Wrrkboo& for Chapter 5 : 1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Wrrkboo& for Chapter 5 : 1 iffiffiffi*et Wrrkboo& for Chapter 5 : 1.. ll:::. i:r l!,,:. I lll Name Date Multiple- Choice Qrestions 7. The largest component of GDP is (t.03) a) net exporis c) consumption the letter that corresponds to the answer Circle best b) investment d) government purchases 1. Since 1955 Americans have been spending -. 8. The largest component of C is (L.Ol) iLO"jr a) durable goods a) a larger percentage of their incomes on services b) services b) a smaller percentage of their incomes on services c) nondurable goods -. c) about the same percentage of their incomes on servlces 9. The consumption function tells us that, as income 2. When the C line crosses the,l5-degree 1ine, saving is rises, consumption 1l-O3) a) declines (1_O3. -1) b) remains the same a) positive c) rises more slowll than income b) negative -. dt rises rnore quickly than income c) zero d) impossible to calculate because there is not 10. When income levels are very low, enough infbrmation to know C is (LO3) 3. When disposable income is zero, (LO5) a) zero a) autonomous consumption is equal to induced b) lower than income consumption c) higher-. than income b) autonomous consumption is equal to total I l. When income is equal to consumption. consumption saving is (t-(}3.:{-) c) induced consumption is equal to total consumption a) negative b) zero The minimurn amount that people wiil spend even if c) positive income is zero is called disposable d) impossible to calculate because there is consumption. (LO-5) insu ffi eient inlbnnation a) autonomous 12. Which of the following relations is nol b) induced coffect? (l-0 l. 2) c) total a) MPC +MPS : I d) I -APS :APC According to the permanent income hypothesis, if a b) APC+APS- I e) 1 -MPC:MPS person received a windfall of $100,000, he would c)MPS-MPC+1 spend that year. (LO7) 13. lnduced consumption expenditures (LO5) a) some of it c) nearly all of it a) fall as income rises b) most of it d) ail of it b) are always equal to autonomous consumption - expenditures -. (l-O-5; As disposable income rises, c) plus saving equals total consumption expenditures a) autonomous C rises c) induced C rises d) represent consumption that is independent of income b) autonomous C falls d) induced C lalls e) are influenced mainly by income -. 11t TZJ When disposable income is $2.000 billion. t4. Autonomous consumption expenditures are 18. consumption is (LO-r ) -_-. ( I-{15 ) billion d) $3,500 billion a) equal to induced consumption expenditures a) -$3,500 e) $4'000 billion b) proportional to disposable income b) 0 billion c) not influenced bY income c) $2,000 -. d) influenced primarily by the saving lunction l9 Which statement is the most accurate'l (l-O8) a) The American personal saving rate would be { l-{) I ) 1 ,s. The average propensity to save _---' higher if we counted capital gains as income that income divided by saving a) is disposable is not spent. of the adclitional saving generated by b) is a measure b) An average propensity to save of 0.02 means that income additional only 2 percent of the population is saving any c) is negative at very high income levels income. the d) varies directly with income; as income rises' c) Our 1ow saving rate is not considered a problem APS rises by many economists. d) Our government saving rate is aiways negative' 12,000 20. Our consumption spending tends to rise as the stock of liquid assets in the hands of consumers 10,000 and credit availabilitY a (l-()6) c B,OOO -o a) rises. rises b) falls. falls d) fails, rises c 6,000 c) rises. falls .E o- -. E Dianne Call earn $100,000 a year. They f 2I Boycl and a c into debt after paying $7-5'000 lbr therr o 4,000 went deeply (J daughter Chelsea's wedding and 550,000 for their daughter Kaylynne's sweet 16 party. Their behavtor 2,000 might best be described by _=-_-. tLO6. 7. 8l a) Milton Friedman 0 xx:<ePS 88 b) John Maynard KeYnes c\t +@@ c) Bruce Steinberg Disposable income ($ billions) d) Thorstein Veblen 22. As a nation's income falls. induced consumption {"igure 1 =-_-_-. 