium. (Even though these equilibria are not problematized. In discussions aimed at trans- notionally stable, computational experiments forming global economic geographies, it seems at suggest that the internal logic breaks down when best paradoxical to make so much of a geography that Krugman’s model is in disequilibrium, making its is exogenous to the theories utilized to promulgate equilibria unachievable; Fowler, 2007, 2010.) such transformations. Second, while the geography of economic activities Although geographical economists differ from may be endogenous, its geographical backcloth is Sachs as to how ‘geography’ matters, they share two not. The exogenous backcloth of a flattened positions: that the geographic backcloth can be hypothetical world and exogenous transportation treated as exogenous to the economy; and that state costs is inconsistent with contemporary economic actions may be necessary to redress the market geographical theory (Sheppard, 2000). Further, imperfections associated with geography. Sachs once the sociospatial dialectic is acknowledged, the argues for global interventions to compensate for capitalist space economy is characterized by the ‘bad geography’ and level the playing field. The unpredictable dynamical complexity and instability World Bank revisits old-style spatial Keynesian described by Norgaard, rather than by equilibrium regional planning to redress spatial inequalities (Plummer and Sheppard, 2006). (Sheppard and Leitner, 2010). Venables argues that Contemporary mainstream - ‘geography’ implies that ‘trade is not necessarily a oriented accounts of geography, globalization and force for of incomes’ (Venables, 2006: development are dominated by Krugmanesque ‘sec- 74), an argument even acceptable to the inveterate ond nature’ accounts, rather than Sachs’ invocation free trader Douglas Irwin (2006). of first nature. (In his entry for the New Palgrave Indeed, even as geographers castigate mainstream Encyclopedia of Economics, Sachs persists in trying economists for endorsing , something to persuade his colleagues to integrate agglomera- quite different is underway in Economics. In his New tion economics with ‘’; Sachs York Times columns, , condemned by and McCord, 2008.) Most economists seem as leery critical geographers as the founding figure of neoclas- of environmental determinism as geographers have sical geographical economics, has become one of been. Thus the 2009 World Development Report the USA’s most widely read passionate critics of not invokes second nature in its subtitle (Reshaping only Bush-era neoliberalism, but also Obama-era

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 54 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1) economic centrism. Beyond this, even this limited States and Vanuatu are equivalent. This presumes that inclusion of geography into as soon as new nation states come into existence, as undermines the viability of claims that the invisible when Yugoslavia broke up, each becomes a coherent hand of competitive capitalism is socially beneficial. territorial economy. Theoretically, national econo- As trade theorists and foreign direct mies are assumed to be reducible to aggregate theorists have begun adding a spatial dimension to production functions, enabling them to be analyzed their theories (in the form of transport costs and using the same neoclassical tools as for individual place-based characteristics), it has become increas- firms, even though it is known that the marginal pro- ingly common that their models do not result in the ductivity claims associated with such functions are as welfare maximizing mutual benefits commonly logically fragile as the transformation problem associ- associated with unrestricted trade and foreign direct ated with Marx’s labor theory of (Harcourt, investment. For trade theory, general equilibrium 1972; Sheppard and Barnes, 1990; Sraffa, 1960). deviates from the welfare-maximizing optimum, Methodologically, there is a strong tendency including scenarios where some regions and toward place-based explanations in mainstream countries lose as a result of trade (cf. Behrens et al., : accounting for the performance 2007; Tharakan and Thisse, 2002; Venables and of each territorial economy in terms of a series of Lima˜o, 2002). For foreign direct investment, James presumed causal attributes of that territory. The Markusen develops complex computable general regression specifications utilized in the debates equilibrium models in which countries lose as a result about geography and development, summarized of the ability of firms to engage in unrestricted foreign above, are of exactly this kind. This has been the direct investment (Markusen, 2002). Ottaviano and case even for much mainstream statistical analysis Thisse (2004) derive what they call the ‘spatial of subnational regional , at least until impossibility theorem’, that neoclassical competitive quite recently, even though economists readily equilibria cannot exist in a capitalist space economy. concede that these are not autonomous territorial Recognition that ‘geography’ matters, even in this economies (Fingleton, 2000). rather static exogenous form, does at least have the Such methodological territorialism is highly merit of undermining conventional economic justifi- problematic, as quantitative geographers long have cations for market triumphalism.12 pointed out, because it does not account for the many ways in which territorial economies are Geographical economics and the question of interconnected and affect one another (not to mention interscalar interrelations). It also has the development specific consequence of reinforcing Rostowian Whereas geographical economists have become more stageist conceptions of development. By definition, cautious about market-based outcomes, this has not such aspatial statistical regressions presume that all catalyzed any significant rethinking of teleological units of analysis are of the same kind. The task is to developmentalism. This stems from how territory and account for how a single measure of performance, distance are treated within this framework. such as gross national income (GNI), varies across First, national political borders are taken as (in this case) national territories, by identifying exogenous to economic theory, and nation states are other attributes of those places that ‘cause’ these commonly presumed to be natural territorial performance differences (causality being defined economic units – a position that sociospatial as a significant partial correlation, backed up by a theorists have extensively critiqued as the national theory that offers its readers a plausible rationale territorial trap or methodological nationalism that predicts such a correspondence). The other (Agnew, 1994; Brenner, 2004). It would be redun- attributes are regressed on a trend line measuring dant to rehearse such critiques in detail here, but performance – which amounts to nothing more than some aspects are important to underline. For these a sequential ranking of national economies in terms units of analysis, size does not matter: the United of this measure, from worst to best (typically, the

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 55

West). This, then, represents national economic for broad audiences, recently have sought to performance in terms of a single trajectory along distance themselves from neoliberal globalization which countries are aligned. For example, the (post) in ways that resonate with critiques in geography Washington Consensus has too often sought to and development studies.14 Their prominence in browbeat states into adopting US and UK forms of global centers of mainstream economic expertise governance. In such a place-based imaginary, and the broad circulation of their arguments is shap- territorial-scale interventions (i.e. national govern- ing both public discourses and policy-making ance reform) become the key to catching up. norms.15 These writers’ interventions have been cat- Second, notwithstanding predilections toward alyzed by the broad impact of counter-globalization methodological territorialism, geographical macro- social movements. Recognizing that neoliberal economists now take into account intercountry globalization has reinforced economic inequality, distance-related effects. Discussions of landlocked they are concerned that influential contestations of countries, for example, note that their performance neoliberal globalization may result in a rejection will depend on a variety of attributes of the neigh- of capitalist globalization tout court – which they boring countries through which their imports and feel would amount to throwing the baby out with the exports must be shipped to access the sea (Collier, bathwater. In short, believing in the overall benefits 2006; Venables, 2006). Such interdependencies of capitalist globalization, pointing to the Great have not been systematically incorporated into Depression as an era of both counter-globalization economists’ theories or empirical estimates of the and global economic crisis, they seek interventions relation between geography and development (but that can redress its unintended negative side effects. see, for example, Yamamoto, 2008). The principal These interventions have been discussed in detail exception is economists’ recent reinvention of an elsewhere (Sheppard and Leitner, 2010). Here, old geographers’ trick, the gravity model, to predict I focus on their implications for discourses about trade flows (Evenett and Keller, 2002; Johnston, trade and development. 1976; Ma´rquez-Ramos et al., 2007; Mitchener and Jeffrey Sachs’ claim that countries are prisoners Weidenmier, 2008). Again, geography is an exogen- of their geography seemingly challenges the free ous backcloth; distance is given, a cost of doing trade doctrine, perhaps explaining why it has not business. Treating distance simply as a transactions received a warm reception among mainstream econ- cost – a barrier to the efficient operation of neoclas- omists. A core theoretical claim of mainstream sical markets – implies that reductions in such costs , dating back to David must level the economic playing field, creating a Ricardo, is the opposite: enables every flatter world in which efficient markets can more place to take advantage of its geographical peculia- readily realize their putative benefits. Shorter dis- rities, whatever these might be, by identifying, and tances reduce transactions costs, benefitting all part- specializing on the basis of, the comparative ners.13 The more general presumption, also adopted advantage associated with its place-based character- by Diamond, is that unfettered spatial economic istics.16 Yet a close reading of Sachs reveals that he interdependencies (trade, foreign direct investment, remains as supportive as ever of free trade (Sachs, portfolio capital flows, migration), reducing transac- 2005): His concern is that not all differences in tions costs, benefit all the people and places that they comparative advantage are equal. Sachs’ claim that connect. It follows that lower transport costs can only the exigencies of geography require spatial accelerate the progress of ‘backward’ territories along redistribution from wealthy to poor places is a the path to development. global Keynesian agenda – with his Earth Institute’s Millennium Villages initiative acting as a proving ground for this argument. ‘New’ development economists As noted above, the development economist As noted above, a group of prominent US Dani Rodrik disagrees with Sachs about geography, mainstream ‘new’ development economists, writing arguing that the ultimate place-based determinant of

