The National Income Multiplier: Its Theory Its Philosophy Its Utility
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
"Social Accounting Matrices and SAM-Based Multiplier Analysis"
Chapter 14 – Social Accounting Matrices and SAM-based Multiplier Analysis (Round) Chapter 14 Social Accounting Matrices and SAM-based Multiplier Analysis Jeffery Round1 14.1 Introduction This chapter sets out the framework of a social accounting matrix (SAM) and shows how it can be used to construct SAM-based multipliers to analyse the effects of macroeconomic policies on distribution and poverty. Estimates provided by a social accounting matrix (SAM) can be useful - even essential - for calibrating a much broader class of models to do with monitoring poverty and income distribution. But this chapter is limited to a review of how SAMs are used to develop simple economy-wide multipliers for poverty and income distribution analysis. What is a SAM? A SAM is a particular representation of the macro and meso economic accounts of a socio-economic system, which capture the transactions and transfers between all economic agents in the system (Pyatt and Round, 1985; Reinert and Roland-Holst, 1997). In common with other economic accounting systems it records transactions taking place during an accounting period, usually one year. The main features of a SAM are threefold. First, the accounts are represented as a square matrix; where the incomings and outgoings for each account are shown as a corresponding row and column of the matrix. The transactions are shown in the cells, so the matrix displays the interconnections between agents in an explicit way. Second, it is comprehensive, in the sense that it portrays all the economic activities of the system (consumption, production, accumulation and distribution), although not necessarily in equivalent detail. -
On the Concept of Nudging: Its Coherence and Applicability?
On the Concept of Nudging: Its Coherence and Applicability? Mads Wistrup Freund September 15, 2017 25-June-1993-xxxx MSc in Business Administration and Philosophy Vejleder: Marius Gudman Høyer 1 Abstract The practice of nudging has attracted attention from researchers, policymakers, and practitioners alike. The contemporary interest in nudging has sparked demands for a clearer examination of the conditions under which nudging and other behavioral methods can be used efficiently and acceptable. There are several unresolved questions which may have contributed to heated political and scientific discussions, especially heated is the ethical discussion of applying nudging in the public policy domain. This thesis concentrate on the philosophical premises nudges are built on. It is argued that the model is philosophically problematic. Different interventions might operate through various logics that threaten not only effectiveness but also representativeness and ethical ends. This thesis aruges that the next step in advancing the acceptability nudging requires a clarification. The thesis investi- gates the internal logic of this practice by exploring the expositions and implications within the literature on nudging in public policy, by specifically exploring its origins in behavioral economics; its impact on welfare policy; and ethical implications. This analysis is guided by Foucaults concept of veridiction and understanding of power. This thesis concludes that nudging would be more acceptable if it clarified that humans, in these models, are treated as defective econs. Choice architects are trying to represent the complex reality of hu- man judgment and decision-making with the inclusion of psychology in a highly simplified normative modeling framework, to increase individuals tendency to act according to neo- classical rational choice models. -
How Do Income and the Debt Position of Households Propagate Public Into Private Spending?
University of Heidelberg Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series No. 676 How Do Income and the Debt Position of Households Propagate Public into Private Spending? Sebastian K. Rüth and Camilla Simon February 2020 How Do Income and the Debt Position of Households Propagate Public into Private Spending? Sebastian K. R¨uth Camilla Simon∗ February 21, 2020 Abstract We study the household sector's post-tax income and debt position as prop- agation mechanisms of public into private spending, in postwar U.S. data. In structural VARs, we obtain the consumption \crowding-in puzzle" for surges in public spending and show this consumption response to be accompanied by a persistent increase in disposable income. Endogenously reacting income, however, is insufficient to rationalize conditional comovement of private and public spending: once we hypothetically force (dis)aggregate measures of in- come to their pre-shock paths, consumption still rises. Corroborating these findings within an external-instruments-identified VAR, which constitutes an adequate laboratory for the simultaneous interplay of financial and macroe- conomic time-series, we provide causal evidence of fiscal stimulus prompting households to take on more credit. This favorable debt cycle is paralleled by dropping interest rates, narrowing credit spreads, and inflating collat- eral prices, e.g., real estate prices, suggesting that softening borrowing con- straints support the accumulation of debt and help rationalizing the absence of crowding-out. Keywords: Government spending shock, household income, household in- debtedness, credit spread, external instrument, fiscal foresight. JEL codes: E30, E62, G51, H31. ∗Respectively: Heidelberg University, Alfred-Weber-Institute for Economics, phone: +49 6221 54 2943, e-mail: [email protected] (corresponding author); University of W¨urzburg,Department of Economics, phone: +49 931 31 85036, e-mail: camilla.simon@uni- wuerzburg.de. -