1LO5) Use the data in Figure I to answer questions 16 through l8 a) rises 16. Saving is equal to zero at a disposable income b) falis of_-. (l-0+) c) remains the same a)0 d) $6,000 billion L). Twenty years from now our disposable income will b) $2'000 billion e) $8,000 billion rise from $30 trillion to $3 I trillion. On the basis of in saving habits of American consumers, c) $4,000 billion past trends what would be your best guess regarding the increase at a disposable incorne i7. Consumption is equal to 5.000 in consumption during this period? (i-08) of =-. r l-{).r 1 a) S-50 billion c) $950 billion a) $2,000 billion d) $8'000 billion b) $500 billion d) $1.05 trillion b) $4,000 bitlion e) $ 10'000 biliion c) $6'000 billion 124 i 24. Which statement is the most accut'ate? tLO6, 8) -5. Dissaving takes piace when lI-O5) a) The American consumer was lirgel-v responsible for Induced consumption is induced by (l-O5 ) Japan's economic resurgence since World War lI. 6. b) China. as the rvorid's most populous country, has 7. According to the saving function,-. as disposable the world's largest consumer market. income rises, (LO:l) -. c) Although there are some who call the American consumer a world-class shopper. most Amencans 8. The most important determinant of the level of save substantial parts of their incomes. consumption is (LO6) d) Since we import most of our goods, the American -. economy has only a smail impact on the world's 9. The average propensity to consume in the United other large economies. (i-O States today is about-. I ) 25. Which statement is true'l (LO 1, 8) (LOl) a) Americans save much more of their incomes than 10. I -MPS:-. they did 20 years ago. 11. When the C iine crosses-. the 45-degree line, saving is b) ln 2012, ourAPC was a little beiow 1.0. equal to (LO3. -l-) c) Although the United States does not have the highest saving rate in the world, Americans save Problerns more money than the citizens of every other country. 1. Given the information shown in Table 1, calcuiate the negative the 1990s. d) Our APS has been since early APC and the APS. (LOl ) 26. Which statement is true? (LO6) a) Consumption spending accounts for about ffi.ffi 60 percent of our GDP. Disposable Inconte Consumption l b) The basic long-term trend in consumption spending as a percentage of GDP has been $ 10.000 $8,400 downward. c) The wealth efTect accounts for some additional consumption when people perceive themselves to 2. Given the inforrnation shown in Table 2, calculate the be wealthier. MPC and MPS. (Assume disposable income rises d) Were it not for tl.re wealth effect, most Americans, from 535,000 to $37,000.) (LO2) especialiy those who owned homes and corporate stock, would have cut back on their consumption i#ffiB-FHff-trffi even more, making the Great Recession more ffi.@*#ffi#c sevefe. YeiLr Disposable Income Saving Fill-In Qrestions 2002 $35,000 $4,600 2003 37.000 5,300 1. About percent of what Americans spend on consumption is spent on services. (I-Ol. 3) 3. Using the information in Figure 2, how much are 2. The average propensity to consllme is found by consumption and saving when disposable income - is: (LO3.'1) dividing by (LO I ) C Saving 3. The APS + the APC . (LO I ) a) $1,000 b) 2,000 i 1. The cofsumption function-. states thal c) 3.000 _. (LO3) rz) Using your answers from question 3a, calculate the APC and the APS. (LO 1. (,i . 5. Using your answers from questions 3a and 30, calculate the MPC and the MPS when disposable income rises fiom S1.000 billion to $2,000 billion. (LOl) a 6. Using the data in Figure 2, how much is autonomous EB .: consumption'? tL[J-i) e ov F o E af CI : C) a c '-€ 468 10 tz 'F ($ o- Disposable income trillions) E = ca () F igtrre 3 1 Use the data in Figure 3 to answer questions 9 through 12. rr 9. Determine incluced consumption when disposable - rri income is: (1,O5) iltl 123 a) 0 Disposable income ($ trillions) b) $6 trillion II c) $12 trillion liiglrz 2 l-- 10. When disposable income is $9 trillion: (l-O3..i) 7. Using the data in Figure 2, determine induced t- a) Hor'v much is autonomous consumption? consumption when disposable income is: (LO5) b) How much is total consumption? a) $1 trillion c) How much is saving? ,i b) $2 trillion u c) $3 trillion lt. When disposable income is $12 trillion: (LO I ) ,1. \ a) How much is the APC? 8. If C is $4 trillion, disposable income is $5 trillion, b) How much is the APS? and autonomous consumption is 53 trillion: (LO5) a) How much is saving? t2. In question 11: tLO2) Pr b) How much is induced consumption'? a) How much is the MPC? c) How much is the APS? b) How much is the MPS? The: d) If theAPS falls by 0.01, how much (in dollars) rndr', does saving fall? afe ( and .