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 56 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1) national economic performance is institutions. He World Bank (1997–2000) reinforced this belief. has been battling Sachs over the question of institu- He has castigated the multilateral post-Bretton tions versus ‘geography’ via dueling econometric Woods institutions for their lack of transparency: for specifications (Rodrik et al., 2004). Yet he shares making decisions behind closed doors, even as they Sachs’ concerns about neoliberal globalization. The penalized third world governments for the same lack son of a Turkish businessman who benefitted of transparency (Stiglitz, 2002). He observes that greatly from the policies of import substituting power inequities in the institutions governing the industrialization that came to be vilified under neo- world economy hurt the global South, urging reform liberalism, Rodrik highlights three problems associ- on the WTO to redress this. He argues against ated with globalization (Rodrik, 1997): workers are structural adjustment and biopiracy, and for policies disadvantaged by free trade and investment due to promoting global equity, forgiving national debts and their low mobility; there is a failure to acknowledge stimulating in the global South. and accept national cultural preferences and norms Countries with ‘a proven track record’ (p. 242) should (e.g. reluctance to purchase commodities produced be given financial aid and the freedom to decide how under exploitive labor relations or in environmen- to use it, instead of being told what to do. tally harmful ways); and globalization has under- Yet he still believes that fairer trade, achievable mined the nation state. Yet he also finds that by reforming the WTO to eliminate its current national-scale interventions do not suffice. Thus de facto bias in favor of the global North, can he seeks modifications to the norms governing promote development (Stiglitz and Charlton, global trade, such as altering the WTO agreement 2005). Noting the lack of realism in mainstream on safeguards to enable democratic nation states to trade theory, he and Charlton urge that richer exert more territorial authority over economic flows countries be forced to guarantee open access to crossing their borders, when a national consensus imports from poorer countries, while poorer exists about such issues. countries are accorded the right to restrict imports Sachs and Rodrik also share the same criticism of from richer countries. The Generalized System of attempts under the Washington Consensus to Preferences should be adjusted to favor the global impose ubiquitous ‘best practice’ neoliberalism on South, and the WTO should stay away from promot- all countries, because this fails to take context into ing unrestricted international capital flows and account. Citing the influence of his spouse, a property rights agreements, such as TRIPS, that medical doctor, Sachs argues for a ‘clinical’ favor the global North. Diagnosing a democratic approach to economic policy-making, one that deficit within the WTO (abuse of the market defines the healthy economic body in terms of a set through control over information), he advocates of performance indicators, which become the goal global Keynesianism: tipping the playing field in that differentiated policy interventions, tailored to favor of the global South; enforcing transparency the national patient, are designed to realize. Rodrik and accountability on institutions that are not argues for policy prescriptions tailored to national subject to democratic control; paying poor countries circumstances. Yet both believe in a single set of for the full value of their primary commodity exports (neoclassical) ‘laws of economics’, to be drawn on and for ecological services they provide to the global in developing differentiated policy prescriptions. system; global rules to prevent corporations from Rodrik dubs this One Economics, Many Recipes playing one territory off against another and to reduce (Rodrik, 2007). monopoly power; unconditional debt forgiveness for Joseph Stiglitz has been the most vocal main- countries by allowing them to declare bankruptcy; stream critic of the Washington Consensus (Stiglitz, and a global bank that lends to those in need (Keynes’ 2002, 2006; Stiglitz and Charlton, 2005). He unsuccessful proposal during the Bretton Woods received the Nobel Medal for theorizing that infor- negotiations) (Stiglitz, 2006). mation asymmetry undermines the effectiveness of Notwithstanding significant disagreements, markets, and his service as chief economist for the Sachs, Rodrik and Stiglitz share the view that the

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 57 rollback of the state promulgated under neoliberal Pitts, 2005). (Free trader Richard Cobden’s globalization has gone too far, catalyzing a concen- anti-imperialism also comes to mind.) Like Sachs, tration of wealth in the hands of global elites, Diamond, Rodrik and Stiglitz, Easterly sees all impoverishment, theft of intellectual property and humans as equally able and creative, with the poor environmental degradation, and catalyzing world- unable to make good on their capabilities. Yet, wide social resistance. Their explicit promotion of citing Hayek, he believes that only the free market Keynesian alternatives, at national and global scales, (‘the laws of economics’; Easterly, 2002) can directly challenges neoliberalism. Indeed, in the provide the incentives, attentive to local context, aftershocks of the 2008 financial crisis discourses that can unfetter the potential of the poor to succeed about the need for a new New Deal and a new Bretton as capitalist entrepreneurs – who thereby become Woods have become commonplace. Friedrich von responsible for their success, or failure. As in trade Hayek, , Margaret Thatcher and theory, the capitalist market is conceptualized as Ronald Reagan should be rolling in their graves. recognizing and valuing difference, as a mark of Yet William Easterly and Hernando de Soto, distinction that can be traded on for mutual benefit while sharing the others’ criticisms of the failure and profit (Sheppard and Leitner, 2010). of the Washington Consensus, would beg to differ: The Peruvian economist Hernando de Soto they argue that Hayek was right. Easterly, a former similarly places his faith in the entrepreneurial senior research economist for the World Bank acumen of the poorest of the poor. De Soto, credited (1985–2001) and participant in the ‘geography’ with converting Peruvian president Alberto versus institutions debate, agrees that the interna- Fujimori from Keynesianism to neoliberalism, tional financial institutions have failed the global directs the Institute for Liberty and Democracy South’s poor, but reserves just as much ire for Sachs (recipient of awards, inter alia, from the Cato and Keynesian do-gooders of all stripes, as no Institute and ).17 He sees poorly different than Robert Owens and his 19th-century demarcated property rights as the principal cause utopian fellow travelers. He divides the world into of poverty. This is because the homes and planners (Owens, Sachs, the World Bank, etc.) and businesses of the poor are not legally registered in seekers (the entrepreneurial spirit in us all). In his their own names, and processes of registration are view, global development policies of all kinds enormously time-consuming, bureaucratic and (including the ‘Global War on Terror’) are Big Push costly. He argues that the principal source of capital initiatives that are doomed to fail, and infused with for small entrepreneurs is self-finance, from the the conceit that the global North holds all the answers. equity accumulated in their homes and businesses. ‘The White Man’s Burden emerged from the West’s The poor in the global South, living in squatter self-pleasing fantasy that ‘‘we’’ were the chosen ones settlements and working in the informal economy, to save the Rest ... The Enlightenment saw the Rest cannot take advantage of such potential sources of as a blank slate – without any meaningful history or capital (which he estimates as being worth over institutions of its own – upon which the West could US$9 trillion worldwide; de Soto, 2000). He argues inscribe its superior ideals’ (Easterly, 2006: 23). that the United States experienced the same situation If Easterly seems to be channeling Edward Said’s in the late 18th century but was able to overcome it, Orientalism or Eric Wolf’s Europe and the People and should be taken as a model for the global South without History (Said, 1978; Wolf, 1982), he lies to follow in order to move from a ‘pre-capitalist’ to a much closer to , the 19th-century ‘capitalist’ property system (de Soto, 2000: 172). English conservative who criticized liberalism for its duplicitous policies toward colonial India. Burke Hayek versus Keynes? Temporality, critiqued liberals for trampling on the individual rights of Indians in their zeal to remake them non-ergodicity and capitalist development in liberals’ own image, destroying rich local cul- Critical scholarship recently has highlighted the tures in the process (Mehta, 1999; Muthu, 2003; differences separating Keynesian Fordism from

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 58 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1)

Hayekian neoliberalism, even exhibiting nostalgia inducing individuals to hoard (dubbed their for the good old days when Keynesian discourses ) in times of uncertainty. This were hegemonic by comparison to the more brutal in turn requires state-led demand-side macroeco- ‘there is no alternative’ era of neoliberalism. These nomic intervention to alleviate in are vital differences of opinion about how capital- times of crisis (Keynes, 1936; Weatherson, 2002). ism can bring prosperity to all, whose instantiation Such socialization of investment, Keynes wrote, as development policy prescriptions has had was not devised as ‘a terrific encroachment on indi- enormous impact on the livelihood possibilities of vidualism, [but], on the contrary ... as the only people in places across the global South. Their practicable means of avoiding the destruction of ongoing contestation, as described above, remains existing economic forms [that is, capitalism] in their of enormous import.18 Yet these are differences entirety and as a condition of successful functioning about how capitalism can bring prosperity, not of individual initiative’ (Keynes, 1936: 380). whether it can. The Nobel Medal winning American economic Notwithstanding severe personal, intellectual historian Douglass North has taken up the question and political differences, the last of which might of the relation between irreducible uncertainty and be summarized as neoliberalism versus progressive capitalist development, arguing that this must be liberalism, both Hayek and Keynes had little addressed in any historical account of economic patience for the deterministic mathematical equili- change that is to remain faithful to the laws of eco- brium theories based on microfoundational rational nomics. ‘The study of economic change must ... choice models – the hard core of mainstream eco- begin with the ubiquitous efforts of human beings nomics. They both argued that time itself is a radical to deal with and confront uncertainty in a non- destabilizing factor, because of irreducible uncer- ergodic world’ (North, 2005: 5).20 In his conception, tainty about the future. Hayek, the anti-rationalist, individuals’ actions are founded in belief systems, believed that knowledge emerges from actions, requiring (cf. Hayek, 1952) ‘that we delve into how themselves rooted in habit and tradition, not from the mind and brain work’ (p. 5), and take place our ability to discern how the world works. The only within particular national institutional contexts. way for rationality to emerge from the habitual Individual agents face two kinds of uncertainty nature of everyday behavior, he believed, was (natural, and socially constructed) in their environ- through the discipline of competitive markets. This ments. Historically, individuals residing in territorial would have the important side effect, for him, of societies develop institutions (e.g. cultural systems, equating social efficacy with individual liberty risk markets and governance structures) to manage (Hayek, 1937, 1948). ‘In arguing that competition the uncertainties they confront (many of which are breeds rationality, Hayek is claiming that the filter a consequence of humans and their institutions). His of profit and loss weeds out those whose habits tend overriding conclusion is that national economies to generate inappropriate responses to market succeed or fail, engendering wealth or poverty for signals’ (Butos and Kopl, 1997: 351).19 their residents, depending on their ability to develop Keynes, the rationalist, saw human action as effective institutions to manage the real-world plagued by a radical uncertainty about the future uncertainties plaguing markets. (perhaps never more so than at present), which By taking temporality seriously, as an unknowable encourages speculation. ‘In such a world action can- future rather than an equilibrium trajectory, Hayek, not be rational; it must spring from an irrational Keynes and North pose serious challenges to the source, animal spirits ... A Cartesian rationalist adequacy of microfoundational models of the may be glad for the impulse to action that animal economy. At the same time, however, they share spirits provide, but he cannot have much faith that the mainstream paradigm’s predilection for ground- the actions so motivated will very often turn out as ing economic theory in the choices of autonomous intended’ (Butos and Kopl, 1997: 349). Here, mar- individual agents, its faith in a monistic (capitalist) kets cannot provide the necessary information, economics, and its conviction that spatiality is a