The Macroeconomic Implications of Consumption: State-Of-Art and Prospects for the Heterodox Future Research
The macroeconomic implications of consumption: state-of-art and prospects for the heterodox future research Lídia Brochier1 and Antonio Carlos Macedo e Silva2 Abstract The recent US economic scenario has motivated a series of heterodox papers concerned with household indebtedness and consumption. Though discussing autonomous consumption, most of the theoretical papers rely on private investment-led growth models. An alternative approach is the so-called Sraffian supermultipler model, which treats long-run investment as induced, allowing for the possibility that other final demand components – including consumption – may lead long-run growth. We suggest that the dialogue between these approaches is not only possible but may prove to be quite fruitful. Keywords: Consumption, household debt, growth theories, autonomous expenditure. JEL classification: B59, E12, E21. 1 PhD Student, University of Campinas (UNICAMP), São Paulo, Brazil. [email protected] 2 Professor at University of Campinas (UNICAMP), São Paulo, Brazil. [email protected] 1 1 Introduction Following Keynes’ famous dictum on investment as the “causa causans” of output and employment levels, macroeconomic literature has tended to depict personal consumption as a well-behaved and rather uninteresting aggregate demand component.3 To be sure, consumption is much less volatile than investment. Does it really mean it is less important? For many Keynesian economists, the answer is – or at least was, until recently – probably positive. At any rate, the American experience has at least demonstrated that consumption is important, and not only because it usually represents more than 60% of GDP. After all, in the U.S., the very ratio between consumption and GDP has been increasing since the 1980s, in spite of the stagnant real labor income and the growing income inequality. -
Macro Model Objectives : Understand the Difference Between Desired
Macro Model Objectives : Understand the difference between desired expenditure and actual expenditure. Explain the determinants of desired consumption and desired investment expeditures. Understand the meaning of equilibrium national income. Recognize the difference between movements along and shifts of the aggregate expenditure functions. Desired expenditure Everyone makes expenditure decisions. Fortunately, it is unnecessary for our purposes to look at each of the millions of such individual decisions. Instead, it is sufficient to consider four main groups of decision makers. The sum of their desired expenditures on domestically produced output is called desired aggregate expenditure, or more simply aggregate expenditure (AE). AE = C + I +G +(X-M) Autonomus versus induced expenditure. Components of aggregate expenditure that do not depend on national income are called autonomous expenditures. Components of aggregate expenditure that do change in response to changes in national income are called induced expenditures. Global Economics : macro model 2 Important simplifications Our goal is to develop the simplest possible model of national-income determination. To do so we focus on only two of the four components of desired aggregate expenditure. Consumption and investment Desired consumption expenditure By definition, there are only two possible uses of disposable income–consumption and saving. W hen the household decides how much to put to one use, it has automatically decided how much to put to the other use. The consumption function relates to total desired consumption expenditures of all households. The consumption behaviour of households depends on the income that they actually have to spend, which is called disposable income. Under the assumptions, here, there are no governments, therefore no taxes. -
10Expenditure Multipliers*
Chapter EXPENDITURE 10 MULTIPLIERS* Key Concepts FIGURE 10.1 The Consumption Function Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans1 5 In the very short run, firms do not change their prices and they sell the amount that is demanded. As a result: 4 ♦ The price level is fixed. ♦ GDP is determined by aggregate demand. 3 Aggregate planned expenditure is the sum of planned consumption expenditure, planned investment, planned Consumption 2 function government purchases, and planned exports minus planned imports. GDP and aggregate planned expenditures have a two- 1 way link: An increase in real GDP increases aggregate planned expenditures, and an increase in aggregate expenditures increases real GDP. 123 45 Consumption expenditure (trillions of 1996 dollars) Consumption expenditure, C, and saving, S, depend on Disposable income (trillions of 1996 dollars) disposable income (disposable income, YD, is income minus taxes plus transfer payments), the real interest ♦ The slope of the consumption function equals the rate, wealth, and expected future income. MPC. The slope of the U.S. consumption function The consumption function is the relationship between is about 0.9. consumption expenditure and disposable income. Fig- ♦ Changes in the real interest rate, wealth, or expected ure 10.1 illustrates a consumption function. future income shift the consumption function. ♦ The amount of consumption when disposable in- Consumption varies when real GDP changes because come is zero ($1 trillion in Figure 10.1) is called changes in real GDP change disposable income. autonomous consumption. Consumption above this The saving function is the relationship between saving amount is called induced consumption. and disposable income. The marginal propensity to ♦ The marginal propensity to consume,,, MPC,,, is save, MPS,,, is the fraction of a change in disposable the fraction of a change in disposable income that is ∆S income that is saved, or MPS = . -