Recommended publications
  • The National Income Multiplier: Its Theory Its Philosophy Its Utility
    University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers Graduate School 1959 The national income multiplier: Its theory its philosophy its utility John Colin Jones The University of Montana Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Jones, John Colin, "The national income multiplier: Its theory its philosophy its utility" (1959). Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers. 8768. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd/8768 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE NATIOHAL INCOME MULTIPLIER; ITS THEORY, ITS PHILOSOPHY, ITS UTILITY J» COLIN H. JONES B.A. University of WaJes^ U.C.W., Aberystwyth, 195Ô Presented in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts MONTANA STATE UNIVERSITY 1959 Approved by: , Board of Examiners Dean, Graduate School AUG 6 1959 D a te UMI Number: EP39569 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. UMI Dis»art«t)on Publishsng UMI EP39569 Published by ProQuest LLC (2013).
    [Show full text]
  • AP Macroeconomics: Vocabulary 1. Aggregate Spending (GDP)
    AP Macroeconomics: Vocabulary 1. Aggregate Spending (GDP): The sum of all spending from four sectors of the economy. GDP = C+I+G+Xn 2. Aggregate Income (AI) :The sum of all income earned by suppliers of resources in the economy. AI=GDP 3. Nominal GDP: the value of current production at the current prices 4. Real GDP: the value of current production, but using prices from a fixed point in time 5. Base year: the year that serves as a reference point for constructing a price index and comparing real values over time. 6. Price index: a measure of the average level of prices in a market basket for a given year, when compared to the prices in a reference (or base) year. 7. Market Basket: a collection of goods and services used to represent what is consumed in the economy 8. GDP price deflator: the price index that measures the average price level of the goods and services that make up GDP. 9. Real rate of interest: the percentage increase in purchasing power that a borrower pays a lender. 10. Expected (anticipated) inflation: the inflation expected in a future time period. This expected inflation is added to the real interest rate to compensate for lost purchasing power. 11. Nominal rate of interest: the percentage increase in money that the borrower pays the lender and is equal to the real rate plus the expected inflation. 12. Business cycle: the periodic rise and fall (in four phases) of economic activity 13. Expansion: a period where real GDP is growing. 14. Peak: the top of a business cycle where an expansion has ended.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Concept of Nudging: Its Coherence and Applicability?
    On the Concept of Nudging: Its Coherence and Applicability? Mads Wistrup Freund September 15, 2017 25-June-1993-xxxx MSc in Business Administration and Philosophy Vejleder: Marius Gudman Høyer 1 Abstract The practice of nudging has attracted attention from researchers, policymakers, and practitioners alike. The contemporary interest in nudging has sparked demands for a clearer examination of the conditions under which nudging and other behavioral methods can be used efficiently and acceptable. There are several unresolved questions which may have contributed to heated political and scientific discussions, especially heated is the ethical discussion of applying nudging in the public policy domain. This thesis concentrate on the philosophical premises nudges are built on. It is argued that the model is philosophically problematic. Different interventions might operate through various logics that threaten not only effectiveness but also representativeness and ethical ends. This thesis aruges that the next step in advancing the acceptability nudging requires a clarification. The thesis investi- gates the internal logic of this practice by exploring the expositions and implications within the literature on nudging in public policy, by specifically exploring its origins in behavioral economics; its impact on welfare policy; and ethical implications. This analysis is guided by Foucaults concept of veridiction and understanding of power. This thesis concludes that nudging would be more acceptable if it clarified that humans, in these models, are treated as defective econs. Choice architects are trying to represent the complex reality of hu- man judgment and decision-making with the inclusion of psychology in a highly simplified normative modeling framework, to increase individuals tendency to act according to neo- classical rational choice models.
    [Show full text]
  • How Do Income and the Debt Position of Households Propagate Public Into Private Spending?
