<<

MAXIM BOYCKO Russian Center ROBERT W. VISHNY

PrivatizingRussia

WHENANATOLY B. CHUBAIS was put in chargeof the State Committee on the Managementof State Property(GKI) in October 1991,privatiza- tion was not at the top of 's reformagenda. Price liberalization and controlof the budgetwere the top priorities.Politicians and the pub- lic debatedwhether Russia shouldbe privatizingat all before macroeco- nomic problems are solved. No privatizationprogram existed at the time. In fact, the very name of Chubais' agency reflected the govern- ment's ambivalenceabout privatization. A year and a half later, privatizationhas become the most successful reformin Russia. By September1993, more than 20 percent of Russian industrialworkers were employedby privatizedfirms. Privatization has spreadeven more widely in service firms. More than 60 percent of the Russianpeople supportedprivatization, and Chubaishas become one of the betterknown politicians.

[Mostof the datain this paperexist in an unpublishedform in Russianagencies, where they were collectedby the authors.The authorstook care to ensureaccurate transcription of the datain this paper,but it has not been possibleto verifythe dataas is usuallydone in the courseof editingthe paper.-Eds.] DavidFischer and Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes provided excellent research assistance. Some of the resultsreported in this paperuse surveysconducted by JosephBlasi and Ka- tharinaPistor for the StateCommittee on the Managementof StateProperty. We aregrate- ful to StanleyFischer and Jeffrey D. Sachs for theircomments at the BrookingsPanel. 139 140 Brookings Paper-s on Economic Activity, 2:1993

In this paper,we try to describeand evaluate the progressof Russian privatization.Doing so at this point raises the obvious problemof tim- ing. Privatizationin Russia is extremely young. What has been accom- plishedis largelya formaltransfer of ownershipof cash flow and control rights of some firms from the state to private parties. Real changes in the operationsof enterpriseshave barely begun. We cannot, therefore, evaluate the progress of Russian privatizationbased on the actual im- provementsin efficiencyit has delivered.Instead, we need to use a more subjectiveyardstick to evaluate the accomplishmentsof privatization, namely our educated estimate of the likelihood that privatizationwill lead to restructuringof privatizedfirms. We arguethat the key prerequi- site for restructuringis depoliticizationof firms, meaninga change in their conduct from meeting the wishes of politicians to maximizing profits.In this paper, we try to evaluate whetherprivatization in Russia is in fact depoliticizingstate firms. The second section presents our case for looking at depoliticization to predictrestructuring success. We arguethat, in most countries,politi- cians try to influencefirms to pursue political objectives, such as over- hiringor locatingin particularareas. Firms' managersextract subsidies from the treasuryin returnfor addressingthese politicalgoals. The re- sult of this politicizationof firmsis inefficiencyin publicenterprises. We arguethat privatizationis just one of several steps that makeit more ex- pensive for politiciansto influencefirms. As such, privatizationreduces the amountof inefficiencythat firmsaccept to satisfy politicians, but it does not make firms fully efficient. Creatingproduct marketcompeti- tion, improvingcorporate governance, and eliminatingpolitical control of capital allocationare other importantsteps that make political influ- ence more expensive. An importantmessage of the second section is that debates about whetherprivatization, corporatization, or any other single measureis sufficientto make firmsefficient miss the point: these are all partialmeasures of depoliticization. In the thirdsection, we discuss the designof the Russianprivatization programin lightof the objectiveof depoliticization.In particular,we dis- cuss why Russia opted for voucher privatization,rather than for a Pol- ish-style mutualfund scheme. We also show that, quite aside from its objectives, the Russianprogram was to a largeextent shapedby the po- litical constraintson what was feasible. Maxim Boycko, Andr-ei Shleifer, and Rober-t W. Vishny 141

The fourth section presents the basic facts about Russian privatiza- tion, includingsome evidence on its extraordinaryspeed. We also ad- dress an importantpuzzle that the evidence raises, namely the remark- ably low valuationof Russianfirms in the marketplace. In the fifth, sixth, and seventh sections, we look beyond privatization and ask what other mechanismscan reduce politicalinfluence on firms. The fifth section briefly describes the disnial state of product market competitionin Russia. The sixth section examines governanceof firms throughequity ownership. We presentsome surveyevidence suggesting that privatizationin Russia is leading to very significantownership by managersand workers,and some ownershipby largeoutside sharehold- ers. Whilesome managementand outsiderownership is a cause for opti- mism, the extent of insider entrenchmentraises concerns about future restructuring.In the seventh section, we turnto depoliticizationof capi- tal supply mechanisms as a step toward depoliticizationof firms. We firstdescribe the currentcapital allocation mechanisms in Russia, which are still primarilypolitical and dominatedby the financingpractices of the government and the central bank. Commercialbanks are playing only a minorrole in capitalallocation. We also describe the role of mac- roeconomic stabilizationand of foreignaid in depoliticizingcapital allo- cationin Russia. The evidence in the sixth and seventh sections suggests that, in the nearfuture, if capitalallocation is to contributeto depolitici- zation of firms,it shouldavoid the highlypoliticized commercial banks. The eighth section presents some evidence on the politicaleffects of Russian privatization.In particular,we include results suggestingthat privatizationmay have helped PresidentBoris Yeltsin to win the crucial April25 referendum,in which the Russianpeople endorsedhim and the reforms.We conclude in the ninth section by summarizingour findings.

The Goals of Privatization

To focus on the goals of privatization,it is useful to start by asking what is wrongwith publicenterprises and why. On the questionof what is wrong, there is much agreement:public enterprises are inefficient. They employ too many people, produce goods that consumers do not want, locate in economicallyinefficient places, do not upgradetheir cap- 142 Brookings Paper-s on Economic Activity, 2:1993 ital stock, and so on. While these problems are particularlysevere in easternEurope, public enterprisesthroughout the world are conspicu- ous for theirinefficiency, as well. ' This observationis no longercontro- versial. The questionof why public enterprisesare inefficientis harderto an- swer. Standardpublic finance starts with the assumptionthat govern- ments maximize social welfare, and views public enterprisesfrom this vantagepoint. In particular,public enterprisesare supposedlyproduc- tively efficient, and in fact cure monopoly and externality problems caused by privatefirms.2 As a positive theory of public enterprises,this one fails miserably.More recent work has stayed with the assumption of benevolentgovernment, but arguedthat publicenterprises are ineffi- cient because the governmentis poorly informedabout their efficiency, and so rationallysubsidizes them to pursue uncertainprojects.3 These theories mightexplain why governmentssubsidize highly uncertainre- searchand developmentprojects or defense contracts.It does not, how- ever, make much sense as an explanationof the dramaticinefficiency of publicagriculture, coal ,and other relativelyroutine production. The highcosts and inefficienciesof such firmsare publicknowledge, yet the governmentstill does not insist on theirrestructuring. An alternativetheory of public enterpriseargues that they are ineffi- cient because they become the means by which politiciansattain their politicalobjectives.4 Excess employment,location in economicallyinef- ficientplaces, and underpricingof outputall help politiciansget votes or avoid riots. For example, it is plausibleto arguethat the principalobjec- tive of the Russiancommunists was to secure theirown survivalagainst (perceived)external and internalthreats. Manyfeatures of the commu- nist economy follow from this assumption. Russian state enterprises producedso manymilitary goods because the politicianscared about se- curityand not about social welfare. The governmentlavished capitalon militaryfirms at the expense of consumerproduct firms for the same rea- son. The communistgovernment invested resources in public health, but not in healthcare for the elderly, because it needed healthy soldiers,

1. Mueller(1989) and Vining and Boardman(1992) survey the evidence on the relative efficiencyof publicand privatefirms. 2. Atkinsonand Stiglitz(1980). 3. Laffontand Tirole (1993) and Dewatripontand Maskin(1990). 4. A versionof this theoryis presentedin Boycko, Shleifer,and Vishny (1993a). Maxim Boycko, And)rei Shleifer, and Rober-t W. Vishny 143 not because it was humanitarian.The communist government asked firms to overemploy people because it insisted on full employment to prevent social unrest that would threatenits control. The government createdlarge collective farms to control peasants and so avoid the per- ceived threatfrom them. State firmsproduced large farm machineryto ensure that only these large state farms could survive. Thus, a simple view of politicalobjectives can go some way towardexplaining many of the inefficiencies of the Soviet economy. The examples can be multipliedand extended aroundthe world. Publicenterprises are ineffi- cient because their inefficiencyserves the goals of politicians. Except in a pure commandeconomy, managersneed not automati- cally do what politicianswant them to do. Instead, managersand politi- cians bargainover what the firmdoes. Managers'objectives usuallyare closer to profit maximizationthan are those of politicians, if only be- cause managerswant to maximizeresources under their control. To con- vince managersto pursuepolitical objectives, politicianssubsidize firms. In returnfor those subsidies, managershire extra people, locate in eco- nomically inefficientplaces, and so on. Note that the relationshipbe- tween politiciansand managersis best describedas a bargain:managers mightbe the ones who come to the politiciansand beg for money, threat- eningto lay off workersif they do not get funds. But such beggingworks only when politicianscare aboutemployment. Because politicianswant somethingother than profits from firms, bargainingbetween managers andpoliticians results in paymentsfrom governments to firms(subsidies or soft budgetconstraints) in returnfor the desiredinefficiency. This framework has an obvious implication for privatization and other restructuringpolicies. Specifically,the objective of these policies must be to change the terms of trade in the bargainbetween politicians and managers, makingit more expensive for politicians to buy ineffi- ciencies with subsidies. To do that, the cost to the politicianof findinga dollarof subsidies must increase, the ability of that dollarto buy extra inefficiencymust fall, or both. When subsidies become more expensive and less effective, managerswill do less to cater to the objectives of the politicians,and the firmwill begin to restructure.In this paper, we will considerprivatization and other policies from this perspective of depo- liticization. The first question to ask is whether restructuringactually requires privatization:that is, change in the ownership of cash flows of state 144 Br-ookings Paper-s on Economic Activity, 2:1993 firms.It is sometimesargued that all that is really necessary is to change control from politicians to managers:in other words, to corporatize state firms.' Once control changes, cash flows can remain publicly owned as long as managershave some incentives to maximize profits. These incentivesmight come fromincentive contracts for the managers, from productmarket competition, or from hardcredit policies; we dis- cuss these issues later. Indeed, in , many state enterpriseshave begun to restructurein the regime of product marketcompetition and stricter oversight by banks without privatization.6This evidence sug- gests that privatizationof cash flows is not necessary for restructuring when controlis removedfrom politicians. The depoliticizationmodel outlinedabove suggests that corporatiza- tion is one of the key steps that make subsidiesless effective. By shifting controlfrom politiciansto managers,corporatization enables managers to extract more surplusin the bargainwith politicians. Whereasbefore corporatization,politicians could order firms, for example, to employ extra people, after corporatization,they must pay them to do so, which is moreexpensive. Because corporatizationraises the cost to politicians of getting firmsto cater to their wishes, it stimulatesrestructuring. But how much restructuringit stimulates depends on other factors deter- miningthe costs of politicalinfluence. For example, in Polandafter sta- bilization, the combinationof corporatizationand tight budgets signifi- cantly reduced subsidies to firms and stimulated restructuring.In Russia, monetarypolicy is not as tight, and hence the effectiveness of corporatizationby itself would likely be muchlower, because politicians have too much money to influencefirms. More generally, corporatiza- tion has often failed to lead to significantrestructuring because politi- cians have attemptedto regaintheir control over firms.7In a countrylike Russia, where the mechanismsof political influenceare numerousand the politicians'demand for influenceis high, corporatizationby itself is a ratherweak measure.