The Wealth Effect in Empirical Life-Cycle Aggregate Consumption Equations
The Wealth Effect in Empirical Life-Cycle Aggregate Consumption Equations Yash P. Mehra his article presents an empirical model of U.S. consumer spending that relates consumption to labor income and household wealth. This specification is consistent with the life-cycle hypothesis of saving first T 1 popularized in the 1960s by Ando, Modigliani, and their cohorts. My anal- ysis here extends the previous research in several directions. First, I examine the dynamic relationship between consumption, income, and wealth using cointegration and error correction methodology. In previous research, the tra- ditional life-cycle model has often been examined using either levels or first differences of these variables. While the use of differences does avoid the pitfall of spurious correlation due to common trending series, it tends to lead to the omission of the long-run equilibrium (cointegrating) relationships that may exist among levels of these variables. In fact, Gali (1990) goes so far as to present a theoretical life-cycle model that generates a common trend in aggregate consumption, labor income, and wealth. Therefore, my empirical work here tests for the presence of a long-run equilibrium (cointegrating) rela- tionship between the level of aggregate consumer spending and its economic determinants such as labor income and wealth. I then examine the short-run dynamic relationship among these variables using an error correction specifi- cation proposed in Davidson et al. (1978). The present article investigates whether wealth has predictive content for future consumption. If it does, then changes in wealth may lead to changes in The author wishes to thank Huberto Ennis, Pierre Sarte, and Roy Webb for many useful suggestions. -
Circular Flow of Income Compiled from Internet
Circular flow of income Compiled from internet (not my own creation) The circular flow of income is a way of representing the flows of money between the two main groups in society - producers (firms) and consumers (households). These flows are part of the fundamental process of satisfying human wants. As we have already seen, a free market economy consists of two components, or sectors, as they are called. These are firms and households. People in households work for firms (selling their factor services) and receive wages in exchange. On the scale of the whole economy, this is known as national income - the total amount of income earned over a given time period. This money is spent on food, clothing, transport, entertainment etc, and so it returns to the firms. This is the circular flow. Figure 1 Circular flow of income We can see this circular flow in Figure 1. Households sell their factor services to firms (in the factor markets) and in exchange receive wages (the left-hand side of the flow). In the meantime, households spend this income on goods and services (in the goods market) and in exchange receive the goods and services themselves (the right-hand side of the flow). Economists call the wages plus the other forms of income, national income and give it the code 'Y'. Domestic consumption is given the code 'C'. Not all income is spent, however. Some is saved. Savings are coded as 'S'. Other money is used to buy goods or services produced overseas. The money to buy these goods and services flows out of the country. -
The Aggregate Expenditure Model a Stylized Look at Business Cycle Dynamics
The Aggregate Expenditure Model A Stylized Look at Business Cycle Dynamics Elements of Macroeconomics ▪ Johns Hopkins University Outline 1. The Aggregate Expenditure Model 2. An Expanded Aggregate Expenditure Model 3. The Multiplier Effect • Textbook Readings: Ch. 12 Elements of Macroeconomics ▪ Johns Hopkins University From Macro Variables to (Short-Run) Macro Models • The first of three models - The Aggregate Expenditure Model § Solely output variables are in this model • Next class: Aggregate Demand - Aggregate Supply Model § Both output and prices are in this model • Later: Expanded Loanable Funds Model (Monetary Policy) § Output, prices and financial markets are in this model Elements of Macroeconomics ▪ Johns Hopkins University A Quick Review • We have measurements GDP = C + I + G + NX § Consumption: Households purchases of goods and services § Investment: Housing, business investment in equipment, software, buildings plus inventories § Government spending: defense, infrastructure, social security, … § Net exports: Exports minus imports • We need a model § What forces drive the overall economy? Elements of Macroeconomics ▪ Johns Hopkins University What Are We Looking For With This Model? • We acknowledge that boom/bust cycles are regular occurrences • Periodically, we see big imbalances § Millions want jobs, but can’t find them ➞ Unemployment jumps § Millions want to drive cars and trucks ➞ Gasoline prices soar and inflation jumps • We want a model that identifies equilibrium, BUT ALLOWS FOR IMBALANCES Elements of Macroeconomics -