    University of Heidelberg Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series No. 676 How Do Income and the Debt Position of Households Propagate Public into Private Spending? Sebastian K. Rüth and Camilla Simon February 2020 How Do Income and the Debt Position of Households Propagate Public into Private Spending? Sebastian K. R¨uth Camilla Simon∗ February 21, 2020 Abstract We study the household sector's post-tax income and debt position as prop- agation mechanisms of public into private spending, in postwar U.S. data. In structural VARs, we obtain the consumption \crowding-in puzzle" for surges in public spending and show this consumption response to be accompanied by a persistent increase in disposable income. Endogenously reacting income, however, is insufficient to rationalize conditional comovement of private and public spending: once we hypothetically force (dis)aggregate measures of in- come to their pre-shock paths, consumption still rises. Corroborating these findings within an external-instruments-identified VAR, which constitutes an adequate laboratory for the simultaneous interplay of financial and macroe- conomic time-series, we provide causal evidence of fiscal stimulus prompting households to take on more credit. This favorable debt cycle is paralleled by dropping interest rates, narrowing credit spreads, and inflating collat- eral prices, e.g., real estate prices, suggesting that softening borrowing con- straints support the accumulation of debt and help rationalizing the absence of crowding-out. Keywords: Government spending shock, household income, household in- debtedness, credit spread, external instrument, fiscal foresight. JEL codes: E30, E62, G51, H31. ∗Respectively: Heidelberg University, Alfred-Weber-Institute for Economics, phone: +49 6221 54 2943, e-mail: [email protected] (corresponding author); University of W¨urzburg,Department of Economics, phone: +49 931 31 85036, e-mail: camilla.simon@uni- wuerzburg.de.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 2 Professor Christina Romer Spring 2019 Professor David Romer LECTURE 20 PLANNED AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE and OUTPUT Ap
    Economics 2 Professor Christina Romer Spring 2019 Professor David Romer LECTURE 20 PLANNED AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND OUTPUT April 11, 2019 I. OVERVIEW OF SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS II. THE KEY ROLE OF DEMAND A. Terminology B. Evidence C. Source III. PLANNED AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE (PAE) A. Components B. Short run versus long run IV. DETERMINANTS OF EACH COMPONENT OF PAE p A. Planned investment (I ) B. Government spending (G) and net exports (NX) C. Consumption (C) 1. Factors that affect consumption 2. The “consumption function” V. DETERMINANTS OF OUTPUT IN THE SHORT RUN A. 45-degree line (Y = PAE) B. Expenditure line (PAE) C. Equilibrium and how the economy gets there D. Short-run versus long-run equilibrium VI. SHIFTS IN THE EXPENDITURE LINE A. Crucial determinant of short-run fluctuations B. Example: A decline in autonomous consumption C. The multiplier effect Economics 2 Christina Romer Spring 2019 David Romer LECTURE 20 Planned Aggregate Expenditure and Output April 11, 2019 Announcements • We have handed out Problem Set 5. • It is due at the start of lecture on Thursday, April 18th. • Problem set work session Monday, April 15th, 6:00–8:00 p.m. in 648 Evans. • Research paper reading for next time. • Romer and Romer, “The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes.” I. OVERVIEW OF SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS Real GDP in the United States, 1948–2018 Source: FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data); data from Bureau of Economic Analysis. Short-Run Fluctuations • Times when output moves above or below potential (booms and recessions). • Recessions are costly and very painful to the people affected. Deviation of GDP from Potential and the Unemployment Rate Unemployment Rate Percent Deviation of GDP from Potential Source: FRED; data from Bureau of Labor Statistics.
    [Show full text]
  • AGGREGATE DEMAND and ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin, Et Al.), 2Nd Edition
    Chapter 24 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2nd Edition Chapter Overview This chapter first introduces the analysis of business cycles, and introduces you to the two stylized facts of the business cycle. The chapter then presents the Classical theory of savings-investment balance through the market for loanable funds. Next, the Keynesian aggregate demand analysis in the form of the traditional "Keynesian Cross" diagram is developed. You will learn what happens when there’s an unexpected fall in spending, and the role of the multiplier in moving to a new equilibrium. Chapter Objectives After reading and reviewing this chapter, you should be able to: 1. Describe how unemployment and inflation are thought to normally behave over the business cycle. 2. Model consumption and investment, the components of aggregate demand in the simple model. 3. Describe the problem that “leakages” present for maintaining aggregate demand, and the classical and Keynesian approaches to leakages. 4. Understand how the equilibrium levels of income, consumption, investment, and savings are determined in the Keynesian model, as presented in equations and graphs. 5. Explain how, in the Keynesian model, the macroeconomy can equilibrate at a less-than-full-employment output level. 6. Describe the workings of “the multiplier,” in words and equations. Key Terms Okun’s “law” behavioral equation “full-employment output” (Y*) marginal propensity to consume aggregate expenditure (AE) marginal propensity to save accounting identity paradox of thrift Chapter 24 – Aggregate Demand and Economic Fluctuations 1 Active Review Fill in the Blank 1. The macroeconomic goal that involves keeping the rate of unemployment and inflation at acceptable levels over the business cycle is the goal of .