5. For a discussion of distinctionbetween cash flow rights and control rightsin the characterizationof ownership,see Grossmanand Hart(1986). 6. See Pinto, Belka, and Krajewski(1993) and Blanchardand Dambrowski(1993). 7. Nellis (1988)presents evidence that incentive contracts of managersof publicenter- prises are often repealedwhen managersbegin to restructurein earnestand thus violate the goals of the politicians.After their contracts are repealed,managers are told explicitly not to lay off workers,to continuebuilding plants where politicians want them, and so on. Nellis' examplesillustrate the fragilityof corporatizationas a depoliticizationstrategy. MaximBoycko, Andr-eiShleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 145

Of course, everywhere in the world politicianstry to exert influence over private firms-let alone state enterprises-by offering them pro- curementcontracts, regulatory and tax breaks, and outrightsubsidies in returnfor meeting political objectives. So what does privatizationac- complishthat corporatization does not? How does privatizationdepolit- icize firms? First, when managers and outsider shareholdersreceive substantialcash flow rights,the cost of convincingfirms to be inefficient by pursuingpolitical objectives rises because they now care about the forgone profitsfrom failing to restructure.This incentive effect makes it more expensive for politiciansto get what they want, and hence can accelerate restructuring.Second, in many cases, the mechanismsfor political influenceover firmsare dismantledwhen firmsare privatized. For example, after privatization,ministries are abolished. This change both eliminatesone politicalconstituency that wants to control the firm (the ministry)and makes control by politiciansoperationally more diffi- cult. Third,privatization creates a political constituency of owner-tax- payers who oppose governmentinterference in the economy because it raises theirtaxes and reduces theirprofits; this contributesto depolitici- zation througha politicalmechanism, rather than an economic one. For all these reasons, privatizationby itself is a criticalstrategy of depolitici- zation, and hence restructuring.

Beyond Privatization Importantas privatizationmay be for depoliticization,it is not suffi- cient. Politicianstry and often succeed in gettingprivate firms to pursue political objectives, as well. For example, in Russia, privatized firms still receive subsidies in exchange for keepingup employment.In Italy, many private firmscontinue close relationshipswith politicians. Other measures promotingdepoliticization must complement privatization. This paperwill examinethree criticalstrategies: competition policy, eq- uity governance,and capitalallocation. Throughoutthe world, product market competition plays a critical role in depoliticizingfirms. When firmsface efficient rivals, they must be efficientthemselves to survive in the marketplace,or else be subsi- dized.8But keeping an inefficientfirm in a competitivemarket from go-

8. Hart(1983) presents a formalmodel. 146 Br-ookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 ing bankruptis much more expensive for a politicianthan keeping afloat an inefficientmonopoly that can waste large monopoly rents before it begins to lose money. Unfortunately,politicians realize that competi- tion raises the cost to them of exertinginfluence, and often restrictprod- uct marketcompetition by political action. First, politiciansoften pro- tect domestic firmsfrom both foreignand domestic competition,which of course leaves them with rents that can be dissipatedon politicallyde- sirableactivities. Second, bankruptcyprocedures are often politicized, and hence inefficientfirms are "rehabilitated"rather than allowed to go bankrupt.But when politiciansfail to underminecompetition, restruc- turingbenefits come quickly. Notably, Polandand the Czech Republic have madegreat strides in depoliticizingfirms by creatinga competitive marketplace,both by encouragingdomestic competitionand openingto internationaltrade. The second importantdepoliticization mechanism is equity gover- nance:giving equity ownershipto active decisionmakers.Equity gover- nance of necessity entails significantmanagement ownership. It is also fostered by significantshareholdings by large investors-also referred to as core investors or active investors-who can put pressureon man- agers to restructureand to resist pressures from politicians.9The reli- ance on core investors for governance has characterizedprivatization programsin France, Mexico, and, more recently, the Czech Republic. Unfortunately,politicians can also disruptthe functioningof this gover- nance mechanismas well by preventingoutside shareholdersfrom vot- ing their shares or otherwise exercising their control rights. The thirdkey depoliticizationmechanism is replacingpolitical alloca- tion of capitalwith privateallocation. As long as the allocationof credit in the economy is politicized, the firmsthat cater to politicians, rather than to shareholders,will get credit. Bankruptfirms will simply seek debt relief from the politiciansand satisfy politicalobjectives in return. Even managerswith incentives either throughtheir own ownership or throughpressure from large shareholderswill cater to politiciansin ex- changefor creditsand subsidies. The success of restructuringrelies crit- ically on depoliticizingcredit policies.

9. Shleiferand Vishny (1986) stress the role of largeshareholders in governingfirms in the West. Frydmanand Rapaczynski (1991), Lipton and Sachs (1990),and Blanchardand his colleagues (1991)present privatization schemes that turnon the pivotal role of large shareholdersin deliveringgovernance to privatizingfirms. Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 147

This necessitates two things. First, it requireseliminating soft credits and government subsidies, which have historically been politicians' most effective mechanism of control. But politicians cannot be con- trolledunless money is controlled. Hardeningthe budgetconstraints of firmsrequires macroeconomic stabilization. Second, depoliticizationof capital requires that capital be available on commercialterms. While some restructuringcan occur without much new investment (firmscan lay off some employees, change their product mix using the existing equipment,reduce waste in inventories,and so on), substantialrestruc- turingusually requires capital. Needless to say, such depoliticizationof capital allocation is usually opposed by politicians, who try to control credit policies throughbankruptcy regulation, control of banks, and in- flationaryfinance. But while gettingprivate capital allocation to replace politicalcapital allocation may be the hardesttask, it is perhapsthe most significantfor eventualdepoliticization of firms. To summarize,restructuring the Russianeconomy requiresdepoliti- cization of firms. This strategy must be pursued on many fronts, in- cluding privatization,competition policy, , and capitalallocation. To assess the likely success of the Russianprivatiza- tion, we will need to look at the progresson all these fronts.

Political Goals of Privatization Even though the ultimateeconomic objective of privatizationis re- structuring,privatization is always and everywherea political phenom- enon. The goal of governmentsthat launch privatizationalways is to gain supportfor the reformist(or conservative)politicians. Mass priva- tizationfits this mandateparticularly well because it is perceived by the generalpopulace as the only partof the economic reformthat can unam- biguously benefit them. Unlike price liberalization, monetary tight- ening, and reductionof governmentspending, all of which impose pain- ful costs on some people, privatizationallocates sharesto the people for free or at low prices-typically a popularmeasure. The politicalsupport for privatizationmight even spillover to otherreforms, such as stabiliza- tion. By creatinga class of supportersof reformand reducingthe power of its opponents, privatizationcan change the political balance in the country. 148 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 2:1993

The need to gain supportfor reformis the politicalargument for priva- tizing rapidly.If privatizationis slow, the benefitsto the populationare by definitionsmall, and hence the politicalcapital they buy the reform- ers is small as well. Fast privatizationis privatizationthat offers large political benefits from the start-exactly what a reformistgovernment needs. Criticsof fast privatizationhave arguedthat it creates fast unem- ployment and thus drains the governmentbudget.'0 This can produce both political opposition and economic problemsfor furtherprivatiza- tion. This argumentoverlooks two essential points. First, privatization in eastern Europe is inherentlyvery slow. Slowing it down furtherbe- yond what internalpolitical forces accomplish will stop it altogether. Second, and more important,rapid privatization buys enormouspoliti- cal benefitsand thus allows reformsto deepen.

The Russian Privatization Program

The Russian privatizationprogram was designed to meet the objec- tives discussed above. " Yet it was also designedin an extremelyhostile politicalenvironment. As a result, the programhad to accommodatethe political and economic demandsof various stakeholdersin state firms, so as to get theirsupport or at least precludeactive opposition.The prin- cipal stakeholders included enterprise managers and employees- whose lobbies controlledthe parliamentand who themselves effectively controlled state firms in the transition-and local governments, who gainedmuch of the politicalinfluence over firmsthat the centerlost. The second part of this section explains how these constraints shaped the privatizationprogram.

Description of the Program As a firststep, the programdivided firms into those thatwould be sold primarilyfor cash by the local governmentsand those that would go into the mass privatizationprogram. In this way, most small shops and some

10. See, for example,Aghion and Blanchard(1993). 11. Shleiferand Vishny(1992) and Boycko and Shleifer(1993) present some ideas that went into the program.A legal descriptionis foundin Frydman,Rapaczynski, and Earle (1993). Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Rober-t W. Vishny 149 smaller enterprises were immediately allocated to the local govern- ments, who demandedthe revenues from small-scale privatizationas theirmajor concession (althoughlater, small shops were sold for vouch- ers as well). As a second step, the programdelineated larger firms into those sub- ject to mandatoryprivatization, those subject to privatizationwith the permissionof the privatizationministry, those requiringgovernment ap- provalfor privatization,and those whose privatizationwas prohibited. Mandatoryprivatization included firms in lightindustries, including tex- tiles, food processing, and furniture. Firms requiringGKI approval tended to be somewhatlarger firms, yet not operatingin any of the im- portant strategic industries. Major firms in most strategic industries, such as naturalresources and defense, could only be privatizedwith the agreementof the entire government.Given the antireformistcomposi- tion of the governmentin 1993,this restrictionmeant that these firmsin generalcould not be privatized.Even if some part of their equity could be privatelyowned, control always remainedwith politicians. Finally, some firms, includingthose involved in space exploration,health, and education,could not be privatizedat all. As a thirdstep, all large and medium-sizedfirms (except those in the last list) were to be corporatized.12 Thatis to say, they were to re-register as joint stock companies with all equity owned by the government, adopta corporatecharter, and appointa boardof directors.Initially, the board would include representativesfrom the propertyfund (the gov- ernment'sselling agency), the management,the workers,suppliers, and customers. The corporatizationdecree, signed by PresidentYeltsin in June 1992, was correctly viewed as the first majorstep toward subse- quentprivatization of state firms. In tandemwith corporatization,divisions of state firmshad the right to split off from the holding company and become independent. This provedto be ratherdifficult because of resistancefrom the management of the holdingcompany and the local officials,who preferredto deal with largerfirms. Nonetheless, such splitoffsoccurred in many cases. Once a firm corporatized, its managers and workers got to pick among three privatizationoptions. The first option (variant 1) gave workers 25 percent of the shares of the enterprisefor free, yet made