12 Revision – National Income, Circular Flow, Multiplier
●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●● 12 Revision – National income, circular flow, multiplier The main economic goals There are usually five economic main aims for 2. A low level of unemployment government. 3. A low and stable rate of inflation 1. A steady rate of increase of national output 4. A favourable balance of payments position (economic growth) 5. An equitable distribution of income. The circular flow of income model Households INVESTMENT SAVING EXPORTS Expenditure Goods and Factors of Wages, rent, IMPORTS on goods and services production interest, and services profits GOVERNMENT Firms TAXES SPENDING Households provide the factors of production and 2. The income method measures the value of receive income. They buy the goods and services all the incomes earned in the economy. produced by the firms which use the income 3. The expenditure method measures the received, and in this way the income circulates value of all spending on goods and services in throughout the economy. the economy. This is calculated by summing The leakages from the system are savings, taxes up the spending by all the different sectors in and imports. The injections are investment, the economy. government spending and exports. The economy In practice, however, the data that is collected to is in equilibrium when leakages are equal to calculate each of the three values comes from injections. many different and varied sources, and inevitably there will be inaccuracies in the data, leading to imbalances among the final values. Measurement of national income Some of these inaccuracies are the result of the The most commonly used measure of a country’s timing of the data gathering; often figures have national income is gross domestic product (GDP). -
Coronavirus and the Effects on UK GDP
Article Coronavirus and the effects on UK GDP How the global coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic and the wider containment efforts are expected to impact on UK gross domestic product (GDP) as well as some of the challenges that National Statistical Institutes are likely to face. Contact: Release date: Next release: Sumit Dey-Chowdhury 6 May 2020 To be announced [email protected]. uk +44 (0)2075 928622 Table of contents 1. Executive summary 2. Background 3. The circular flow of income 4. The treatment of non-market output in GDP 5. The treatment of the CJRS and SEISS in GDP 6. Practical challenges 7. Publications 8. Conclusions 9. Authors Page 1 of 14 1 . Executive summary Forecasters expect the coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic to lead to a contraction in the UK and global economy this year, reflecting how it has led to a reduction in the demand for goods and services and the impact on the ability of businesses to supply those products. The impact is expected to reflect the length of the pandemic as well as the public health restrictions imposed and other voluntary social distancing measures. The response to COVID-19 will also impact on the ability of National Statistical Institutes (NSIs) to compile estimates of gross domestic product (GDP), inflation and the labour market. We are responding to these challenges so that we capture the economic activity of the UK in line with the latest international guidance. In this article, we describe how those transactions that are most likely to be impacted by the pandemic will be reflected in the production, income and expenditure measures of GDP ( Section 3), including how we have reflected this accordingly in our volume-based estimates of health and education output ( Section 4). -
Measuring Gdp and Economic Growth
MEASURING GDP Objectives AND ECONOMIC CHAPTER GROWTH 20 After studying this chapter, you will able to Define GDP and use the circular flow model to explain why GDP equals aggregate expenditure and aggregate income Explain the two ways of measuring GDP Explain how we measure real GDP and the GDP deflator Explain how we use real GDP to measure economic growth and describe the limitations of our measure © Pearson Education Canada, 2003 © Pearson Education Canada, 2003 An Economic Barometer Gross Domestic Product GDP Defined What exactly is GDP GDP or gross domestic product, is the market value of How do we use it to tell us whether our economy is in a all final goods and services produced in a country in a recession or how rapidly our economy is expanding? given time period. How do we take the effects of inflation out of GDP to This definition has four parts: compare economic well-being over time Market value And how to we compare economic well-being across Final goods and services counties? Produced within a country In a given time period © Pearson Education Canada, 2003 © Pearson Education Canada, 2003 Gross Domestic Product Gross Domestic Product Final goods and services Market value GDP is the value of the final goods and services produced. GDP is a market value—goods and services are valued at their market prices. A final good (or service), is an item bought by its final user during a specified time period. To add apples and oranges, computers and popcorn, we add the market values so we have a total value of output A final good contrasts with an intermediate good, which is in dollars.