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 59 relatively minor complication. The fact that the richer the cultural context in terms of providing spatial extent of economic systems enhances agents’ multiple experimentation and creative competition, uncertainty is acknowledged, but is not seen as under- the more likely the successful survival of the society’ mining the capacity of markets, in principle, to be (North, 2005: 36). Like modernization theorists, socially beneficial. Like the neoclassical mainstream, North makes three arguments: that northwestern spatiality is conceptualized in terms of the location in European cultural and institutional contexts are richer which individuals find themselves (shaping their than others (at least in terms of their capacities for endowments, opportunities, preferences and culture). managing economic uncertainty); that the prosperity Keynes and North combined these with methodologi- of these societies is evidence of their superior cal nationalism: macro-scale features of the economy, cultural/institutional mix; and thus that other societies and of the institutions governing it, are equated with should emulate this mix if they wish to succeed. Such national territories, taken as the natural units of arguments have been extensively criticized for their analysis for the study of development. unwarranted structural functionalism (the assertion Even for a non-ergodic world, these arguments that the presence of certain attributes in places mobilize a teleological conceptualization of devel- deemed to be successful suffices to prove that these opment. When North asks why Europe becomes the factors are necessary for success); for their neglect center of capitalism after 1492, his answer is in of the asymmetrical relational connections between terms of attributes of Europe that, in his view, make places that may be every bit as important in causing it better suited to developing capitalist governance uneven development as territorial attributes; and for systems to manage uncertainty (North, 2005): their Eurocentrism (e.g. Blaut, 2000). They are, again, individualist belief systems that can underwrite rooted in methodological nationalism. ‘impersonal exchange’ (which he contrasts with Islamic collective action and Soviet collectivism), themselves rooted in ‘fundamental demographic/ Sociospatial ontologies and resource constraints that became embodied in development imaginaries religions’ (p. 136), combined with a fractured In the three preceding sections, I have examined the European geography of small territorial economies contrasting views of different overlapping groups of that enabled competition between different institu- economists on the question of economics, nature, tional and cultural assemblages. ‘The failures of the geography and development. I have noted substantial most likely candidates, China and Islam, point disagreements about the importance of first versus the direction of our inquiry. Centralized political second nature, the relative importance of institutions control limits the options ... The lack of large- and ‘geography’, and the merits of Keynesian versus scale political and economic order created the Hayekian prescriptions. Nevertheless, these disagree- essential environment hospitable to economic ments orbit fairly tightly around a shared belief in growth and ultimately human freedoms’ (p. 137). the capacity, in principle, of democratic capitalism, North concludes: ‘Growth has been generated when US-style, to solve poverty and bring development to the economy has provided institutional incentives to all. In this section, I explore how the sociospatial undertake productivity-raising activities such as the ontology of mainstream economics contributes to Dutch undertook. Decline has resulted from disin- this capacity for consensus on the question of centives to engage in productive activity as a result development, and contrast this with the quite different of centralized political control of the economy and development imaginaries that emanate from Anglo- monopoly privileges’ (p. 134). phone geographical political economy. North’s arguments are, thus, remarkably similar to those of the modernization theorists of 40 years ago, who generalized Rostow’s teleological economic The view from Economics model to incorporate sociological and psychological Notwithstanding the potential diversity of Economics, aspects (cf. McClelland, 1961; Parsons, 1966): ‘the I explore here the hegemonic mainstream perspective.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 60 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1)

This has produced the most effective and cohesive to function like Adam Smith’s invisible hand: ‘It is paradigm in Anglophone social science of the last not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, century. Imre´ Lakatos argues that every scientific or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their epistemological community constitutes its research regard to their own . We address ourselves, program through the articulation and defense of a set not to their humanity but to their self-love’ (Smith, of ‘hard-core’ propositions that should not be ques- 1776: I.ii.2). tioned, surrounded by a protective belt of ‘auxiliary There is considerable contemporary debate about hypotheses’ that protect this core from being falsified the cognitive and even neural aspects of choice- (Lakatos, 1970), and mainstream economists have making, about optimizing versus satisficing choices, mastered this. Even what seem to outsiders to be and about limited information and uncertainty, but relatively minor deviations within Economics are these are considered undesirable deviations from a marginalized by the mainstream’s proponents as rationally ordered and socially efficacious capitalist ‘heterodox’. Practitioners of such heresies find them- space-economy – deviations that should be fixed selves largely excluded from the canonical journals with a dose of ‘libertarian paternalism’ (Thaler and and departments. Indeed, some have concluded that Sunstein, 2003). Rationality is to be defended at all the mainstream view is simply autistic about such costs. The rationality of this ontology of capitalism alternatives (http://www.paecon.net). The hegemony rests on the question of how often individuals actu- of this epistemological community during the past ally achieve the intended consequences of their century also has had the effect of constituting the choices through the operation of the market. If this world through the enactment of its laws, with the were rare, there would be little reason for individuals effect of making their plausibility seem self-evident to repeat such actions; indeed, the very rationality of (Mitchell, 2005a). choice making would be called into doubt. To doubt As conceived within this tradition, the laws of the economic rationality of choice-based behavior, economics are, first, deemed to be ubiquitously then, would be to call the entire set of hard-core applicable, across space and time. Second, they propositions into question. separate the economic from other aspects of The spatiotemporal ontology accompanying, and socionature. Indeed, some proponents claim that reproduced through, this model of capitalism helps these laws apply to all domains of human action reign in the possibility of unintended consequences including our relationship with nature (consider, for – at least within its own theoretical confines. One example, the current popularity of carbon markets) scale dominates: that of the human body. Adopting (Fine and Milonakis, 2009). Third, they are the principle of methodological individualism, grounded in mathematical languages that enhance economic processes are reduced to the rational, their status as seemingly scientific. Fourth, they perfectly informed, self-interested and autonomous constitute a development imaginary in which the choices of individuals (themselves often reduced progress of nations is judged by whether and how to ideal types known as representative agents). they deviate from practicing these laws. Without such ‘’, a theoretical The social ontology underlying this shared belief model has little chance of gaining respect in con- is well known, but its spatiotemporality has received temporary mainstream economics – even in network less attention. The social ontology has the following economics where a relational model of human characteristics. The economy is composed of indi- action is now popular. Individual actions in turn are viduals of more-or-less equivalent social capacities, aggregated into territorialized macroeconomic differing in preferences and endowments (usually objects (e.g. aggregate production functions, or taken as exogenous to the economy). Markets factor endowments), which are assumed to describe function as a result of more-or-less well-informed adequately the dynamics of urban, regional and individuals making self-interested choices to buy (most commonly) national economies. Each scalar and sell. Markets are assumed to clear, placing the territorial entity is treated as a bounded and homo- economy in a neoclassical equilibrium that is argued geneous unit of analysis. Scalar units are given

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 61 a priori, and linked together through a bottom-up exception to this minimalist incorporation of causal logic, beginning with the individual, that temporality – including Hayek and Keynes. conforms with hierarchy theory in : objects A non-ergodic world poses deep problems for those at any scale are mobilized by actions emanating seeking to defend the rationality of a microfounda- from smaller scales and constrained by events tional approach. When the future is not simply operating at larger scales (Wu, 1999). unknowable but plagued with unpredictable twists Geographical detail is attached to this scalar and turns, how can humans, or even economists, ontology as a fixed set of attributes characterizing retain faith in their capacity to know and act on the each scaled unit of analysis (body, region, nation) world (Rosser, 2004)? Even here, however, it seems – a naturalized geography. This set includes possible to rescue the possibility of rationality, and place-based attributes (resources, climate, culture, of a teleological path for capitalist development, as etc.), and relative location (accessibility to other long as the other ontological features are preserved. such units, measured on the basis of given commu- nications geographies). If geographical difference Mainstream economics’ development imaginary. Taken creates unequal opportunities, it constitutes a tilted together, methodological individualism, naturalized ‘playing field’ on which some actors cannot achieve geographies and methodological territorialism economic welfare through their individual actions. underwrite the teleological, neocolonial develop- This would challenge the rationality of microfoun- ment imaginary that Rostow pioneered. Within this dations and thereby the hard-core principles. If such ontology, aided by a Walrasian auctioneer, capital- attributes can be commodified, however, as ism becomes a benevolent and harmonious functions driving preferences, or as resource mechanism of market clearance, in which all parti- endowments driving comparative advantage, then cipants are equally positioned and empowered to the possibility remains that the market can modulate realize their preferences.22 Its ubiquitous principles such differences through the rational choices of its promise to bring economic prosperity to all. In this participants (Sheppard and Leitner, 2010). imaginary, to be developed is to achieve high levels For most mainstream theorists, this bottom-up, of median gross national income and the like, which multiscalar and methodologically territorial spatial- immanent capitalist accumulation is imagined to ity is combined with a particular (a)temporality: the make possible.23 A crucial implication of this economy is assumed to approximate a market- teleology is that failure to achieve prosperity can be clearing equilibrium. Much mainstream economic attributed to characteristics of people and places that theory is static, with dynamics typically treated in prevent the market from achieving its potential: to bad one of two ways. One approach assumes that the latitude, bad attitude (Hart, 2002) or poor governance. economy is always approximately in equilibrium, Geography plays a relatively minor role, in the with the details of that equilibrium depending on the form of place-based characteristics – variations in context: Baldwin’s account of globalization exem- local context (e.g. endowments, traditions of state- plifies this. Here, dynamism is an attribute of the market relations, cultural norms, and geographical context rather than the economic theory. Alterna- advantage).24 Attending to these is acknowledged tively, it is assumed that the economy moves as crucial to making the appropriate intervention, smoothly along a dynamic equilibrium ‘golden’ but the goal of accelerating capitalist accumulation growth path, where current production exactly and growth remains the same (Rodrik, 2007). Jim matches future demand (clearing the market over Blaut has dubbed this developmental imaginary time). In such equilibrium models, time is reversi- ‘diffusionism’: development simply diffuses from ble: a shifting parameter rather than an evolutionary advanced to backward countries (Blaut, 1987, historical force. Unintended consequences are less 1993). Countries are ranked, then, by how far they likely and rationality still can rule.21 have progressed along the path to prosperity, con- As noted above, economists who stress the structing what Dipesh Chakrabarty calls ‘History 1’ irreducible nature of uncertainty are a notable (Chakrabarty, 2000) – a historical narrative that