12. Sachs(1992) makes the argumentsfor corporatization. 150 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 these shares nonvoting.Top managerscould purchase5 percent of the shares at a nominalprice. In addition, after privatization,the workers and the managerscould get an additional10 percent at a 30 percent dis- count to book value through something that resembles an employee stock ownershipplan (ESOP). The second option (variant2) gave man- agersand workers together 51 percentof the equity, all voting, at a nomi- nal price of 1.7 times the July 1992book value of assets. This, of course, representeda very low price relativeto the marketvalue of these assets in a highlyinflationary environment. Workers could pay for these shares in cash, with vouchers (to be discussed later), or throughthe retained earningsof the enterprise,and could pay over some relativelyshort pe- riodof time. As in the firstoption, an additional5 percentof sharescould be obtainedby managersand workersat low prices throughthe ESOP. Finally, a third option (variant3), imposed by the manageriallobby in the parliament,allowed the managersto buy up to 40 percent of the sharesat very low prices if they promisednot to go bankrupt.For a vari- ety of reasons, this option has hardlybeen used. 13 Once the managersand workers selected their benefits option, they could submit a privatizationplan that described how the rest of the shareswere to be sold. Whilesome enterprisesare subjectto mandatory privatization,in practice, the filing of privatizationplans is almost al- ways voluntary. The principalway in which the sale of shares takes place in Russia is throughauctions of sharesfor vouchers. Every person in Russia was offered a privatizationvoucher for a small fee, and most people picked them up. The voucher had a denominationof 10,000ru- bles, was supposed to expire at the end of 1993, and was freely trada- ble.14 This voucher could then be used as the sole allowable means of payment in auctions of shares of privatizingenterprises. Each priva- tizing enterprise enters into its individualvoucher auction in the city where it is headquartered;systems have been built to enable people to buy shares of firmslocated in other cities. Biddingin these auctions is very easy: the principaltype of bid is to submitthe voucher and to get howevermany sharesit buys at the equilibriumprice. Because vouchers are tradable,some investorsacquire blocks of vouchersand bid for large blocks of shares. In a typical company,up to 30 percentof the sharesare

13. See Frydman, Rapaczynski, and Earle (1993, pp. 55-57). 14. See Frydman, Rapaczynski, and Earle (1993, p. 67). Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 151

sold in voucherauctions, althoughsmaller stakes are sold in "strategic" enterprisesthat are privatized. Voucher privatizationis clearly the definingfeature of the Russian program.It was chosen over the alternativemass privatizationscheme using mutualfunds for four reasons, listed in orderof increasingimpor- tance.15 First, a mutualfund scheme would be too difficultto implement in Russia technologically. Second, it was hoped that vouchers would more actively involve people in privatizationby giving them a choice of whatto invest in, and hence makeprivatization more popular to the pub- lic than a mutualfund scheme, which does not involve choice. Third,a mutual fund scheme that imposed large shareholders on managers would have created serious opposition from the manageriallobby, which would have made made implementationof the programdifficult. Fourth, there was a great concern in Russia that large state-sponsored mutualfunds owning large stakes in Russian companieswould become politicized and hence be unable to enforce restructuringpolicies. For these four reasons, Russia gave up the instantlarge shareholderadvan- tage of Polish-style mutualfunds and opted for a voucher privatization program.16 The fate of the shares neither allocated to the workers nor sold in voucher auctions remainsuncertain. About 5 percent of the numberof shares sold in a voucherauction can be later sold by propertyfunds (the local governmentoffices selling the shares)for cash, with the proceeds to be used to offset the expenses of privatization,as well as pay bonuses to bureaucrats.This approachhas proved popularwith propertyfunds thatwant to sell morefor cash they can retain.Another strategy incorpo- ratedinto the privatizationprogram is to sell shares throughinvestment tenders to domestic or foreign investors, where the means of payment would be investment commitments, rather than vouchers or cash. In practice, this strategy has often amountedto a giveaway of shares to managers,their relatives, and friends. In other cases, some shares can, in principle,be retainedby the governmentfor some period of time. In yet other cases, the governmentmight contribute the shares towardin-

15. The case for the mutualfund scheme is presentedby Liptonand Sachs (1990).In the context of Russia, Sachs (1992)suggests that the choice of a mass privatizationpro- gramis not importantas long as that programis actuallyimplemented. 16. A more detaileddiscussion of voucher schemes versus mutualfund schemes is containedin Frydmanand Rapaczynski (1991) and Boycko, Shleifer,and Vishny(1993b). 152 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 dustry associations and financial-industrialgroups; we will discuss this later. In most enterprises,the privatizationof the last 20 or so percentof the shares was not fully specified by the privatizationplan, and hence shares remainin the government-controlledproperty funds.

The Program in Light of the Constraints It Faced The design of the programclearly reflectedthe political constraints. As we show below, most importantstakeholders received majorconces- sions. Local governmentsgained control over small-scaleprivatization, as well as most revenues from it. They would have received revenues from large-scaleprivatization as well, except that the means of payment were vouchers. Most important, voucher auctions were run locally, which gave local governmentssome limitedopportunity to exclude un- desirableoutsiders. Thanksto these concessions, local governmentsin most cases did not resist privatization,although many would have pre- ferredcash to voucherpayments. Workersin enterprisesbeing privatizedreceived the most generous concessions of any privatizationin the world. They have gotten either 25 percent of the firmfor free (plus an ESOP), or 51 percent (plus an ESOP)at a discount. Moreover,they get to choose the privatizationop- tion that the firmchooses in a vote. Withthe benefitof hindsight,work- ers' benefitsin the Russianprivatization appear very high,and may have adverse consequences for governance, as discussed below. It is im- portantto realize, however, that at the time the programwas proposed, the groups in the parliamentdemanding total worker ownership ap- pearedto present the greatestthreat to privatization.Only by makinga coalition with those groups by offering significantworker ownership could the reformerssucceed in defeatingthe manageriallobbies that op- posed privatization. Concessions to the managersdo not appearlarge on the surface, but in truththey are enormous.Although managers' direct ownershipstake is only 5 percent in variant 1-perhaps higher in variant 2-in many cases, managersbuy additionalshares cheaply in voucherauctions or in the aftermarketfrom employees. A much more importantconcession to the managersis that the privatizationprogram does not impose large shareholderson the firm,so managerialindependence in Russia is much greaterthan elsewhere in eastern Europe. Recall that in the Czech Re- Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 153

Table 1. Corporatization Results by July 1, 1993 Corporatizationprocedure Corporatizationmeasure Mandatory Voluntary Subdivisions Total Permissionissued 2,918 6,508 1,237 10,663 Registeredfirms 1,838 4,121 518 6,477 Percentchoosing variant ia 30.6 18.1 11.7 21.0 Percentchoosing variant2b 68.3 80.5 87.3 77.8 Percentchoosing variant3c 1.1 1.4 1.0 1.3

Source: Authors' calculations based on data from the State Committee on the Management of State Property (GKI). a. Gives workers 25 percent of nonvoting shares for free. Managers can purchase 5 percent of the shares at nominal prices. After privatization, workers and managers can acquire an additional 10 percent through an ESOP. b. Gives managers and workers 51 percent of equity, all voting, at a nominal price of 1.7 times the July 1992 book value of assets. An additional 5 percent could be purchased through an ESOP. c. Allows managers to buy up to 40 percent of the shares at low prices if they promise not to go bankrupt. public firms got core investors as part of privatization,and in Poland they are expected to get mutualfunds as blockholders.Because major shareholderswere not forcibly imposed on the privatizationprocess, managerstacitly gained a majorconcession, reflectingtheir parliamen- tary influence,as well as theirde facto controlof enterprises.Insistence on core investors would have arousedstrong opposition from managers and made privatizationimpossible, especially because privatizationin Russia is still effectively discretionary. While grantingconcessions to many importantgroups, the Russian privatizationfailed to address the wishes of the central bureaucracy. The result has been that the bureaucracyhas continued to fight priva- tization every step of the way. Bribingthe bureaucracyis one of the greatestchallenges of any economic reform. In short, the Russian privatizationprogram represents a political compromise reflecting the existing property rights and political influ- ences in the country. The real question is whether, nonetheless, priva- tizationis likely to lead to restructuring.We turnto this question next.

The Progress of Russian Privatization

Table 1 presents the results on corporatization.By July 1, 1993, out of 4,972 large enterprisesslated for mandatoryprivatization, GKI and local privatizationcommittees issued decisions to privatize for 2,918 enterprises,or 59 percent, of which 1,838, or 63 percent were actually 154 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 registered as joint stock companies. In addition, 6,508 enterprises corporatized on a voluntary basis. The apparent enthusiasm for corporatizationamong many small and medium-sizedenterprises sug- gests that workersand managersconcluded that corporatizationwould give them morebenefits and/or better opportunities to keep controlover the enterprisethan small-scaleprivatization. 17 Finally, some 1,237joint stock companieswere formedon the basis of subdivisionsof state enter- prises that separatedfrom their holdingconmpany. Overall, by July 1, 1993,6,477 joint stock companieswere registered. As table 1 shows, in 77.8 percent of the enterprises, workers have chosen variant2, which gives them and the managersvoting control;in 21 percentof enterprises,they have chosen variant1. In most cases, the ostensible reason for choosing variant2 is that otherwise control might revert to outsiders. Workershave chosen variant1 when the enterprise has been too capital-intensivefor workers and their families to afford variant2, or when the relationshipbetween workers and managershas been sufficiently tense that the managersfear giving workers voting shares. Interestingly, variant 3 has hardly ever been chosen, even thoughit would give the largestownership stake to the managers.