    [Show full text]
  • The Macroeconomic Implications of Consumption: State-Of-Art and Prospects for the Heterodox Future Research
    The macroeconomic implications of consumption: state-of-art and prospects for the heterodox future research Lídia Brochier1 and Antonio Carlos Macedo e Silva2 Abstract The recent US economic scenario has motivated a series of heterodox papers concerned with household indebtedness and consumption. Though discussing autonomous consumption, most of the theoretical papers rely on private investment-led growth models. An alternative approach is the so-called Sraffian supermultipler model, which treats long-run investment as induced, allowing for the possibility that other final demand components – including consumption – may lead long-run growth. We suggest that the dialogue between these approaches is not only possible but may prove to be quite fruitful. Keywords: Consumption, household debt, growth theories, autonomous expenditure. JEL classification: B59, E12, E21. 1 PhD Student, University of Campinas (UNICAMP), São Paulo, Brazil. [email protected] 2 Professor at University of Campinas (UNICAMP), São Paulo, Brazil. [email protected] 1 1 Introduction Following Keynes’ famous dictum on investment as the “causa causans” of output and employment levels, macroeconomic literature has tended to depict personal consumption as a well-behaved and rather uninteresting aggregate demand component.3 To be sure, consumption is much less volatile than investment. Does it really mean it is less important? For many Keynesian economists, the answer is – or at least was, until recently – probably positive. At any rate, the American experience has at least demonstrated that consumption is important, and not only because it usually represents more than 60% of GDP. After all, in the U.S., the very ratio between consumption and GDP has been increasing since the 1980s, in spite of the stagnant real labor income and the growing income inequality.
    [Show full text]
  • Macro Model Objectives : Understand the Difference Between Desired
    Macro Model Objectives : Understand the difference between desired expenditure and actual expenditure. Explain the determinants of desired consumption and desired investment expeditures. Understand the meaning of equilibrium national income. Recognize the difference between movements along and shifts of the aggregate expenditure functions. Desired expenditure Everyone makes expenditure decisions. Fortunately, it is unnecessary for our purposes to look at each of the millions of such individual decisions. Instead, it is sufficient to consider four main groups of decision makers. The sum of their desired expenditures on domestically produced output is called desired aggregate expenditure, or more simply aggregate expenditure (AE). AE = C + I +G +(X-M) Autonomus versus induced expenditure. Components of aggregate expenditure that do not depend on national income are called autonomous expenditures. Components of aggregate expenditure that do change in response to changes in national income are called induced expenditures. Global Economics : macro model 2 Important simplifications Our goal is to develop the simplest possible model of national-income determination. To do so we focus on only two of the four components of desired aggregate expenditure. Consumption and investment Desired consumption expenditure By definition, there are only two possible uses of disposable income–consumption and saving. W hen the household decides how much to put to one use, it has automatically decided how much to put to the other use. The consumption function relates to total desired consumption expenditures of all households. The consumption behaviour of households depends on the income that they actually have to spend, which is called disposable income. Under the assumptions, here, there are no governments, therefore no taxes.
    [Show full text]
  • 10Expenditure Multipliers*
    Chapter EXPENDITURE 10 MULTIPLIERS* Key Concepts FIGURE 10.1 The Consumption Function Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans1 5 In the very short run, firms do not change their prices and they sell the amount that is demanded. As a result: 4 ♦ The price level is fixed. ♦ GDP is determined by aggregate demand. 3 Aggregate planned expenditure is the sum of planned consumption expenditure, planned investment, planned Consumption 2 function government purchases, and planned exports minus planned imports. GDP and aggregate planned expenditures have a two- 1 way link: An increase in real GDP increases aggregate planned expenditures, and an increase in aggregate expenditures increases real GDP. 123 45 Consumption expenditure (trillions of 1996 dollars) Consumption expenditure, C, and saving, S, depend on Disposable income (trillions of 1996 dollars) disposable income (disposable income, YD, is income minus taxes plus transfer payments), the real interest ♦ The slope of the consumption function equals the rate, wealth, and expected future income. MPC. The slope of the U.S. consumption function The consumption function is the relationship between is about 0.9. consumption expenditure and disposable income. Fig- ♦ Changes in the real interest rate, wealth, or expected ure 10.1 illustrates a consumption function. future income shift the consumption function. ♦ The amount of consumption when disposable in- Consumption varies when real GDP changes because come is zero ($1 trillion in Figure 10.1) is called changes in real GDP change disposable income. autonomous consumption. Consumption above this The saving function is the relationship between saving amount is called induced consumption. and disposable income. The marginal propensity to ♦ The marginal propensity to consume,,, MPC,,, is save, MPS,,, is the fraction of a change in disposable the fraction of a change in disposable income that is ∆S income that is saved, or MPS = .