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 62 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1) represents the developmental histories of western case in our anti-canonical discipline. Economic Europe and North America as the norm against which geography includes a group of scholars who hew all are to be judged (and most found wanting). more closely to mainstream economic thinking, but Crucially, this imaginary locates expertise about currently is dominated by Anglophone geographical development within the global North; those people political economy (Sheppard, 2011a). Even this is and places that have prospered are positioned to a very diverse body of knowledge rife with show others the way. Cowen and Shenton distin- philosophical, theoretical and methodological guish between immanent and intentional develop- disagreement (Sheppard and Barnes, 2000). Yet, ment: that is, between development as an emergent connecting across this diversity, it can be character- process and strategic efforts to create development ized by a very different sociospatial ontology (Cowen and Shenton, 1996). (Gillian Hart, 2001, from that of geographical and development dubs these ‘development’ and ‘Development’.) economics, with room for alternative development Within this imaginary, the path of immanent devel- imaginaries.25 opment is given, and a model that wealthy regions In contrast to the Cartesian ontology of draw on to bring intentional development to others. mainstream geographical economics (individuals Intentional development becomes necessary when and territories as hermetic objects of analysis; immanent development possibilities are blocked. spacetime as exogenous coordinates), geographical Developed countries’ expertise is necessary to open political economists tendentially favor a relational, such blockages, as their own prosperity confirms or dialectical, sociospatial ontology.26 This is so their successful experience in solving development in at least three senses. First, it attends to the problems. As both Blaut and Chakrabarty note, this co-constitution of society, spacetime and the contitutes a Eurocentric development imaginary. more-than-human world. Second, it takes a dialecti- Yet the principles invoked for intended develop- cal approach to theorizing the agents and territories ment have proven far from successful. Notwith- of a capitalist space economy. Third, it stresses how standing multiple experiments with different economic and non-economic aspects of the social territorial models of governance – spatiotemporally world (identity, politics, culture, etc.) are co-implicated. variegated capitalisms that articulate with different It is in the domain of theorizing economic actions local visions of state-market relations and shifting that economic geography can be most immediately global policy discourses (Brenner, 2004; Peck and compared to the economic mainstream, since this Theodore, 2007) – there has been serial policy is where the mainstream focuses. Indeed, some failure. Neither state-led development nor structural scholarship in geographical political economy has adjustment have been particularly successful in made the comparison as straightforward as possible accelerating many countries along the development through deployment of the mathematical language path. Nevertheless, the hegemony of this geographi- of theory that economists so value. Summarizing a cal imaginary has meant that such serial failures substantial body of such research (in heterodox eco- have not seriously undermined the global North’s nomics and economic geography), its focus is on the claims to expertise, even as its experts periodically production of commodities, not market exchange. reverse their views about which principles This entails, first, taking temporality seriously. are appropriate (Sheppard and Leitner, 2010). Markets, as places of instantaneous equilibrating Diffusionism implies that there are no alternatives exchange, are replaced by places of production, a to what development means or how to achieve it – process that takes time: the timelag between no legitimate contestations. advancing capital to finance production and the anticipated recuperation (realization) of profits is crucial to profitability. The view from Geography Second, it conceptualizes economic actors in If thinking in Economics can readily be simplified terms of their positionality within economic to a hegemonic mainstream view, this is far from the processes (shaped by class, gender, location, etc.)

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 63 rather than simply as rational autonomous agents. production to those of consumption, of anticipating Positionality conceptualizes agents in terms of their consumer demand in other places, and of plugging differently empowered interrelations, instead of ima- into complex and shifting geographies of finance. gining that they are autonomous agents with given Geographers stress the importance of recognizing that endowments and preferences. Third, geographical geographies are produced through socio-economic research takes seriously the shifting connections processes, if social theory is to avoid spatial fetishism between firms in a sector and between sectors, (Sheppard, 1990). Yet it is equally important to including the transportation sector – connections recognize that produced geographies have their own shaped by prevailing technological interdependen- distinct effects on socio-economic processes: society cies, labor relations and transportation costs. Even shapes geography, and geography shapes society without the complications of geography, such a shift (Plummer and Sheppard, 2006). Attempts to in perspective raises serious questions about main- commodify the more-than-human world (e.g. through stream macroeconomics (e.g. whether factor accumulation by dispossession and ecological reflect their marginal productivity or their bearers’ markets) are further plagued by the biophysical political power: Harcourt, 1972; Sraffa, 1960), and processes shaping the material world – processes that confirms Marx’s thesis of exploitation.27 capitalists seek to align with capitalism via commodifi- This scholarship confirms Marx’s intuition that a cation, albeit incompletely and often unsuccessfully.28 capitalist economy is generative of social inequality Once space and ‘nature’ are endogenized into and typically far from equilibrium, with different theories of capitalism, the dynamics of capital accu- alignments of agents struggling over the disposition mulation cannot be reduced to the microfoundations of the economic surplus (Harvey, 1982; Pasinetti, of geographical economics. 1981; Roemer, 1981, 1982; Sheppard and Barnes, 1990; Webber and Rigby, 1996). While market- Economic actors are neither fully rational nor clearing equilibria may emerge as significant autonomous. Their and preferences are orientation points for the dynamics of capitalism, shaped by their sociospatial position, their knowl- the individual and collective actions of agents gen- edge is imperfect, and they engage in collective action. Their actions shape, but also are shaped erally keep the economy far from such equilibria, by, the social structures and cultural context in with the very real possibility that agents cannot real- which they find themselves. As Marx quipped, they ize the intentions behind their seemingly rational, make the world, but not a world of their own choos- self-interested choices (Bergmann et al., 2009). ing. (Plummer and Sheppard, 2006: 622) Incorporating the co-constitution or production of spacetime and the more-than-human world It becomes that much harder for agents to select further muddies Panglossian mainstream represen- actions whose consequences can be foreseen, or can tations of capitalism. Distance is no longer simply be expected (with much confidence) to realize their a cost of doing business, but is produced by trans- intended goals, undermining the rationality of a portation and communications firms shaping how capitalist space economy grounded in the places are connected – firms that commodify space, self-interested actions of its agents. Further, uneven reshaping accessibility. Production technologies geographical development is the order of the day, differ across sectors, and regions (cf. Rigby and with some places realizing prosperity at the expense Essletzbichler, 1997). Places cannot be captured in of impoverishment elsewhere (the development of terms of given attributes or endowments, since their underdevelopment, cf. Frank, 1978; Harvey, 1982, characteristics, and sociospatial positionality, are 2005; Smith, 1984). continually in flux. The uncertainties faced by Over the past decade, drawing on cognate commodity producers, seeking to realize profits on scholarship in feminist studies, cultural studies, the capital advanced, are compounded by the post-prefixed philosophy, , economic difficulties of obtaining inputs from distant suppliers, sociology and political science, economic geogra- of having to move commodities from places of phers have demonstrated that ‘economic’ processes

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 64 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1) cannot be examined separately from, or prior to, through shifting geographies, tendentially reproduce more-than-economic processes (conventionally such inequalities, notwithstanding periodic spatial labeled as cultural, social and political) that they are restructuring (Sheppard, 2002). The fact that this bound up with (cf. Barnes, 1996; Gibson-Graham, most recent phase of rapid, neoliberal globalization, 1996; Grabher, 2006; Lee, 2006; McDowell, 1997; like that of the 19th century, has been accompanied Thrift, 2005; Wright, 2006). Rather, each is co- by persistent and intensifying sociospatial inequal- constitutive of the others. Consider, for example, ities, culminating in the current global crisis, ‘culture’ – an enduring problematic of development. provides prima facie evidence supporting this claim The most mundane economic practices – indeed the (Milanovic, 2005; Obstfeld and Taylor, 2004; very definition of what counts as economic – are Williamson, 2005). shaped by, as well as shaping, cultural norms, dis- Departing from Eurocentric territorial accounts courses and subject formation. Such practices yoked to History 1, a relational/dialectical view should be conceptualized in terms of how the situ- stresses sociospatial positionality, not European- ated imaginaries, knowledges and interests of differ- ness, as the catalyst for western Europe’s capital- ently positioned and unequally empowered agents ist prosperity. Diamond, Sachs and North explain give meaning to and shape economic practices. European prosperity in terms of northwestern Beyond this, such practices inevitably express the European territorial attributes (climate, topogra- situated identities of their practitioners, performa- phy, politics, culture, religion). Such explana- tively reproducing and challenging these – a process tions cannot adequately account for the ‘great that Judith Butler (1990) dubs citation. Geogra- divergence’ between Europe and eastern and phers’ contributions to making sense of these inter- southern Asia after 1492 – after which wealth minglings, and the complex assemblages that they and economic momentum rapidly moved from bring forth, have particularly focused on the multi- one side of the old world to the other (Abu- valent spatialities of positionality, and social and Lughod, 1991; Blaut, 1993; Pomeranz, 2000). political norms, and how these are co-implicated Methodological territorial explanations overlook with those of economic processes. Such complex- a key relational advantage that Europe possessed: ities are not reducible to rational microfoundations the good fortune of comparatively easy access to or mathematical theorems, although mathematical the Americas. This ‘new world’ proved readily modeling can help make their implications more pre- exploitable for resources, land, gold and silver, cise (Bergmann et al., 2009). its plantations became a proving ground for fac- tory labor practices, and the production of cheap The development imaginaries of geographical political sugar, coffee and cotton could be organized for economy. Geographical political economy, the bare European markets (Blaut, 1993). contours of which are sketched above, creates space European contact with the Americas profoundly for alternative development imaginaries. By altered the more-than-human world, in ways that contrast to the teleological model of capitalist devel- particularly benefitted Europe. This Columbian opment associated with mainstream Economics’ exchange (Merchant, 1989) brought European sociospatial ontology, a relational/dialectical viruses to the Americas, where American indigen- ontology envisions no such diffusion of immanent ous socio-ecological complexes were replaced by development from north to south. Even deploying European agricultural practices and species. such conventional conceptions of development as In Europe, diets improved, food and labor costs fell, economic prosperity, very different conclusions are factory technologies were catalyzed, and the money arrived at as to the conditions of possibility for supply and profit rates increased. In the Americas, achieving this. In this view, capitalism engenders depopulation and the depredations and displace- sociospatial inequality. Differences in sociospatial ments of colonialism undermined indigenous positionality, a historical legacy of social hierarchies livelihood practices (and military power), creating and geopolitical power inequalities mediated widespread impoverishment and further opening the