Voucher Distribution and Use Between October 1992and January1993, 150million could pick up their vouchers at their local savings banks. The fee for the voucherwas only 25 rubles(5 cents at the prevailingexchange rate). Be- cause, as we explained, privatizationin Russia was much more populist than in the Czech Republic,the idea of charginga reasonableparticipa- tion fee ($35 in the Czech Republic)to eliminate marginallyinterested citizens was rejected. By the end of January1993, almost 97 percent of vouchers had been distributed. Shortlyafter its introduction,the voucher became the first liquid se- curity in Russia. It is actively tradedon dozens of organizedexchanges throughoutthe country. On the largest exchange in , the Rus- sian Commodityand Raw MaterialExchange, the volumeof tradeeasily

17. In small-scaleprivatization in Russia, the main benefitprovided to workersis a cash paymentequaling 30 percentof the priceobtained in the auction.If the workers'col- lective happensto win the auction,workers receive a 30 percentdiscount. Maxim Boycko, Andr-ei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 155

Figure 1. Voucher Prices in Rubles and Dollars, October 22, 1992-July 23, 1993 Rubles Dollars 10,000 A 20 9,000 - 18 8,000 _ 16 7,000 _ Voucherprice 1i4 (left scale) 6,000 I 12 5,000 '- 10

4,000 - 8

3,000 \ I - 6 2,000 -Voucher price -4 scale) 1,000 - ~~~~(right -2 1 1 1 1 1 0 I I 0 Nov. 22 Dec. 18 Jan. 22 Feb. 19 Mar. 19 Apr. 16 May 14 June4 July 9 1992 1992 1993 1993 1993 1993 1993 1993 1993 Source: Authors' calculations based on GKI data. reaches 60,000 to 100,000vouchers per day ($600,000to $1 million at prevailing prices). Apparently, investors willing to participate in voucherauctions do not face majorproblems in assemblinglarge blocks of vouchers. Wide swings in the marketprice of the voucher, as shown in figure1, seem to be easily attributableto politicaldevelopments in Russia.18 The voucherrose brieflyin the second halfof Novemberand earlyDecember 1992,anticipating demand for vouchers from investors in the upcoming closed subscriptionsand voucherauctions. The fall of actingPrime Min- ister Yegor T. Gaidarin mid-Decemberled to a collapse in the voucher market. From Januarythrough April 1993, more than 1,300 voucher auctions notwithstanding,the ruble voucher price stagnated, quickly fallingin dollarterms. The voucherprice doubledshortly after President Yeltsin's victory in the April25 referendum,which revealed strongpub- lic supportfor the economic reform.19

18. The morepuzzling fact thatthe voucherprice is so low is discussedbelow. 19. After PresidentYeltsin disbandedthe Russianparliament and declaredthe new election, the voucherprice more than doubledby early November 1993to 27,000rubles (morethan $20). 156 BerookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 2:1993

Table 2. Voucher Auctions, December 1992-June 1993 Voutcher auction Per-iod statistic December January February Marc/h April May Jutne total Number of enterprises sold 18 105 188 416 582 477 632 2,418 Number of regions participating 8 19 29 51 58 48 61 75 Number of employees (thousands) 47 191 181 651 898 511 692 3,171 Chartercapital sold (millions of rubles) 513 607 1,375 5,318 7,057 4,193 6,102 25,165 Weighted average percent of charter capital sold 17 11 23 20 24 21 23 21 Vouchers accepted (thousands) 158 150 501 2,188 4,854 2,666 3,526 14,043 Weighted average auction rate (shares per voucher) 3.2 4.0 2.7 2.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 Source: Authors'calculations based on GKI data.

The Pace of Voucher Auctions Table2 presents some basic statisticson the pace of voucherauctions in Russia.20Voucher auctions began in December 1992, when eighteen firmswere sold in eight regions. By April, the pace of sales had acceler- ated to include 582 enterprisesin fifty-eightregions. In May, the rate of sales fell because auction preparationshad stopped in April as people waitedout the April25 referendum.In June, sales recoveredto 632 firms in sixty-oneregions, which seems to be a sustainablemonthly rate. Alto- gether, 2,418 firms had been privatizedin voucher auctions by the end of June. One way to look at the pace of sales is by focusing on the numberof employees who work in privatizedcompanies. By the end of June, more than 3.6 million employees worked in firms privatizedin voucher auc- tions, which represents roughly 18 percent of the manufacturinglabor force in Russia. In Marchthrough June, the privatizationrate averaged 700,000employees per month,or about3.5 percentof industrialemploy-

20. Voucherauctions are the best documentedpart of the large-scaleprivatization in Russia. Little aggregateinformation exists aboutthe actualpace of closed subscriptions, in which workersand managersbuy shares accordingto the chosen variant.In the vast majorityof cases, a closed subscriptionprecedes a voucherauction for a given company. Thus, beforea voucherauction, some 40 to 51 percentof sharesof a typicalcompany have alreadybeen sold. MaximBoycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 157 ment. If this rate continuesto the end of 1993,another 4 millionRussian industrialworkers will end up in the private sector, so that the total will amountto about40 percentof manufacturingemployment. This is rather fast for one year of privatizationin a countrywhere no other reformhas worked.21 An averagefirm whose sharesare auctionedhas about 1,300employ- ees and 50 millionrubles of chartercapital. It sells about 22 percent of its shares(11 millionrubles of chartercapital) in the auction,in exchange for about 5,300 vouchers. In terms of numbers, medium-sizedfirms dominate:71 percentof firmsprivatized through voucher auctions have fewer than 1,000 employees. However, large firms account for a very large share of privatizedassets and employment.Firms with more than 1,000 employees account for 83 percent of employmentand 86 percent of assets of enterprisesprivatized through voucher auctions. As table 3 suggests, largefirms on averageprivatize somewhat faster thanmedium and smallfirms.

Asset Values One of the most interestingaspects of voucher auctions is the prices at which assets sell. Table 2 shows that the numberof shares (each with a book value of 1,000rubles) received per voucher startedout at around 3 or 4 at the turnof the year, and fell toward 1.5 in Apriland May before recoveringto 1.7 in June. To interpretthese numbers,we can convert them into a dollarprice per share. Because vouchers are tradedin Rus- sia, we can convert shareprices from vouchers to rubles.Figure 1 shows a time series of voucherprices in both currencies.Because the rublehas been freely convertible in 1993, we can then convert ruble prices into dollars. Using this information,we have calculated that, in April and May, the averagedollar value of 1,000rubles of chartercapital acquired in a voucherauction was around$3 and rose to $5 in June. A rough computationsuggests what these numbersimply. Suppose that enterprisesthat were privatizedby July 1993are representativeof the Russian industry(this is not a perfect assumptionbecause none of the most valuable naturalresource industries have been privatized).

21. ThroughOctober 1993, 5,925 enterprises had been privatized,with a totalemploy- ment of 6.35 millionworkers, or about 32 percentof the industriallabor force. Thus the goal of 40 percentby the end of 1993appears solidly within reach. ?C as "C r-

n - t-k 0

4.)

e 9 0'c ~ro o - oC 0

I- ~ S:.0 15~

00

0 tD* *0 o

- > ?o ' , o 0.0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C

-. E 00=o 8 ?r- . V 0 , Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 159

These enterprisesconstitute about 15 percent of the Russian industry, and approximately20 percent of the value of these enterpriseshas been sold in voucher auctions. That is, a total of 3 percent of all equity was sold throughJune 1993.As table 2 indicates, about 15 millionvouchers were accepted for this equity, with a price per voucher consistently be- low $10. Because most transactionstook place in later months, an opti- mistic estimate of the dollarvalue of accepted vouchers is $150 million. That puts the total value of the Russian industryat about $5 billion. It is possible to make these calculationsdifferently and to come up with numbersas high as $10 billion. The point, however, is inescapable:the entireRussian industrial complex is valued in voucherauctions at some- thinglike the value of a large Fortune500 company. Perhapsan even more dramaticway to look at the numbersis to ex- aminethe prices in some focal transactions.Table 4 presents the results of voucher auctions and lists the implieddollar values of the ten largest companiesby employmentand the ten most valuabletransactions. The market value of ZIL, the truck and limousine maker with more than 100,000employees, with a ready marketfor as much of its productas it can make, and with a large chunk of Moscow real estate, is about $16 million. The market values of Uralmash and Permsky Motors, two household names in Russian manufacturing,are $4 million and $6 mil- lion, respectively. The Caterpillarand GeneralElectric of Russianman- ufacturingthus appearto be virtuallyworthless. The list of most valuablecompanies contains some new names. Next to ZIL, the most valuable company is Hotel MINSK in the center of Moscow (with 154 employees), whose managementmade a futile at- temptto keep the price of shareslow by disguisingthe name of the com- pany (presumablythey wanted to buy more sharesthemselves). A Mos- cow chocolate factory with 1,500 employees is worth 50 percent more than Uralmash,with 34,000. Some businesses do have value, although the overall level of prices is quite low. One way to calibratehow low the prices of manufacturingcompanies are is to note that U.S. manufacturingcompanies have marketvalue of about $100,000 per employee. Russian manufacturingcompanies, in contrast, have marketvalue of about $100 per employee-a 1,000-fold difference! Whatmight explain such a low price level of Russianassets? The first hypothesisis that most of these firmsreally are worthless, because they 160 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993

Table 4. Ten Largest Enterprises Sold in Voucher Auctions by Employment and by Value as of July 1, 1993 Implied dollar Monthof value of Employees Name of enterprise Induistiy sale enterprise Ten largest enterprisesby emnployment 103,000 ZIL Truck manufacturing April 15,857,826 44,817 Preobrazhenskaya Fishing April 118,477 42,928 Rostselmash Automobile manufacturing April 771,477 35,000 Permsky Motors Engine manufacturing March 6,276,015 34,041 Uralmash Machine production April 3,908,214 32,769 Zapadno-Sibirsky Metallurgical Metal production March 3,890,820 27,351 Ribinsky Motors Aircraft engines March 988,241 26,417 Volgograd Tractor Factory Tractor manufacturing March 570,747 24,198 Pervouralsky Novotrubny Metal production April 2,548,514 17,942 Dalnevostochnoi Morskoi Shipping April Parochodstvo Ten largest enterprisesby implieddollar value 103,000 ZIL Truck manufacturing April 15,857,826 154 Na Tverskoi Hotels May 8,412,378 8,056 Sayan Aluminum Plant Aluminum production December 6,716,613 35,000 Permsky Motors Engine manufacturing March 6,276,015 1,490 Russian Chocolate Factory Chocolate production January 5,724,558 34,041 Uralmash Machine production April 3,908,214 32,769 Zapadno-Sibirsky Metallurgical Metal production March 3,890,820 16,500 Vladimir Tractor Factory Tractor manufacturing March 3,692,419 10,373 Bratsky Aluminum Factory Aluminum production May 3,597,752 4,940 Koksokhim Chemical production May 3,343,053 Source: Authors'calculations based on GKI data. have a very outdatedcapital stock. We submit, however, that this hy- pothesis goes only partof the way in explainingthe pricing.Consider the following rough calculation. At the purchasing-power-parityvalue of the dollar of about 300 rubles, Russian manufacturingwages average about$200 per month, which is aboutone-tenth of Westernmanufactur- ing wages. In fact, estimates of the Russian standardof living as about one-tenththe Westernstandard are suggestedby more detailedcalcula- tions. If the value of the Russiancompanies were in the same proportion to wages as it is in the West, then these companiesshould be worthabout one-tenthof what theirWestern counterparts are worth. On this calcula- tion, the value ratio of 1,000still seems implausible. The low qualityof Russian assets thus fails to explain their low mar- ket value by a factor of 100. Additionalexplanations are needed. One line of argumentis that privatewealth in Russia is limited,and hence the Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 161 low value of assets is explained by this low value of private wealth, whichtranslates into the low value of the voucher.This theoryis implau- sible once it is realizedthat there was perhaps$15 billionof capitalflight from Russia in 1992.22 Moreover, foreigners can participatefreely in voucherauctions, which again raises the availablepool of capital. Why wouldn'ta foreign investor buy 20 percent of ZIL for $3 million, when foreigners are paying billions for automobile and truck companies in easternEurope? The capital shortagestory cannotplausibly explain the low valuation. The plausibleexplanations fall under a general category: expropria- tion of shareholdersby stakeholders.That is, while assets themselves have some value, the part of the returnto these assets that is expected to accrueto outside shareholdersafter the stakeholdershave taken their own cut is very small. Three importanttypes of stakeholderstake a cut. The first is employees. As one very progressive Russian managerhas put it, the goal of his privatizedcompany is to raise its efficiency and makeprofits so that it can increasewages. ManyRussian firms continue to pay for kindergartens,hospitals, schools, and other services for their workers. There is little doubt that, particularlywith the high levels of employee ownershipin Russiancompanies, some of the profitswill con- tinue to be spent on wages and benefits to the workers. One sobering fact in this regardis the experience of the Germanprivatization agency, Treuhandanstalt.Because it had to make up-frontpayments to buyers to get them to agree to maintainemployment after privatization,the agency experienceda net loss of $200 billion from its sale of firms. The cost was so large because of the excessive wages that eastern German companieshad to pay theirworkers after privatization. Even so, the dra- maticlosses reflectthe extraordinaryvalue of workers'claims even in a countrylike Germany,where, unlike Russia, workers are not majority owners of firms. The second importantset of stakeholdersis managers,who are likely to expropriateshareholder wealth throughasset sales to their own pri- vately held businesses and other forms of dilution. This theft by man- agers is probablythe principalreason for the remarkablyhigh capital flightfrom Russia. As we will explainfurther below, shareholderrights