    [Show full text]
  • The Wealth Effect in Empirical Life-Cycle Aggregate Consumption Equations
    The Wealth Effect in Empirical Life-Cycle Aggregate Consumption Equations Yash P. Mehra his article presents an empirical model of U.S. consumer spending that relates consumption to labor income and household wealth. This specification is consistent with the life-cycle hypothesis of saving first T 1 popularized in the 1960s by Ando, Modigliani, and their cohorts. My anal- ysis here extends the previous research in several directions. First, I examine the dynamic relationship between consumption, income, and wealth using cointegration and error correction methodology. In previous research, the tra- ditional life-cycle model has often been examined using either levels or first differences of these variables. While the use of differences does avoid the pitfall of spurious correlation due to common trending series, it tends to lead to the omission of the long-run equilibrium (cointegrating) relationships that may exist among levels of these variables. In fact, Gali (1990) goes so far as to present a theoretical life-cycle model that generates a common trend in aggregate consumption, labor income, and wealth. Therefore, my empirical work here tests for the presence of a long-run equilibrium (cointegrating) rela- tionship between the level of aggregate consumer spending and its economic determinants such as labor income and wealth. I then examine the short-run dynamic relationship among these variables using an error correction specifi- cation proposed in Davidson et al. (1978). The present article investigates whether wealth has predictive content for future consumption. If it does, then changes in wealth may lead to changes in The author wishes to thank Huberto Ennis, Pierre Sarte, and Roy Webb for many useful suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 4.Pmd
    Chapter4 Determination of Income and Employment We have so far talked about the national income, price level, rate of interest etc. in an ad hoc manner – without investigating the forces that govern their values. The basic objective of macroeconomics is to develop theoretical tools, called models, capable of describing the processes which determine the values of these variables. Specifically, the models attempt to provide theoretical explanation to questions such as what causes periods of slow growth or recessions in the economy, or increment in the price level, or a rise in unemployment. It is difficult to account for all the variables at the same time. Thus, when we concentrate on the determination of a particular variable, we must hold the values of all other variables constant. This is a stylisation typical of almost any theoretical exercise and is called the assumption of ceteris paribus, which literally means ‘other things remaining equal’. You can think of the procedure as follows – in order to solve for the values of two variables x and y from two equations, we solve for one variable, say x, in terms of y from one equation first, and then substitute this value into the other equation to obtain the complete solution. We apply the same method in the analysis of the macroeconomic system. In this chapter we deal with the determination of National Income under the assumption of fixed price of final goods and constant rate of interest in the economy. The theoretical model used in this chapter is based on the theory given by John Maynard Keynes.
    [Show full text]
  • The Aggregate Expenditure Model a Stylized Look at Business Cycle Dynamics
    The Aggregate Expenditure Model A Stylized Look at Business Cycle Dynamics Elements of Macroeconomics ▪ Johns Hopkins University Outline 1. The Aggregate Expenditure Model 2. An Expanded Aggregate Expenditure Model 3. The Multiplier Effect • Textbook Readings: Ch. 12 Elements of Macroeconomics ▪ Johns Hopkins University From Macro Variables to (Short-Run) Macro Models • The first of three models - The Aggregate Expenditure Model § Solely output variables are in this model • Next class: Aggregate Demand - Aggregate Supply Model § Both output and prices are in this model • Later: Expanded Loanable Funds Model (Monetary Policy) § Output, prices and financial markets are in this model Elements of Macroeconomics ▪ Johns Hopkins University A Quick Review • We have measurements GDP = C + I + G + NX § Consumption: Households purchases of goods and services § Investment: Housing, business investment in equipment, software, buildings plus inventories § Government spending: defense, infrastructure, social security, … § Net exports: Exports minus imports • We need a model § What forces drive the overall economy? Elements of Macroeconomics ▪ Johns Hopkins University What Are We Looking For With This Model? • We acknowledge that boom/bust cycles are regular occurrences • Periodically, we see big imbalances § Millions want jobs, but can’t find them ➞ Unemployment jumps § Millions want to drive cars and trucks ➞ Gasoline prices soar and inflation jumps • We want a model that identifies equilibrium, BUT ALLOWS FOR IMBALANCES Elements of Macroeconomics
    [Show full text]