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 65 territories to the settlement of surplus European tropical subsistence livelihood systems. Others have populations. Here, geographical inequalities are emerged as alternatives, such as the state socialism explained as a consequence of socionatural relations, that many postcolonial societies experimented with connecting places in ways that tendentially benefit after 1950. As the problems of globalizing capital- certain places and social groups at the expense of ism have become particularly trenchant, multivalent others, rather than in terms of territorial differences contestations are increasingly visible, at a variety of in natural endowments. sites and scales (cf. Leitner et al., 2007a). Alterna- More generally, a relational/dialectical ontology tive imaginaries and practices, located in and across stresses how the economic conditions in a territory civil society and political institutions and entailing depend as much on its shifting connectivities with various spatialities, exceed the logics and processes other territories as on place-based attributes. driving capitalism. These include: explicitly Connectivities also are acknowledged within the anti-capitalist national (Venezuela, Iran), regional diffusionist imaginary, but are widely presented as (Kerala) and local territorial strategies (Escobar, mutually beneficial and thus not troubling this 2008; Moore, 1998); state agencies pursuing imaginary.29 By contrast, geographical political econ- non-capitalist agendas; and alternative social omy theorizes such connectivities as tendentially movements stretched across space. reinforcing uneven development. As in dependency As in Chakrabarty’s History 2, these alternatives and world systems theories, the impoverishment of draw strength from a capacity to resist becoming certain people and places co-evolves with globalizing ‘forms of [globalizing capitalism’s] own life- capitalism, rather than being an original condition that processes’ (Chakrabarty, 2000: 63). Of course, immanent capitalist development can overcome (cf. different contestations reflect distinct sociospatial Amin, 1974; Frank, 1967; Harvey, 1982; Wallerstein, positionalities and are unequally empowered, with 1979). questions remaining about their relative efficacy If a relational/dialectical geographic ontology and capacity to realize their particular developmental undermines the diffusionist, territorial History 1 that imaginaries and challenge hegemonic imaginaries still plagues mainstream economic conceptualiza- and practices. Nevertheless, to dismiss contestations tions of geography, capitalism and development – a priori is to cede ground to globalizing capitalism concluding that capitalist development in the core (Featherstone, 2003; Gibson-Graham, 2006; Leitner tendentially undermines that in the periphery – et al., 2007b; Rose, 2002). consideration of culture, identity, and more-than- capitalist economic practices further compounds the Conclusion: Transcending picture. A narrative that imagines enrolling cultural and geographical difference into the drive for development teleologies economic prosperity, commodifying it as tradable In this paper, I have analyzed the different narratives assets, becomes replaced by one that stresses of the economy, geography, nature and development cultural difference as a shifting terrain of contesta- mobilized by mainstream economists and economic tion over what counts as living well: a contestation geographers during the past 15 years. Among the with no determinable outcome. public and in policy-makers’ imaginations, econo- It is vital to recall that globalizing capitalism’s mists’ imaginaries dominate geographers’ – an own emergence to global hegemony (a trajectory ongoing challenge for the viability of our discipline. stretching back to Britain’s adoption of free trade Examining three such influential streams of thought, in the early 19th century) itself was achieved I note that they conceive the relationships between through its own successful contestation, and geography, nature and development in a particular marginalization, of alternative imaginaries and way. Like many geographers, they are increasingly practices of the economy, liberty, justice and the critical of what we have come to call the neoliberal good life. Contestations are ongoing. Some that phase of capitalist globalization that characterized preceded globalizing capitalism persist, such as the past three decades – market triumphalism.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 66 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1)

Nevertheless, they share a sociospatial imaginary, local at all levels means that the material and the itself rooted in mainstream economics, whose virtual, roots and routes, are now correlated in terms methodological individualism and territorialism, of different spatialisations and temporalities ... in and treatment of space and nature as external to the terms of new imaginaries that pluralise belonging in 30 economy, underwrites a diffusionist, teleological quite new ways. (Venn, 2006: 43–44) conception of development – an imaginary of globa- lizing capitalism as capable, in principle, of transfer- Rather than a teleological trajectory, development is ring economic prosperity from the global North to imagined as an assemblage of possibilities that are the global South. As a generation of dependency struggled over by differently situated and located theorists and of postcolonial scholars have noted, groups of actors in shifting alliances and rivalries. this implies that the global North provides a model Sociospatially differentiated conceptions of what it for all to follow – European history is universalized means to live well, of how differentiated economic as everyone’s history. In this imaginary, geography practices are valued and how to improve liveli- plays at best a secondary role: imprisoning disadvan- hoods, cohabit the earth, merging into, and being taged locations by blocking this diffusion, or transformed through, one another. describing a set of contingent contextual place- Of course, contestations are unequally empow- based features that require differentiated instruments ered. Inevitably, more powerful and widespread to align different kinds of places onto the same path. livelihood assemblages seek to superimpose their A corollary of this shared development imaginary is development imaginary on others. Such struggles that the global North remains the repository of long precede the moment when the term develop- expertise about how to achieve development, a role ment gained its current doctrinal usage in European it has asserted for itself since colonial times, because colonial societies (Cowen and Shenton, 1996). success is taken as the mark of expertise. Nevertheless, such attempts at intended develop- Against this, I argue, the relational/dialectical ment, driven by sociospatial processes of power/ ontology currently dominating Anglophone eco- knowledge, persuasion, emulation and governmen- nomic geography makes space for non-teleological, tality, are always incomplete and vulnerable to variegated development imaginaries. Emergent differently positioned contestations – contestations unequal geographies are part of the very fabric of over development imaginaries and practices, and globalizing capitalism. Differently positioned places over development itself (Escobar, 1995; Sachs, require different strategies even when sharing 1990; Santos, 2008; Sidaway, 2007). the same goal, legitimizing a multiplicity of develop- Imaginaries of capitalist development as a mental trajectories, rather than a teleology (Amin, common, economic path to the good life, eventually 2002; Massey, 1999; Sheppard, 2002). Beyond this, deliverable and acceptable to all, have never been cultural differences about what it means to live well, adequate to the task that they set themselves. Irredu- and how to realize this, are increasingly intermingled cibly differentiated livelihood practices come and co-constitutive – an ongoing resource for together in provisional and shifting assemblages, contestation. Couze Venn (2006) puts this well: with particular spatiotemporal footprints and effects. Such assemblages are ‘always heterogeneous; ... Underlying the strategies of development ... one mutually constitutive within and across scale; ... finds ... the idea that ‘progress’ ... [implies] the the human and non-human are intimately related and erasure or conversion of the previous state of co-implicated; ... change is the only constant; ... affairs in favor of more efficient and rational spatiotemporality is an emergent but influential stages. Within this perspective, the co-habitation aspect; and trajectories are contingent and uncertain’ of different spatialities and temporalities is seen (DeLanda, 2006; Sheppard, 2008: 2609). as a sign of dysfunction, or a side effect to be In a relational/dialectical ontology, these are not managed ... [Yet] cultures are inescapably poly- simply multiple trajectories co-existing with one glot ... the interpenetration of the global and the another, from which each chooses their preferred

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 67 alternative. They are interbraided, shaping one associated with the global North, metastasizes to all another in shifting, geographically complex and those participating in such exchange. If such unequal ways. Geographical trajectories of societal engagement could be realized, it is unlikely to result development are more akin to Steven Jay Gould’s in agreement (Longino, 2002). The purpose should intertwining branches than Rostow’s stages. This not be framed in terms of realizing a consensus opening up, while generative of variegated about development and the good life – something imaginaries, is potentially plagued with problems that is likely to be as undesirable as it is impossible. of differential empowerment and the danger of Rather, it should be seen as an open-ended process slippage into relativism. On the one hand, for all its of mutual learning – during which each potential failures and slippages, the performative success of development imaginary is subject to the most the mainstream capitalist imaginary must be rigorous challenge and revision. Such a normative acknowledged. Its taken-for-granted status and vision is difficult to implement and fraught with propagation through the vectors of postcolonial risk. Even-handed engagement between global- geopolitics has enabled it to masquerade as univer- scale powerful, seemingly universal assemblages sal, quasi-scientific knowledge about geography and more local and heterogeneous alternatives and development. Yet, like all such monistic knowl- (between, say, the World Economic Forum and the edge systems, it emerged as a local epistemology, World Social Forum) will be impossible without carved out of a particular context (18th-century finding ways to empower the latter. Further, the British Lockean liberalism sutured to European co-existence of different assemblages and imagin- colonialism). Thus, before accepting this ontological aries will require developing alternative modalities and theoretical framework on faith, it is important to of interaction and coordination – tasks convention- interrogate how it has fared as it has globalized ally given over to the market and the state; alterna- beyond its time/place of origin. tive assemblages cannot simply exist side by side On the other hand, for all their multifaceted and but will be interconnected. Yet the current status potentially transformative possibilities, it cannot of the world is hardly one that endorses any suffice to simply celebrate every one of those complacency about the adequacy of the currently contestations that still seem, from the mainstream hegemonic development imaginary. Indeed, the perspective, particular, parochial, and local.31 essence of geographical reasoning should be an Creating space to take alternatives seriously cannot open-minded acknowledgement of the differences be a license to do so uncritically. Indeed, all such across, and a rigorous interrogation of the possibilities assemblages must be subjected to a reciprocal criti- of, our world, wherever this may lead. cal engagement with one another, whereby each is challenged to defend its norms in light of others’ criticisms. Each must be assessed critically in terms Notes of its impact on both the livelihood possibilities of 1. Quoted in ‘A question of blame when societies fail’, those pursuing it and those living otherwise (and George Johnson, New York Times, 25 December elsewhere). Political and moral grounds, the implicit 2007. Available at: http://www.nytimes.com/2007/ bases for critique, must be laid bare for debate 12/25/science/25diam.html. (Barnes and Sheppard, 2010; Olson and Sayer, 2. I take a very broad-brush approach to nature, reducing 2009). Finally, this cannot be restricted to the realm the incredibly complex interminglings of a more- of intellectual disagreement; critical assessments of than-human geography to two contrasting narratives grounded livelihood practices undertaken in the about the relationship between the human and name of one or another imaginary are at least as non-human world: first versus second nature. I leave important. it to others to judge whether and how this simplification Such mutual critical engagement between liveli- compromises the arguments made here. hood assemblages and development imaginaries 3. These arguments remain controversial in Economics, implies that the locus of expertise, conventionally as will be discussed in the next section.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 68 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1)