22. See CelesteBohlen, "BillionsBleed Outof RussiaAs Its WealthIs Sent Abroad," New YorkTimes, , 1993,p. Al. 162 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 in Russia are not protected, and few companiesexpect to pay dividends in the nearfuture, leaving more for managersto take. The last stakeholderresponsible for reducingfirm value to outside shareholdersis the government,which expropriatesfirm value through taxes, regulations,restrictions on productmix and layoffs, custom du- ties, and many other interventions,including potential nationalization. The fear of governmentexpropriation is often referredto as politicalin- stability,and surelyexplains some of the low value to outside sharehold- ers. Of course, expropriationof shareholdersby the governmentis noth- ing other than continued politicization of now-privatized firms. Evidently, the Russianmarket estimates that such politicizationis likely to continue so that, among them, the three types of stakeholderswill grababout 99 percentof shareholderwealth.23 In sum, voucher auctions have been a great success and have helped move a substantialpart of the Russian industryinto the private sector, even thoughthe impliedasset values have been very low. The next ques- tion is whetherrapid privatization is likely to lead to restructuring.

Product Market Competition

In the second section, we arguedthat privatizationis only one of sev- eral steps needed to depoliticize Russian firms. In the next three sec- tions, we discuss the other steps, beginningwith productmarket compe- tition. As we argued above, product market competition is extremely importantin raisingthe cost to politiciansof influencingfirms. For this reason, competition strategy, includingfacilitation of entry and open- ness to imports, has been a critical reform strategy in Poland and the Czech Republic. Unlike these countries, Russia has not had much suc- cess with competition as a depoliticization strategy, both because it startedout with an extremelyuncompetitive economy and because poli- cies failed to foster competition. Russia inheritedfrom centralplanning a highly uncompetitiveecon- omy. To facilitate centralcontrol, most industrieswere highly concen-

23. FollowingYeltsin's victory over the parliamentin October1993, the voucherprice doubledto more than $20. Even with this increase, the total value of Russianassets re- mains very low. Nevertheless, the event demonstratesthat the possible increase in the securityof propertythat accompanied the demiseof the parliamentdoubled the valuation of assets. Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 163 trated.24Import penetration in most sectors has been extremelylow, and trade collapsed with the collapse of .Finally, centralplan- ners have establishedvery rigidsupply chains and builta transportation and storagesystem to matchthese rigidsupply chains. As a result, most Russian firms, even if they were not unique producers of particular goods, bought their inputs only from specifically designated suppliers and sold their outputs only to specifically designated customers. No competition worked or could easily begin to work in most goods markets. Of course, competitionpolicy could address these problems. Unfor- tunately, in Russia, such policy has done the reverse. Moscow bureau- crats-whose personalfinancial concerns have not been allayed by pri- vatization-have plottedto resurrecttheir ministries in the formof trade associations and financial-industrialgroups, so as to facilitateboth col- lusion and subsidizedfinance from the central bank. To this end, they have triedto consolidate, ratherthan break up, firms.Nor is there much talk about opening up foreign trade and stimulatingcompetition in this way: existing firmsrarely fail to get protection. Even at the local level, where competitioncould probablybe the single most reliablestrategy of depoliticization,politicians have restrictedit. Many local governments have already taken actions to protect incumbent firms from entry through licensing and other anticompetitive strategies. The Russian antimonopolycommittee has been capturedby the interestsof bureauc- racy and managersfearing competition. It has no interestin breakingup large firms or encouragingentry. It has shown a strong interest in pre- venting privatizationof those firms with market power (that is, most firms)on the groundsthat it is easier to regulateprices of state firms. In fact, the antimonopolycommittee arguedfor the consolidationof firms into monopoliesso as to makeprice regulationeasier. Finally,privatiza- tion of transport,which may be the singlemost effective procompetition strategy,has been slow in most regions. Moreover, competition is most effective when companies that lose money actually go bankrupt. The Russian bankruptcy law, written underclose supervisionof the manageriallobby, allows for effectively

24. JointStudy (1991)presents some evidence on industrialconcentration in the Rus- sianeconomy. Brown, Ickes, andRyterman (1993), however, argue that the Russianecon- omy is no moreconcentrated than the U.S. economy, and simplydoes not have as many smallfirms. @3=s 4 CoNC, - - - e - - - c

h5 o) kO O O- oOoo(a OOooa)oo (a ( o

2 N 0000 co N

e

0 =o _ 0kN ^ c m o m c o N ~ r- 2h 2

to ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~0 o O St.

X X ^ o ookr) okr ookr o7 (7 -C -C eq o _ _- 0 o r 00 o1 tx 1 It c

0

t 0 0 0 ' 00 0 0 t- 0 S ^ o N o oN oN o oo o0 ~~~~~~~~~~ U~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~. 0

cuc

rA co~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~cri0 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 ~~~~~~~~J ~~~~~~Ck en en eq eq en kf en k) en | t00t 4)-?>n co r

U)

0 > 4- v 4- M~~~~~~~U Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 165 permanent"rehabilitation" of bankruptcompanies under existing man- agement.In partas a response to this law, and in partas consequence of a long history of borrowingfrom the government, Russian companies rarelyrepay their debts. As long as debts and negativecash flows do not result in hardshipsfor the managementbut simply lead to help from the government,depoliticization will remainan elusive goal. This leaves us with a fairly pessimistic view of the role of product marketcompetition in depoliticizingRussian firms in the nearfuture, de- spite the fact that free trade, free entry, and other policies promoting competition have been essential in depoliticizingfirms in eastern Eu- rope. While we argue below that other depoliticizationstrategies have workedbetter in Russia, competitionpolicy remainsa gapinghole in the reforms.

Corporate Governance through Equity Ownership

In discussing equity governance, we will distinguishbetween man- agement and outside shareholderownership. As we arguedin the sec- ond section, managementownership works as a governance device when managersrefuse to cater to the preferencesof the politicians.Ide- ally, managersmust have high ownership stakes, yet at the same time not be completely entrenched, so that outside investors can oust them when they fail to maximizeprofits. To begin, we brieflydiscuss the evo- lution of managementownership in Russia. Systematic data on managementand other shareholderownership in Russia do not exist. Two researchersworking at GKI, Joseph Blasi and KatharinaPistor, have conducted small surveys of firmsthat ask man- agers about the ownershipstructure of their firms. The surveys ask not only about the results of voucher auctions, but about the actual owner- ship structurethat emerges after some tradingof shares. Tables 5 and 6 present the preliminaryresults of these two surveys, which together cover fifty-five firms. The data in these surveys are self-reportedand hence in some cases may be incorrect.Nonetheless, the overall results presenta very clear picture. In the Blasi sample, shown in table 5, between closed subscription, ESOPs, and subsequentacquisition of shares, managersand workers to- getherend up owning an averageof 70 percentof the company. Of that, -o ------

or

0t 0 srIto oo q 1 C c q E wo

U: U - N ~~~~C~C- C t- C~ C~ C - C~ C~ C Co

.= = ? N C C m C t ~~CICC-CCC C

?4 N? --OO O~~~~o tO-ON o =~~~~~~~Z tl W

0s I o t0 - ^ dt- m ?O t- 00O 'o O - t 00 - 00 oo

2

, 00Or?~0 N ci N icic

ci c ci c ci ci ci ci c ci c c ci ci

0 00o en 'fVo oC 0 0 Ci 00 00 O

ci ci~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~c co co Co Co Co Ct Co c cl cl c) cl l oo eq

000000 t' %c 000tk 000000) 0 0

kf e C es k ()n_N N en N o _

. 0

* q . * . . en . * 0

r 0

-. o

.c0

o 0g.x D XoU 168 Br-ookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 about 17 percent on average is owned by the managementteam, of which about 7 percent on average (and less than 3 percent if one com- pany is excluded)is owned by the CEO. The ownershipof the additional shares is divided between outsiders and the propertyfund (the govern- ment), with the outsidersowning an averageof 14percent and the prop- erty fund owning an average of 16 percent. Note that in many cases a good chunkof the shares of the propertyfund is claimed. In many com- panies, 10percent of the propertyfund sharesare goingto be transferred to the ESOP, and in a few cases, such as ZIL, an investmenttender is planned. Thus the 70 percent figure probably underestimatesinsider ownership. Pistor's sample, shown in table 6, covers largerfirms than Blasi's but also oversamplesa few specialized regions. For example, Pistor's sam- ple includes six firms(observations 19-24) from the Ivanovo textile re- gion, which had peculiar variant 1 privatizationswith virtuallyno out- side investors. Nonetheless, Pistor's results are surprisinglysimilar to Blasi's. On average, managementand workers in her sample together own about 61 percent of the equity. Her data do not allow us to divide this between managersand workers. Outsiderson averageown about 19 percent, as does the property fund. Pistor's sample appears to have fewer completed ESOP transactions, so property fund ownership is likely to fall. Pistor's sample thus confirmsthe overwhelminginsider ownershipof Russianfirms. The evidence suggests that managementteams end up owning con- siderablymore than they get in the closed subscription.They usuallyget 5 to 10 percent of the sharesof theircompanies from the combinationof the subsidized distributionand shares they get throughthe ESOPs. In Blasi's data, however, they end up with 17 percent, on average, even though ESOPs have not yet been distributedin most companies. Man- agers usually try to enhance their ownership stake by buying more shares both in the voucher auctions and from workers. Sometimes the managersget loans from the companyto supplementtheir stakes. In the end, managersend up with much higherownership than they got in the closed subscription. High as the managerialownership of cash flows is, it probablyunder- estimates their degree of control. Indeed, managersin most companies aggressively consolidatedtheir control beyond that warrantedby their ownershipof sharesby gettingworkers' voting support either informally Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 169 or throughformal trust arrangements.In several takeover situations, managerssucceeded in keeping theirjobs only because of worker sup- port. In many companies, managersactually encourage workers to buy more shares to consolidatetheir own control. This emergingpicture of workersas allies of the managers-who not only fail to provideany monitoringof the managers,but actuallycontrib- ute to theirentrenchment-is uniquein Russia. In Polandand elsewhere in easternEurope, workers' collectives often counterbalancemanagers' control-although not necessarily with the best results for restructur- ing. In Russia, in contrast, workers' collectives appear to be passive, althoughof course this passivity mightbe a reciprocationfor highly ac- commodatingmanagerial practices. Thus, while worker passivity al- layed the fears of many who worried about worker control, the price managerspay for workersupport may well be the slowdown of restruc- turing.The greatestfear is that when credit constraintsbegin to tighten, workers will become naturalallies of politicians in preventingrestruc- turing,and thus will disruptdepoliticization of firms. In sum, Russianmanagers are often emergingfrom privatization with quite substantialownership of cash flows. They are also emergingwith a tremendousamount of control, particularlybecause of their influence over workers' collectives. In smallercompanies, this ownershipstruc- ture may well be efficient because it provides managerswith a strong incentive to maximize profits, as long as they do not get capturedby workers'collectives. In the largestcompanies, however, some external checks are needed on managersto preventtheir entrenchmentand cap- ture by politicians. Table5 providessome data on largeshareholders from the Blasi sam- ple. On average, about 14 percent of the shares is owned by outside in- vestors. Of that, about9.5 percentis owned by blockholderswhom man- agers were willing to identify to the interviewer.Thus, in this sample, blockholdersacquire almost two-thirdsof the shares that outsiders get in the voucher auctions (recall that managersand workers also partici- pate actively). Pistor's data in table 6 presenta similarpicture. Of the 19 percent of shares owned by outsiders in the companies in her sample, about 10.6 percent on average is owned by blockholders. In Pistor's sample, investmenttenders have been completed more frequentlythan in Blasi's, and so the blockholders have gotten their shares through those, as well as throughvoucher auctions. 170 Brookings Paper-s on Economic Activity, 2:1993

Evidencefrom the largestcompanies, where blockholdersare partic- ularlyimportant for restructuring,suggests an even greaterpresence. In ZIL, the largest Russian enterpriseprivatized so far, out of the 30 per- cent of shares offered in a voucher auction, 28 percent were bought by seven largeinvestors. Moreover,all these investorsappear to have busi- ness ties, so ZIL might end up with a single shareholdercontrolling 25 to 30 percentof the shares. A privatecompany holds an 18percent stake in Uralmash, another industrialgiant. A Russian graduateof Harvard Business School boughta 6 percent stake in his formeremployer, Vladi- mirTractor Works, and tried to become the CEO. AlphaCapital, an ag- gressive investment fund, bought a 10 percent stake in the Bolshevik cake factory. Similarstories can be told about other well-knownpriva- tizations. This evidence underscoresthe importanceof voucher tradabilityfor the formation of blockholdings in Russia. Accumulating blocks of vouchers and then bidding them in a voucher auction is the principal strategyby which potentiallarge investors can get theirblocks. Without voucher tradability,the only strategies for accumulatinglarge blocks would be to startan investmentfund, which some largeblockholders are clearlydoing, or to buy sharesin the aftermarket,which is very difficult. The creationof a liquidmarket for vouchershas enabledthe Russianpri- vatization to do what for political reasons it could not accomplish di- rectly: to create core investorsfor many majorcompanies. Who are these large blockholdersin Russia? They appear to be of three types. The firstis privatevoucher investmentfunds that were cre- ated followingthe Czech model. These funds collect vouchers from the population in exchange for their own shares and then invest them throughvoucher auctions. GKI evidence indicatesthat so far 550 funds have been formed. They have 12 million shareholdersand have col- lected 25 million vouchers, or one-sixth of the total. The largest funds are located in Moscow: the three largesthad 1.8 million, 1.1 million,and 0.95 millionvouchers, respectively, at the end of June 1993. Whatdo the funds do with the vouchers?Apparently, about one-third of the vouchers have been invested in privatizingcompanies. But until recently, funds were also actively speculatingin vouchers, buying and selling them across Russia to take advantageof price differencesacross space and time. Most Russian funds appeardisinterested in corporate governance. But some funds, led by Alpha Capital, the second largest Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 171 fund, have acquiredlarge stakes in several companiesand have actively challengedthe management.This corporategovernance role of invest- ment funds is only likely to increase. The second type of largeinvestor consists of wealthy individualsand private firmsthat made their fortunes in the last few years in trade and othercommercial activities. These investorsoften have the financialand perhaps even the physical muscle to stand up to the managers.While managerstry to discouragethese investors, in some cases, their pres- ence is clear: these investors, for example, purchasedthe largest share of ZIL, Uralmash,and VladimirTractor Works. The thirdcategory of large investors is foreigners.To them, the mar- ket prices in voucher auctions present a majorattraction. At the same time, they do not usually openly challenge the managers,for fear of a politicalreaction. Indeed, they usuallyacquire their stakes throughRus- sian intermediaries.Foreign investors are still insignificantrelative to other large shareholders,but they mightcome to play an importantrole in restructuring. Anecdotal evidence suggests that large shareholdersoften try to use their votes to change company policies, althoughless often to change management.Alpha Capital,for example, has startedcampaigns to get firmsit invested in to pay dividends.Other large investors want firmsto sell some of theirland holdings. In some cases, such as VladimirTractor Works, an outside investor offered his candidacyto run the company, but lost to the incumbentmanager. So far, corporate managershave resisted these challenges fiercely and rathersuccessfully. Managersthreaten the workerswith dismissals if they do not supportthe incumbent,and appear to be gettingthe critical worker support. But managersalso physically threatenchallengers at shareholdermeetings, rig shareholdervotes, illegally change corporate charters(from one share-one vote to one shareholder-onevote, for ex- ample),refuse to recordshare trades in corporateshare registers, and so on. Most of these activities are not reportedin the press. The current situationis best describedas a stalemate:large outside shareholdersare clearlyposing a challengeto the existingmanagement, but management, in turn,often with the supportof the workers,has managedto repel most threats.The marketfor corporatecontrol in Russia is very lively; it re- mains to be seen whether it is effective enough to get restructuring going. 172 Br-ookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993

The key questionis whetherthe largeshareholders will be able to play their role without being stopped by the political process. Many man- agers are appealingto the local governmentsand to the centralgovern- ment to restrainlarge investors. The managementof Bolshevik has un- successfully lobbied GKI to force Alpha Capital, its large investor, to sell its shares. The governmentof PrimorskyKrai (the southeasternsea- coast region of Russia) has temporarilystopped privatizationafter a couple of enterprisemanagers were sacked in a shareholdervote. And perhaps in the most extraordinaryaction so far, the head of ZIL, the ubiquitoustruck maker, has appealed to PresidentYeltsin to keep the government'scontrol of the companythrough a "goldenshare" (with no dividend rights and a veto power over major restructuringdecisions) that will be kept by the government,thus eliminatingthe controllingin- fluenceof the outside investors. In sum, the transitionfrom political to private governanceis clearly very painful. Politicians do not give up their control over enterprises very easily. They have resisted privatizationfrom the start,and they are still tryingto bringfirms under the control of industryassociations and financial-industrialgroups. Moreover,the residualequity stakes that re- main in the hands of propertyfunds may well be used in the future to reassertpolitical control over enterprises. As political governancerecedes, it is replacedto a significantextent by managerialcontrol. Such control is betterthan controlby politicians because managerswith significantownership stakes have more interest in value maximizationand restructuring.Nonetheless, in many cases, managerialownership needs to be supplementedby largeoutsider own- ership to put pressure on the managersand workers' collectives to re- structure.As of now, large outside shareholdersface tremendousresis- tance from both managers and politicians in exercising their control rights. Still, they remain the most effective source of external gover- nancein Russia. In the future,their role will increasewhen they become a source of capital, and notjust oversight.

Capital Allocation

Effective restructuringis thwartedby political allocation of capital. When politicianslavish capital on some firmsbecause they want them MaximBoycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 173 to maintainhigh output and employment,these firmshave no incentive to restructure,even if they have made headway in other dimensionsof depoliticization.Moreover, firms that do not get capital as part of the politicalallocation can achieve only limitedrestructuring, because sub- stantialrestructuring usually requirescapital. In this section, we show that capital allocation in Russia now is completely politicized and sug- gest some strategiesfor improvingthis dismal situation.

Current Capital Allocation Most capitalof Russian enterprisesstill comes from the state, which includes both subsidies from the budget and directed credits from the centralbank. In 1992,total subsidiesfrom the budgetaccounted for 21.6 percent of GDP.25Most of these subsidies went to enterprisesand in- cluded importsubsidies, energy subsidies, and subsidiesfor makingin- terest paymentson alreadysubsidized credits. Directedcredits from the centralbank to enterprisesadded up to an additional21 percentof GDP. Agriculturewas the principalbeneficiary of these directed credits, tak- ing up 7.5 percentof GDP, but energy and industryreceived substantial subsidies as well. Creditexpanded very rapidlyin the beginningof 1993 but slowed down by mid-1993.26 The allocationof credits and subsidies is highly politicized, in terms of who benefits and by how much. Agriculture,energy, and very large manufacturingfirms are the main beneficiariesof the governmentand centralbank policies. Firmsfortunate enough to get credits throughthe centralbank obtain them at negative real interest rates. In addition,the governmentoften subsidizes the enterprise's interest payments to the central bank. Finally, enterprisesoften do not repay the loans, except from proceeds from the new loans. Thus, the combinationof subsidies and loans reallocates massive resources to some sectors of the econ- omy. It is not surprising,in this regard,that Russia has madeno progress in privatizingagriculture: what farmer would take the fat of the landover that of the centralbank? In its allocationof credit, the central bank does not discriminatebe- tween state-owned and privatized firms. All firms deemed worthy of

25. Datain this section come fromWorld Bank (1993a, 1993b). 26. Sachs (1993)discusses recentRussian monetary policies. 174 Br-ookings Paper-s on Economic Activity, 2:1993 creditsget them.27This, of course, does not bode well for the effective- ness of privatizationin gettingrestructuring going. Centralbank credits are channeledthrough commercial banks. Many of the banks are descendantsof formerSoviet sectoral banks, in which case they simply allocate central bank credits to enterprisesin their re- spective sectors. Such is the situation in agricultureand construction, for example. In addition, some enterprises have themselves formed commercialbanks that take credits from the centralbank and then pass them throughto the enterprisesthat foundedthem, their suppliers,and customers. Commercialbanks thus do not make credit allocation any less political, or any more conducive to restructuring. While some selected sectors are getting credits, it appears that smallerfirms in Russia have been substantiallycut off from the public subsidiesand credits. For example, the majorityof firmsin Blasi's sam- ple did not report receiving subsidies or subsidized credits from com- mercialbanks, and complainedabout not having enough capital to re- structure.The centralbank explictly denies credits to new firmson the groundsthat lendingto them is unsafe. The question is: can these firms findcapital elsewhere if they want to restructure? It appearsthat private capital marketsdo not meet this need. Some privatizedfirms are planninga public equity issue in the fall of 1993,al- thoughit is not entirelyclear how muchthey can raise withoutpromising investors dividends, restructuring,or at least a governancerole. Some commercialbanks are providingcredit from their own resources, but that situation usually occurs only when there are noncommercialrea- sons for makingloans or when debt contractscan be enforcedby physi- cal force. This is not surprising:lending as a practice does not make sense withouta bankruptcyprocedure that gives creditorsaccess to the borrower'sassets, but such a proceduredoes not exist in Russia. With- out bankruptcy,debt contractscannot really work. Rapidinflation is an additionalfactor that undermineslong-term lending by banks of their own funds. Finally, many privatized firms-and even state enter- prises-are formingjoint ventureswith privatedomestic and foreignin-