4. Throughout, I place geography in quotes when it 11. Indeed, the very idea that there could be more than refersto the particularlylimiting conception disinterred one equilibrium outcome was quite controversial in by Diamond and Sachs. mainstream economics, until recently. 5. Diamond’s explanation of why Haiti is largely 12. This has long been recognized (Harvey, 1999; Lo¨sch, deforested (a mark of its unsustainability), unlike the 1954 [1940]; Ottaviano and Thisse, 2004). Dominican Republic, is very similar. Adopting the 13. This is exemplified by mainstream trade theory, unfamiliar domain, for him, of social rather than envi- where the benefits of free trade are presumed to ronmental analysis, he argues that the Dominican outweigh any costs for a minority, who can be Republic benefitted from European immigration and compensated in order that all can gain from trade cash crop exports, and thus was able to mobilize con- (Sheppard, 2011b). siderable local expertise of European origins about 14. The United Nations Research Institute for Social forest management. By contrast, he suggests, Haiti Development organized a conference on ‘The need (whose population of largely African origin fomented to rethink development economics’ in September a famous anti-slavery rebellion) did not attract 2001 (Hart, 2002). European immigrants, engaged in subsistence agri- 15. The shaping influence of this cluster of economists is culture instead of cash crop exports, and now requires such that a distinct, explicitly radical ‘new develop- external expertise to manage its forests (Diamond, ment economics’ (Jomo and Fine, 2006) has received 2005: 339–41). (He leavens this account with the little attention. Malthusian specter of overpopulation in Haiti.) Like 16. For a critical assessment see, for example, Peet Acemoglu et al., he associates expertise, here, with (2009); Sheppard (2005). (white) Europeans rather than Africans, and equates 17. Timothy Mitchell has traced how de Soto’s trajectory, development with specialization and international via Geneva, to become the representation of indigen- trade. ous third world economic expertise with considerable 6. Social Darwinists such as Herbert Spencer drew on influence over World Bank policy was shaped by this conception in their arguments that human and the same forces that made the neoliberal thought societal competition inevitably favors those who are collective of the West (Mirowski and Plehwe, 2009; superior – using such arguments to legitimate the Mitchell, 2005b). success of Europeans and the privileged classes (Peet, 18. The Economist now views state capitalism as impor- 1985). tant for years to come (The Economist, 2010). 7. I am grateful to Marion Traub-Werner for drawing 19. These arguments, formalized by Eugene Fama as the my attention to this. Efficient Markets Hypothesis (EMH), were broadly 8. is a popular subcurrent of criticized given their central role in the 2008 implo- heterodox (i.e. non-mainstream) economics, where sion of global finance markets (Buiter, 2009; Fama, biological debates about evolution still are revisited 1991; Mackenzie and Millo, 2003). Yet any reports (e.g. Boschma and Martin, 2007). of EMH’s death are greatly exaggerated. 9. Heterodox economists, including Marxists, depen- 20. In ergodic systems, distributions of future possibilities dency and world system theorists and feminist and are well defined and do not depend on the history of ecological economists, as well as economic geogra- the system. In non-ergodic systems, the opposite is the phers, emphasize non-teleological conceptions of case. These include systems exhibiting dynamical development (or, on occasion, other teleological and computational complexity: non-linear dynamical trajectories). systems of the kind popularized under the rubric of 10. Hugh Goodacre offers a similar comparison of Sachs’ complexity theory. and Krugman’s approaches, noting a relative neglect 21. Drawing on complexity theory, some economists of Sachs by economic geographers that reflects their have sought to treat the neoclassical economy as an ‘absorption ... in theoretical and methodological ‘evolving complex system’ (Anderson et al., 1988; issues, at the expense of a focus on the struggle for Arthur et al., 1997). Nevertheless, the power of equi- development’ (Goodacre, 2006: 264). librium thinking is such that the destabilizing

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 69

potential of this approach for mainstream hard-core prosecuting such an imaginary. Yet the sociospatial propositions is repeatedly shied away from (Krugman, ontology described here certainly helps underwrite 1996; Markose, 2005; Plummer and Sheppard, 2006). such imaginaries. 22. Uncertainties about how market-clearing prices can 31. Of course, the mainstream development narrative is actually emerge, even under conditions of perfect also particular, parochial, and local; its success lies competition, are often resolved by resorting to Leon in a capacity to elide this. Walras’ notion of deputizing the task to an auctioneer. 23. Although measurement of development is currently Acknowledgements subject to debate (Stiglitz, 1993). 24. This is much like Andrew Sayer’s realist account of I am grateful to the Center for Advanced Studies in the the difference that space makes (Sayer, 2000). Behavioral Sciences (Stanford, CA) and the National 25. It is impossible, of course, to accurately represent the University of Singapore for leaves enabling me to diversity of economic geography here, or the richness formulate and complete this paper. I have also benefitted of the empirical research on globalizing capitalism from audiences at the University of British Columbia, die that it has generated. I offer my particular, situated Universita¨t Heidelberg, the University of Minnesota, the perspective on geographical political economy, in the National University of Singapore, and the University of belief that its broad lineaments are broadly shared Tennessee, and from Jun Zhang, Luke Bergmann, Padraig across the subdiscipline. This common ground Carmody, and two anonymous referees – all absolved includes the propositions that agency and structure from responsibility for these arguments. are mutually constitutive, that spacetime shapes and is shaped by the economy, that relational connectiv- Funding ities between places and across scales are crucial, that This research received no specific grant from any economic processes are bound up with and insepar- funding agency in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit able from politics, culture and identity, and that sectors. capitalism produces sociospatial inequality. 26. Notwithstanding attempts to distance the recently dubbed ‘relational turn’ in economic geography from References political economy (Boggs and Rantisi, 2003; Ibert, Abu-Lughod J (1991) Before European Hegemony: The 2009), I regard the two as sharing an ontology that World System A.D. 1250–1350. New York: Oxford focuses on the relations between entities rather University Press. than on the entities themselves. Like , Acemoglu D, Johnson S, and Robinson JA (2002) Rever- I regard this as dialectical in inspiration (Harvey, sal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the mak- 1996; Sheppard, 2008). ing of the modern world income distribution. 27. The ‘Fundamental Marxian Theorem’ shows that Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 1231–94. profits can only be made when the socially necessary Acemoglu D, Johnson S, and Robinson JA (2003) Disease labor contributed by workers to commodity produc- and development in historical perspective. Journal of tion is greater than the labor for which they are the European Economic Association 1(2–3): 397–405. compensated (Morishima, 1973). Agnew JA (1994) The territorial trap: The geographical 28. Similar arguments apply to labor, because human assumptions of international relations theory. Review actions are never fully reducible to economic calcula- of International Political Economy 1(1): 53–80. tion (Polanyi, 2001 [1944]). Amin A (2002) Spatialities of globalization. Environment 29. Promoting unrestricted trade, investment, knowledge and Planning A 34: 385–399. and labor flows is supposed to close the ‘gap’ Amin S (1974) Accumulation on a World Scale. New between rich and poor countries, accelerating the York: Monthly Review Press. convergence of the latter on the former. Anderson P, Arrow KJ, and Pines D (eds) (1988) The 30. Of course, this is not a uniquely geographical insight; Economy as an Evolving Complex System. New York: other disciplines have been at least as active in Addison-Wesley.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 70 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1)