27. Accordingto a seniorofficial at the centralbank, the questionof publicversus pri- vate ownershipdoes not come up in the decisionsto allocatecredits by the creditcommis- sion. The same official,when asked whetherthe centralbank would always give creditto a firmon the vergeof shuttingdown, said that"the bank would never let thingsgo thatfar, and wouldlend at a muchearlier stage." MaximBoycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 175 vestors, which gives them access to some capital and know-how.28De- spite the success of joint ventures, they remain a trivial part of the Russian capital market. Political risk remainsgreat, and the , tax, and briberypolicies toward foreign investors are predatory. Thus, at least in the nearfuture, private markets will not addressthe cap- ital needs of restructuringRussian enterprises. In sum, capitalallocation in Russia is the main roadblockto restruc- turing.Central bank lending policies are highlypoliticized, whereas the rapidinflation undermines whatever private capitalallocation might be emerging.Firms not benefitingfrom central bank credits face a harder budgetconstraint and are beginningto restructure.However, substan- tial restructuringof these firmsrequires capital, which is not forthcom- ing fromthe commercialbanks until inflation subsides. Stabilizationwill obviously improvethis situationgreatly. In the meantime,the question of how to deliver capitalto the privatefirms must be addressed.

Privatization and Stabilization An essential step to rationalizingcapital allocation in Russia is to con- trol aggregatecredits and subsidies and thus to stabilize the ruble. In- deed, most Western attention and aid have been focused on stabiliza- tion. This attention raises the question of the relationship between privatizationand stabilization.Some analysts have argued that priva- tizationdisrupts the existingeconomic structure,and so monetarystabi- lization should take the first priority.Once the economy stabilizes, pri- vatization and restructuringcan take place. This position is best describedas "stabilizingsocialism." An alternativeposition arguesthat privatizationshould take the first precedence. Once firms are private, stabilizationcan work. Both these views are wrong. The main expense of the Russian gov- ernment,and hence the mainreason for money creation,is cheap credit to state industryand agriculture.As long as firmsremain public, the ba- sic demandfor subsidies-and hence money creationand inflation-will

28. Foreigninvestors preferjoint ventures over outrightownership of Russiancompa- nies because they can focus on the partof the Russiancompany's business that actually has some promise,do not inheritthe liabilitiesfrom the remainingbusinesses, and allow the incumbentmanagement to retaincontrol over the rest of the firm.Moreover, the firm can usuallystill drawon state creditsto supportnonviable businesses. 176 Brookings Paper-s on Economic Activity, 2:1993 not go away. Foreign aid can temporarilyplug the hole by replacing money creationwith dollarsin subsidies to state firms. But such stabili- zation is only temporary.As long as the basic demand for politically driven credit remains, stabilization cannot succeed without priva- tization. For a similarreason, privatizationcannot lead to restructuringif the governmentcontinues to print money and subsidize selected firmsand sectors. Privatizationof agriculturein Russia has been subvertedby the government'scredit policies. Politicizationof capitalallocation is made possible precisely by the ability of the government to print money. Whenthis abilityis limited, subsidizingselected firmsas long as they do not restructurewill prove much costlier. This will allow private gover- nance and capitalsupply mechanismsto begin to play a role, and hence create a hope of restructuring. Privatizationand stabilizationpolicies are thus complementary.Pri- vatizationallows the demandfor state creditto fall, which in turnmakes stabilizationpossible. Stabilizationcripples the political credit mecha- nism, and in this way stimulatesrestructuring.

Foreign Aid Foreignaid to Russia has been designed in part to solve the problem with the allocation of capital. Stabilization aid will partially replace loans to state firmsfinanced with newly created money. While this ap- proachwill not encouragethe restructuringof state firms,it may reduce money creationand inflation,and so benefit capital allocation. In addi- tion, G-7 countries have offered a package of privatizationassistance, designed at least in partto provide capitalfor restructuringenterprises. We discuss this element of the aid packagebelow. The first question to answer is, why should Western governments provide aid money for investmentin Russia when private investors do not want to invest there?Russia does not evidently have a capitalshort- age, as evidencedby enormouscapital flight. The returnson aid projects will probablynot exceed the returnson privateprojects, which suggests that, economically, investment assistance is hard to justify. Arguably, aid-financedWestern investmentwill demonstratethat there are profit- able investmentopportunities in Russia. It is hardto believe, however, that such a demonstrationrequires billions of dollars. Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 177

The mainreason for foreigncapital assistance is political. It is essen- tial to restructuresome of the Russianenterprises reasonably fast to gain supportfor privatization,and such restructuringmight not be forthcom- ing withoutcapital in the form of aid. The projects in the first place are unlikely to earn marketreturns because of the likely expropriationby politicians and workers. The high returns-both political and eco- nomic-on such aid will come when enterprises begin to restructure, and Russia moves more solidly into the marketeconomy. The criticalquestion is how to providesome badlyneeded investment financein a country like Russia. We have alreadyargued that conven- tional loans will not work in Russia because the bankruptcyprocedure gives so few rights to creditors. In addition, the obvious providers of loans in marketeconomies-commercial banks-remain controlledto a significantextent by the centralbank and the enterprises,and hence can- not be relied upon to allocate the loans commercially.And if the loans are processed throughthe governmentor a new governmentlending in- stitution, they are also sure to become politicized and worthless from the viewpointof restructuring. In part to circumvent the problem with politicization of loans, the Russiangovernment has proposeda system of capitalallocation through regionalenterprise funds. These funds would be originallycapitalized with Westernaid money, but would also be able to raise both equity and debt in the public markets. Other than the initial capitalization,these funds will be managedprivately and have an incentiveto maximizetheir returns.Having raised their capital, these funds would then invest it in equityof restructuringRussian firms, which wouldgive thema more sig- nificantgovernance role than they could get with debt. In addition to capital, these funds might bringknow-how and foreign partnersto the table. The reason for makingfunds regionalis, first, to make them com- pete with each other and, second, to keep them away from Moscow to reduce political influence on them. While located in the regions, the funds could invest elsewhere in Russia to avoid their capture by local politiciansas well. Finally, creatingmany small funds would furtherre- duce the likelihoodof theircapture by politicians. Most G-7 countries have accepted the idea of regional enterprise funds as the basis of post-privatizationassistance to Russia. Several such regionalfunds are expected to start up in 1994. But even if they work extremely well, it is hard to believe that these funds could do 178 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 nearlyas muchfor depoliticizingcredit in Russiaas macroeconomicsta- bilization. Aid to privatizedfirms through such enterprisefunds, along with sta- bilization,can improvethe capitalallocation process. Given the pivotal role of capital allocation in depoliticization, progress with these two strategieswill determinethe success of restructuringin Russia.

The Political Success of Privatization

As we mentionedin the introduction,privatization began in late 1991 as a low-prioritypolicy and emerged in 1993 as the Russian govern- ment's most popularreform. According to GKI opinionpolls, morethan 60 percent of the Russianpeople supportprivatization, with fewer than 20 percentopposing it. Youngerand richerpeople supportprivatization more strongly than older and poorer ones. Perhaps most importantly, privatizationis a very importantpart of the social landscapein Russia. The Number 5 song on the hit parade for several months was called "Wow! Wow! Voucher!" Privatizationhas benefitedboth other reformsand the reformers(al- though it began too late to prevent most reformersfrom being sacked from the government).The manageriallobby is no longeras strenuously opposed to reformas it was in 1992,in partbecause manymanagers have gotten a lot of shares and hence are quite excited about privatization. Privatizationis going much better in reformistregions, such as St. Pe- tersburgand Nizhny Novgorod, and makes other reforms in those re- gions easier to carryout. But ratherthan just cheerlead for privatization,we can offer some statistical evidence concerning its political impact. Table 7 presents cross-regionalregressions interpreting the results of the refer- endum, in which voters expressed their supportfor PresidentYeltsin and economic reform.Separate regressions are shown for the full sam- ple, for regions with auction results, and for regions with substantial sales of firms.The results are ratherstriking in the subsampleof regions where substantialprivatization took place. Controllingfor urbanization and relative income, both of which are associated with higher support for Yeltsin and reform,regions with moreprivatization had significantly highersupport for Yeltsin and for reform.Also, supportfor Yeltsin ran Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 179

Table 7. Regressions of Referendum Results on Privatization Variables and Regional Characteristicsa Sample for question I Sample for question 2 regressions r-egressions Regions Regions having having sold sold more more than ten than ten Regions large Regions large with enterprises with enterprises available before available before Full auctioni June Fuill auction Junze Independent variable sample resuilts 1993 sample results 1993 Intercept 0.0608 0.2075f 0.2004f 0.0769 0.1994f O.l951f (0.0064) (0.0571) (0.0591) (0.0573) (0.0503) (0.0517)

Chartercapital sold 0.0001h 0.00019 0.00019 0.0001h 0.00019 0.00019 per capitab (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) Technical dummyc 0.0205 0.0668f 0.0554f 0.0193 O.O59f 0.04989 (0.0246) (0.0214) (0.0216) (0.0220) (0.0188) (0.0189)

Urban populationd 0.5764f 0.3535f 0.3844f 0.4981f 0.3100f 0.3376f (0.0986) (0.0858) (0.0863) (0.0881) (0.0756) (0.0755) Relative incomee 0.0678f 0.0664f 0.05499 0.0526f 0.052lf 0.0404h (0.0245) (0.0165) (0.0239) (0.0192) (0.0141) (0.0209) Summary statistic Number of observations 77 60 57 77 60 57 R2 0.48 0.56 0.50 0.45 0.55 0.49

Source: Authors'regressions based on GKI data. a. The dependentvariable for question I is the share of people who respondedyes to the question, "Do you supportthe President?"The dependentvariable for question2 is the share of people who respondedyes to the question,"Do you supportthe economicreform program of the government?"Regressions are ordinaryleast squares of referendumquestions I and 2 on privatizationvariables and regionalcharacteristics. Numbers in parenthesesare standarderrors. b. The amountof chartercapital sold per capita,by region,in the sale of largeenterprises. c. Reflectswhether a regionhas receivedtechnical assistance for privatization. d. Percentageof inhabitantsof a regionwho live in cities. e. Relativeincome reflects the incomeof a regionin relationto the nationalaverage. f. Significantat I percent. g. Significantat 5 percent. h. Significantat 10 percent.