Arthur WB, Durlauf SN, and Lane DA (eds) (1997) The Butos WN and Kopl RG (1997) The varieties of subjecti- Economy as an Evolving Complex System II. New vism: Keynes and Hayek on expectations. History of York: Addison-Wesley. Political Economy 29(2): 327–359. Baldwin R (2006) Globalisation: The great unbundling(s). Castree N and Braun B (1998) The construction of nature In: Economic Council of Finland, Globalisation Chal- and the nature of construction: Analytical and political lenges for Europe. Helsinki: Prime Minister’s Office, tools for building survivable futures. In: Braun B and Chapter 1. Castree N (eds) Remaking Reality: Nature at the Barnes T (1996) Logics of Dislocation: Models, Millennium. London: Routledge, 3–42. Metaphors, and Meanings of Economic Space. New Chakrabarty D (2000) Provincializing Europe. Princeton, York: Guilford Press. NJ: Princeton University Press. Barnes T and Sheppard E (2010) ‘Nothing includes every- Collier P (2006) Africa: Geography and growth. Proceed- thing’: Towards engaged pluralism in Anglophone ings: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (Fall): economic geography. Progress in Human Geography 235–252. 34(2): 193–214. Collier P (2007) The Bottom Billion: Why the Poorest Behrens K, Gaigne´C, Ottaviano G, and Thisse J-F (2007) Countries are Failing and What Can Be Done About Countries, regions and trade: On the welfare impacts It. Oxford: Oxford University Press. of . European Economic Review Conway-Morris S (2006) Darwin’s dilemma: The realities 51(5): 1277–1301. of the Cambrian ‘explosion’. Philosophical Transac- Bergmann L, Sheppard E, and Plummer P (2009) Capitalism tions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences beyond harmonious equilibrium: Mathematics as if 361(1470): 1069–1083. human agency mattered. Environment and Planning A Cowen MP and Shenton RW (1996) Doctrines of 41(2): 265–283. Development. London: Routledge. Blaut J (1987) Diffusionism: A uniformitarian critique. Crafts N and Venables AJ (2001) Globalization in history: Annals of the Association of American Geographers A geographical perspective. In: Bordo MD, Taylor AM, 77(1): 30–47. and Williamson JG (eds) Globalization in Historical Blaut J (1993) The Colonizer’s Model of the World. New Perspective. National Bureau of Economic Research. York: Guilford Press. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 323–370. Blaut J (1999) and Eurocentrism. Geo- Davis M (1996) Cosmic dancers on history’s stage? The graphical Review 89(3): 391–408. permanent revolution in the earth sciences. New Left Blaut J (2000) Eight Eurocentric Historians. New York: Review 217: 48–84. Guilford Press. DeLanda M (2006) A New Philosophy of Society: Assem- Boggs J and Rantisi N (2003) The ‘relational turn’ in blage Theory and . London: economic geography. Journal of Economic Geography Continuum. 3(1): 109–116. De´murger S, Sachs J, Woo WT, Bao S, Chang G, and Boschma RA and Martin R (2007) Constructing an Mellinger A (2002) Geography, economic policy, and evolutionary economic geography. Journal of Economic regional development in China. Asian Economic Geography 7: 537–548. Papers 1(1): 146–197. Brenner N (2004) New State Spaces: Urban Governance de Soto H (2000) The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism and the Rescaling of Statehood. Oxford: Oxford Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New University Press. York: Basic Books. Buiter W (2009) The unfortunate uselessness of most Diamond J (1997) Guns, Germs and Steel. New York: ‘state of the art’ academic . The WW Norton. Financial Times 3 March. Available at: http://blogs.ft. Diamond J (2005) Collapse. How Societies Choose to Fail com/maverecon/2009/03/the-unfortunate-uselessness- or Succeed. New York: Penguin. of-most-state-of-the-art-academic-monetary-economics. Easterly W (2002) The Elusive Quest for Growth: Econo- Butler J (1990) Gender Trouble: Feminism and the mists’ Misadventures in the Tropics. Cambridge, MA: Subversion of Identity. London: Routledge. MIT Press.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 71

Easterly W (2006) The White Man’s Burden: Why the Gibson-Graham JK (1996) The End of Capitalism (As We West’s Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done More Harm Know It). Oxford: Blackwell. Than Good. New York: Penguin. Gibson-Graham JK (2006) A Postcapitalist Politics. Easterly W and Levine R (2003) Tropics, germs, and Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press. crops: How endowments influence economic develop- Goodacre H (2006) Development and geography: ment. Journal of Monetary Economics 50(1): 3–39. Current debates in historical perspective. In: Escobar A (1995) Encountering Development. Princeton, Jomo K and Fine B (eds) The New Development NJ: Princeton University Press. Economics: After the Washington Consensus. Lon- Escobar A (2008) Territories of Difference: Place, Move- don: Zed Books, 249–268. ments, Life, Redes. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Gould SJ (1989) Wonderful Life. New York: WW Norton. Evenett SJ and Keller W (2002) On theories explaining Gould SJ (1996) Full House: The Spread of Excellence the success of the gravity equation. Journal of Political from Plato to Darwin. New York: Three Rivers Press. Economy 110(2): 281–316. Grabher G (2006) Trading routes, bypasses, and risky Fama E (1991) Efficient capital markets: II. The Journal intersections: Mapping the travels of ‘networks’ of Finance XLVI(5): 1575–1615. between economic geography and economic sociol- Faye ML, McArthur JW, Sachs J, and Snow T (2004) The ogy. Progress in Human Geography 30(2): 163–189. challenges facing landlocked developing countries. Harcourt GC (1972) Some Cambridge Controversies in Journal of Human Development 5(1): 31–68. theTheoryofCapital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Featherstone D (2003) Spatialities of transnational Press. resistance to globalization: The maps of grievance of Hart G (2001) Development critiques in the 1990s: Culs the Inter-Continental Caravan. Transactions of the de sac and promising paths. Progress in Human Institute of British Geographers 28(4): 404–421. Geography 25(4): 649–658. Fine B and Milonakis D (2009) From Economics Imperi- Hart G (2002) Geography and development: Development/s alism to Freakonomics: The Shifting Boundaries beyond neoliberalism? Power, culture, political econ- Between Economics and Other Social Sciences. omy. Progress in Human Geography 26(6): 812–822. Abingdon: Routledge. Harvey D (1982) The Limits to Capital. Oxford: Basil Fingleton B (2000) Spatial , economic geo- Blackwell. graphy, dynamics and equilibrium: A ‘third way’? Harvey D (1996) Justice, Nature and the Geography of Environment and Planning A 32(8): 1481–1498. Difference. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Fowler CS (2007) Taking geographical economics out of Harvey D (1999) Introduction to the Verso edition. In: equilibrium: Implications for theory and policy. Harvey D Limits to Capital. London: Verso, xiii–xxviii. Journal of Economic Geography 7(3): 265–284. Harvey D (2005) Spaces of Neoliberalization: Towards a Fowler CS (2010) Finding equilibrium: How important is Theory of Uneven Geographical Development. general equilibrium to the results of geographical Wiesbaden: Fritz Steiner Verlag. economics? Journal of Economic Geography.doi: Hausmann R (2001) Prisoners of geography. Foreign 10.1093/jeg/lbq006. Policy January/February: 45–53. Frank AG (1967) Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Hayek FA (1937) Economics and knowledge. Economica Latin America. New York: Monthly Review Press. N.S. 4(February): 33–54. Frank AG (1978) Dependent Accumulation and Underde- Hayek FA (1948) Individualism and Economic Order. velopment. London: Macmillan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Gallup JL, Sachs JD, and Mellinger AD (1999) Geogra- Hayek FA (1952) The Sensory Order: An Inquiry into the phy and economic development. International Foundatons of Theoretical Psychology. Chicago: Review 22(2): 179–232. University of Chicago Press. Garretsen H and Martin R (2010) Rethinking (new) Henderson J (1999) Overcoming the adverse effects of economic geography models: Taking geography and geography: Infrastructure, health, and agricultural history more seriously. Spatial Economic Analysis policies. International Regional Science Review 5(2): 127–160. 22(2): 233–37.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 72 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1)

Hodgson GM (2002) in economics: From financial derivatives exchange. American Journal of analogy to ontology. Journal of Evolutionary Economics Sociology 109(1): 107–145. 12(3): 259–281. Markose SM (2005) Computability and evolutionary Ibert O (2009) Lerndynamiken: Eine relationale complexity: Markets as complex adaptive systems. Wirtschaftsgeographie von Wissenspraktiken und The Economic Journal 115: F159–F192. Innovationsprozessen. Bonn: Rheinischen Friedrich– Markusen JR (2002) Multinational Firms and the Theory Wilhelms Universita¨t Bonn, Geography. of . Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Irwin DA (2006) Commentary: Shifts in economic Ma´rquez-Ramos L, Martı´nez-Zarzoso I, and Celestino geography and their causes. Federal Reserve Bank of S-B (2007) The role of distance in gravity regressions: Kansas City (fourth quarter): 41–48. Is there really a missing globalization puzzle? The B.E. Johnston RJ (1976) The World Trade System: Some Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 7(1): Art. 6. Enquiries Into Its Spatial Structure. London: G. Bell Martin RL (1998) The new ‘geographical turn’ in and Sons Ltd. economics: Some critical reflections. Cambridge Jomo K and Fine B (eds) (2006) The New Development Journal of Economics 23(1): 65–91. Economics: After the Washington Consensus. London: Massey D (1999) Imagining globalization: Power- Zed Books. geometries of time-space. In: Brah A, Hickman M, and Keynes GM (1936) The General Theory of , Mac an Ghaill M (eds) Global Futures: Migration, Interest, and Money. London: Macmillan. Environment and Globalization. New York: St. Martin’s Krugman PR (1993) First nature, second nature, and Press, 27–44. metropolitan location. Journal of Regional Science McClelland D (1961) The Achieving Society. Princeton, 33(2): 129–144. NJ: Van Nostrand. Krugman PR (1996) The Self-organizing Economy. McDowell L (1997) Capital Culture: Money, Sex and Oxford: Blackwell. Power at Work. Oxford: Blackwell. Krugman PR and Venables AJ (1995) Globalization and Mehta US (1999) Liberalism and Empire. Chicago: the inequality of nations. Quarterly Journal of University of Chicago Press. Economics 110(4): 857–880. Merchant C (1989) Ecological Revolutions: Nature, Lakatos I (1970) Falsification and the methodology of Gender and Science in New England. Chapel Hill, scientific research programmes. In: Lakatos I and NC: University of North Carolina Press. Musgrave A (eds) Criticism and the Growth of Knowl- Milanovic B (2005) Worlds Apart: Measuring Interna- edge. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 91–195. tional and Global Inequality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Lee R (2006) The ordinary economy: Tangled up in University Press. values and geography. Transactions of the Institute Mirowski P and Plehwe D (eds) (2009) The Road from of British Geographers 31: 413–432. Mont Pelerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Leitner H, Peck J, and Sheppard E (eds) (2007a) Contest- Collective. Cambridge, MA: ing Neoliberalism: Urban Frontiers. New York: Guil- Press. ford Press. Mitchell T (2005a) Economists and the economy in the Leitner H, Sziarto KM, Sheppard E, and Maringanti twentieth century. In: Steinmetz G (ed.) The Politics A (2007b) Contesting urban futures: Decentering of Method in the Human Sciences: Positivism and its neoliberalism. In: Leitner H, Peck J, and Sheppard E Epistemological Others. Durham, NC: Duke University (eds) Contesting Neoliberalism: Urban Frontiers. Press, 126–141. New York: Guilford Press, 1–25. Mitchell T (2005b) The work of economics: How a disci- Longino H (2002) The Fate of Knowledge. Princeton, NJ: pline makes its world. European Journal of Sociology Princeton University Press. 46(2): 297–320. Lo¨sch A (1954 [1940]) The Economics of Location. New Mitchener KJ and Weidenmier M (2008) Trade and Haven, CT: Yale University Press. empire. The Economic Journal 118(6): 1805–1834. Mackenzie D and Millo Y (2003) Constructing a market, Moore DS (1998) Subaltern struggles and the politics performing theory: The historical sociology of a of place: Remapping resistance in Zimbabwe’s

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 73

Eastern Highlands. Cultural Anthropology 13(3): Polanyi K (2001 [1944]) The Great Transformation: The 344–381. Political and Economic Origins of Our Time, second Morishima M (1973) Marx’s Economics: A Dual Theory of edition. , MA: Beacon Press. Value and Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Pomeranz K (2000) The : China, Press. Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Muthu S (2003) Enlightenment Against Empire. Prince- Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. ton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Presbitero AF (2006) Institutions and geography as Nordhaus WD (2006) Geography and macroeconomics: sources of economic development. Journal of Interna- New data and new findings. Proceedings of the tional Development 18: 351–378. National Academy of Sciences 103(10): 3510–3517. Przeworski A (2004a) Geography vs. institutions Norgaard R (1994) Development Betrayed: The End of revisited: Were fortunes reversed? Working paper, Progress and a Coevolutionary Revisioning of the New York University. Future. London: Routledge. Przeworski A (2004b) The last instance: Are institutions North DC (2005) Understanding the Process of Economic the primary cause of economic development? Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. European Journal of Sociology 45: 165–188. Obstfeld M and Taylor AM (2004) Global Capital Rigby D and Essletzbichler J (1997) Evolution, process Markets: Integration, Crisis and Growth. Cambridge: variety, and regional trajectories of technical Cambridge University Press. change in US manufacturing. Economic Geography Olson E and Sayer A (2009) Radical geography and its 73: 269–285. critical standpoints: Embracing the normative. Rodrik D (1997) Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Antipode 40(1): 180–198. Washington, DC: Institute for . Olsson O and Hibbs DA Jr (2005) and Rodrik D (2007) One Economics, Many Recipes: Globa- long-run economic development. European Economic lization, Institutions and Economic Growth. Princeton, Review 49: 909–938. NJ: Princeton University Press. Ottaviano G and Thisse J-F (2004) Agglomeration and Rodrik D, Subramanian A, and Trebbi F (2004) Institu- economic geography. In: Henderson JV and Thisse tions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography J-F (eds) Handbook of Urban and Regional Econom- in economic development. Journal of Economic ics, Vol. 4. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2564–2608. Growth 9(2): 131–165. Parsons T (1966) Societies: Evolutionary and Comparative Roemer J (1981) Analytical Foundations of Marxian Perspectives. New York: Prentice Hall. Economic Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Pasinetti LL (1981) Structural Change and Economic Press. Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Roemer J (1982) A General Theory of Exploitation and Peck J and Theodore N (2007) Variegated capitalism. Class. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Progress in Human Geography 31(6): 731–772. Rose M (2002) The seductions of resistance: Power, Peet R (1985) The social origins of environmental politics, and a performative style of systems. Environ- determinism. Annals of the Association of American ment and Planning D: Society and Space 20: 383–400. Geographers 75: 309–333. Rosser JB Jr (2004) Epistemological implications of Peet R (2006) Book review: The End of Poverty.Annals of the economic complexity. Annals of the Japan Association Association of American Geographers 96(2): 450–453. for Philosophy of Science 13(1): 45–57. Peet R (2009) Ten pages that changed the world: Decon- Rostow WW (1960) The Stages of Economic Growth: structing Ricardo. Human Geography 2(1): 81–95. A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge Pitts J (2005) A Turn to Empire: The Rise of Imperial University Press. Liberalism in Britain and France. Princeton, Sachs JD (2001) Tropical underdevelopment. NBER NJ: Princeton University Press. Working Paper 8119. Cambridge, MA: National Plummer P and Sheppard E (2006) Geography matters: Bureau of Economic Research. Agency, structures and dynamics. Journal of Economic Sachs JD (2005) The End of Poverty: Economic Possibi- Geography 6(5): 619–637. lities For Our Time. New York: Penguin.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 74 Dialogues in Human Geography 1(1)

Sachs J and McCord GC (2008) Geography of regional Sheppard E, Porter PW, Faust D, and Nagar R (2009b) development. In: Durlauf S and Blume L (eds) The A World of Difference: Encountering and Contesting New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. Development, second edition. New York: Guilford London: Palgrave Macmillan. Press. Sachs J, Bajpal N, and Ramiah A (2002) Understanding Sidaway D (2007) Spaces of postdevelopment. Progress regional economic growth in India. Asian Economic in Human Geography 31(3): 345–361. Papers 1(3): 32–62. Smith A (1776) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes Sachs W (1990) On the Archaeology of the Development of the Wealth of Nations. London: A. Strahan and Idea. Lokayan Bulletin 8(1): 7–37. T Cadell. Said EW (1978) Orientalism. New York: Vintage. Smith N (1984) Uneven Development: Nature, Capital Santos B de S (2008) Another Knowledge is Possible: and the Production of Space. Oxford: Blackwell. Beyond Northern Epistemologies. London: Verso. Sraffa P (1960) The Production of Commodities by Means Sayer A (2000) Realism and Social Science. Thousand of Commodities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Oaks, CA: SAGE. Press. Sheppard E (1990) Modeling the capitalist space Stiglitz JE (1993) Market socialism and neoclassical eco- economy: Bringing society and space back. Economic nomics. In: Bardhan P and Roemer J (eds) Market Geography 66: 201–228. Socialism: The Current Debate. Oxford: Oxford Uni- Sheppard E (2000) Geography or Economics? Contrasting versity Press, 21–41. theories of location, spatial pricing, trade and growth. Stiglitz JE (2002) Globalization and its Discontents. In: Clark G, Gertler M, and Feldman M (eds) London: Allen Lane. Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford: Oxford Stiglitz JE (2006) Making Globalization Work. New University Press, 199–219. York: WW Norton. Sheppard E (2002) The spaces and times of globalization: Stiglitz JE and Charlton A (2005) Fair Trade for All: How Place, scale, networks, and positionality. Economic Trade Can Promote Development. New York: Oxford Geography 78(3): 307–330. University Press. Sheppard E (2005) Free trade: The very idea! From Thaler RH and Sunstein CR (2003) Libertarian paternalism. Manchester boosterism to global management. Trans- American Economic Review 93(2): 175–179. actions of the Institute of British Geographers 30(2): Tharakan J and Thisse JF (2002) The importance of 151–172. being small. Or when countries are areas and not Sheppard E (2008) Geographic dialectics? Environment points. Regional Science and and Planning A 40: 2603–2612. 32(3): 381–408. Sheppard E (2011a) Geographical political economy. The Economist (2010) Re-enter the dragon. The Econo- Journal of Economic Geography, forthcoming. mist 5 June. Sheppard E (2011b) Trade, globalization and uneven Thrift N (2005) Knowing Capitalism. London: SAGE. development. Progress in Human Geography, Venables AJ (2006) Shifts in economic geography and forthcoming. their causes. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Sheppard E and Barnes TJ (1990) The Capitalist Space (fourth quarter): 61–83. Economy: Geographical Analysis after Ricardo, Marx Venables AJ and Lima˜o N (2002) Geographical disadvan- and Sraffa. London: Unwin Hyman. tage: A Hecksher-Ohlin von Thu¨nen model of interna- Sheppard E and Barnes TJ (2000) A Companion to tional specialization. Journal of International Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell. Economics 58(2): 239–263. Sheppard E and Leitner H (2010) Quo vadis neoliberalism? Venn C (2006) The city as assemblage. In: Berking H, The remaking of global capitalist governance after the Frank S, Frers L, Lo¨w M, Meier L, Steets S, et al. (eds) Washington Consensus. Geoforum 41(2): 185–194. Negotiating Urban Conflicts: Interaction, Space and Sheppard E, Maringanti A, and Zhang J (2009a) Where’s Control. Bielefeld: Transcript Verlag, 41–52. the geography? World Bank’s WDR (2009) Economic Wallerstein I (1979) The Capitalist World Economy. and Political Weekly 44(29, 18 July): 45–51. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011 Sheppard 75

Weatherson B (2002) Keynes, uncertainty and interest World Bank (2008) World Development Report 2009: rates. Cambridge Journal of Economics 26(1): 47–62. Reshaping Economic Geography. Washington, DC: Webber M and Rigby D (1996) The Golden Age Illusion: The World Bank. Rethinking Postwar Capitalism. New York: Guilford Wright M (2006) Disposable Women and Other Myths of Press. Global Capitalism. London: Routledge. Whatmore S (2001) Hybrid Geographies: Natures, Wu J (1999) Hierarchy and scaling: Extrapolating infor- Cultures, Spaces. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE. mation along a scaling ladder. Canadian Journal of Williamson JG (2005) Globalization and the Poor 25(4): 367–80. Periphery Before 1950. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Yamamoto D (2008) Scales of regional income disparities Wolf ER (1982) Europe and the People Without History. in the United States, 1955–2003. Journal of Economic Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Geography 8(1): 79–103.

Downloaded from dhg.sagepub.com by Eric Sheppatd on March 21, 2011