5.5 percenthigher in regionsthat received technicalassistance for priva- tizationthan in regionsthat did not. One interpretationof these results is that privatizationhas helped Yeltsin and the reformerswin the referendum.This, of course, is not the only interpretation.It is possible that the more reformistregions both supported Yeltsin and reform, and have privatized more. Unfortu- nately, we do not have an independentcontrol for how stronglya region backs reforms.The relationshipbecomes weaker once the regions with 180 Brookings Papers oni Economic Activity, 2:1993 no privatizationare included. One possible reason for this weaker rela- tionshipis that regionswhere privatizationhas not even begunfor some exogenousreason, such as corruptionof the local administration,do not fit the model. To summarize,privatization has been popularand arguablyhas en- abled other reformsto proceed. It is also at least plausibleto inferfrom the availabledata that privatizationhelped PresidentYeltsin and the re- formerswin the crucialApril referendum.

Conclusion

This paperpresented a view of privatizationas a step in the depolitici- zation of firms-the severance of public influence on private enter- prises. In this regard,we focused on four aspects of change in the way firmsare run and financedthat could influencethe success of depolitici- zation: privatizationitself, competitionpolicy, equity governance, and capital allocation. We then evaluated Russian privatizationfrom this vantagepoint. In some respects, Russian privatizationhas been a great success. Firms are being privatizedat a breathtakingpace. Equity governance mechanismsare emergingvery rapidly,and some of them, particularly largeshareholder activism, are beginningto shakeup Russianfirms. The population approves of privatizationand actively participates in the process. At the same time, large-scaleprivatization in Russiais less thana year old. Most firms remain state-owned, and many have been prohibited from privatizingat all. Politiciansare not giving up their controlof firms easily and are actively resistingdepoliticization. Competition policy has not been effective. And most importantly,the allocationof capitalis still completelydominated by the centralbank, with commercialbanks play- ing a relatively passive role in financialmarkets. Nor is it clear that a responsiblemonetary policy will emerge in Russia in the nearfuture. Last, and most important,the politicallandscape in Russia is treach- erous. Old-linepoliticians-in the government, in the parliament,and in the bureaucracy-by and large have not been replacedand continue underminingall reform, including privatization.The reformers have failed to either destroy or win over these politicians. Withoutquestion, Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 181 the greatest success of Russianprivatization has been to underminethe influence of the old-line politicians. The fundamentalopen question aboutthe success of privatizationand other reformin Russia is whether the days of these politiciansare really over.29

29. This paragraphwas writtenbefore PresidentYeltsin's violent confrontationwith the parliamentin October 1993. Even after this confrontation,old guardpoliticians in Russiaremain powerful. Comments and Discussion

Stanley Fischer: Privatizationstands out as the most successful ele- ment in the Russian reform program.Indeed, Russian privatizationis even outpacing privatizationin other countries in the former and in easternEurope. This interestingpaper, written by some of the importantthinkers behind the program,helps explainwhy. As in other reformingformerly socialist countries, small-scalepriva- tizationhas gone well. Smallerfirms, especially in retaildistribution and services, are being sold for cash or leased, by local governments.The importanceof such privatizationfor the consumershould not be under- estimated;shopping was difficultand time-consumingin the old system, and that problemhas disappeared.The impactof small-scaleprivatiza- tion and the entry of new retailfirms is visible to any visitor. The paperby MaximBoycko, AndreiShleifer, and RobertVishny is aboutprivatizing firms that accountfor 20 percentof employment;all of light industry is included. Excluded are firms in defense, natural re- sources, health and education,and much of agriculture. The paperclearly sets out the threeprivatization options. The key re- sult of the process is summarizedin table 5, which shows that managers and workersown 70 percent of the shares of privatizedfirms; managers accountfor 17percent. The authorssay thatlabor and managementform an alliance, with labor the weaker partner.The paperprovides little in- dependentevidence on this point. The key question posed by the authors at the start of the paper is whether privatizationwill lead to restructuring.While they do not an- swer this question explicitly, they indicate that the privatizationmay have gone too far in the directionof labormanagement. They also argue thatrestructuring will requirenonpolitical control over creditallocation, and nonpoliticalgovernance of firms, neitherof which yet obtains. Ap- 182 Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 183 parently,the authors, like other observers, do not yet see much in the way of restructuringtaking place. Does that mean that the authors should have urged delaying priva- tizationuntil they had inventeda scheme that would guaranteerapid re- structuring?The answeris no, because it was crucialto move these firms out of direct state control. Shouldthe lack of restructuringcause a slow- down of the privatizationprocess? Again, the answeris no, for the same reason. Nonetheless, this initialprivatization may not resultin much re- structuring.The tighteningof credit and macroeconomicstabilization would increase the efficiency of privatizedfirms, but it mightbe neces- sary to attemptfurther restructuring later to reduce the role of labor in management. Was there an alternativethat would have produced more rapid re- structuring?The answer is yes, but that decision belonged not to the privatizersbut to . He could have pushed for a more ag- gressive reform program, but chose instead to confront his congres- sional rivals more slowly. The authors emphasize the importanceof political factors in their discussion of the design of the privatizationprogram. They argue that privatizationis the one reform that brings immediatebenefits to con- sumers and voters. That is true of the first stage of the process, when vouchers are distributedand consumers are given ownershipof firms. However, it is not true at the restructuringstage, when unemployment is likely to grow-and that may help explainwhy restructuringhas been so slow. For all the discussion of political factors, politics nonetheless plays the role of a deus ex machinain much of the paper. Wheneverthe au- thors are uncomfortablewith a decision-for instance the inclusion of privatizationoption 2-they attributethe decision to politics. Presum- ably there was usually more than one way to meet the political con- straint,and more discussion of the choices that were consideredwould have been helpful. The paper gives the impression that all politicians are bad. But at some point it becomes clear that , Boris Yeltsin, and the reformersare good politicians. So this is really a paper about the good guys versus the badguys, andwe do not know whatdrives the good guys, and what differentiatesthem, except that we are on their side and they on ours. 184 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993

Turningto financingmechanisms, the authors'emphasis on the lack of capitalmarkets is important.It will take.time for commercialbanks to play any majorrole in the financing,and especially the restructuring,of Russian industry. The authors' support for the creation of enterprise funds and equity, ratherthan debt, financingis problematicin light of their argumentthat the allocationof capitalshould not be dominatedby the public sector. The enterprisefunds likely to be set up with foreign assistance will have governmentshareholders. If these funds are to take a leadingrole in enterprisegovernance, then they will have to be runon a commercialbasis. That will not be an easy trickto carryoff either. Discussingother factors influencingthe privatizationprocess, the au- thors are skepticalthat competitionthrough imports is likely to play an importantrole in increasingmarket discipline and reducingpolitical in- terference. While the obstacles to increasedcompetition through trade liberalizationare obvious, the internationalagencies and advisers to the Russians should nonetheless keep poundingon this issue-for there are few other pressurespushing in the rightdirection. The authorsare absolutelyright to emphasizethat stabilizationis es- sentialfor restructuring.The creditexpansion that now enables firmsto avoid restructuringwould end if the economy were stabilized. That is the main reason that the opponents of reformare so hostile to stabili- zation. In their paper, the authors do not sufficientlyemphasize the role of new firms. Entry has been at least as importantas privatizationin the developmentof small firms. In the Chinese industrialexpansion, it has been more important.New firms will be crucial to the Russian reform programas well, not least because new firmswill be needed to absorb the laborthat will be shed by restructuringprivatized firms. Beyond the privatizationof industrialfirms lies the challengeof priva- tizing agricultureand housing. Given the speed at which the currentpri- vatization is proceeding, the authors will soon be able to turn their talents to those problems.

Jeffrey D. Sachs: This paperoffers us a vivid look at the tacticalchoices made in the Russian privatizationprogram, by three of the key partici- pants in the process. They have much to be pleased about. In just two years, privatizationhas gone frombeing an abstractidea of a few radical reformersto an operationalfact for tens of thousandsof enterprisesand Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 185 millions of workers-and this after seventy-five years of the brutalre- pressionof privateproperty. Nonetheless, as the authors make clear, privatization to date amountsmostly to a formaltransfer of ownershiprights, rather than real operationalchanges in most enterprises.It is still too early to answerthe authors'central question: will privatizationreally lead to restructuring of the Russianeconomy? They offer one strawin the wind:the low value placed on Russiancorporate capital in the voucherauctions, suggesting that the newly establishedproperty rights have not yet passed the mar- ket test. Significantly,after Yeltsin's showdown with the hardlinepar- liament in October 1993, the price of voucher tickets jumped sharply, presumablya reflectionof increasedpublic confidencein the long-term success of the reforms. Russia's political and economic reformsare so far only half formed, and a bruisingand long strugglelies ahead if the reformsare to be com- pleted successfully. Many of the formal structures have been put in place, but Russia is only fitfullyputting in place one of the centralfea- tures of a marketeconomy and a democraticsociety: open competition. Most of Russia's elite owes its position, wealth, and power to an inheri- tance fromthe communistregime, ratherthan to inventivenessand hard work. For part of the elite, real competitionis mortallythreatening. It is therefore not surprisingthat the breakthroughto free parliamentary elections in December 1993came only aftera violent confrontationwith the Soviet-eraparliament, which become the chief politicalprotagonist of the entrenchedold guard.(The public had voted new elections in the April 1993 referendum, but the parliament leadership had merely sneeredat the results.) On the economic side, therehas been a similarferocious battleto lock in advantages.Managers of state enterprisesand newly privatizedenter- prises seek to shield themselves from shareholders,foreign competi- tion, and new domestic rivals. As MaximBoycko, AndreiShleifer, and RobertVishny make clear, privatizationhas gone forwardrapidly only by meeting the stakeholders more than halfway. The managers and workersare receiving a substantialproportion of the enterprisecapital virtuallyfree of charge. The authorsstate that "voucherprivatization is clearly the definingfeature of the Russian program."This is not really true. The very high distributionof shares to insiders should be judged as an equally definingfeature of Russia's privatizationprocess to this point. 186 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 Russia's situationcan be comparedwith othercountries in the region. In eastern Europe, early elections eliminatedmuch of the communist political class, althoughpostcommunist parties continue to enjoy some electoral success in open competition with centrist and right-wing parties. Similarly, many state managers were thrown out by post- communist governments (as in in 1991) or by anti- communisttrade unions (as in Poland in 1990). In and Latvia, Russian politicians and enterprise managers have been deposed by young nationalistpoliticians. In an earliercase of deep systemic change, Japanafter World War II, the old managerialelite was summarilyforced out by the U.S. occupationauthorities, bringing in a new generationof managers. In Russia, by contrast, there were no nationalelections between the coup attemptand December 1993, so that reformershad to struggleto privatize the economy while key political actors and enterprise man- agers from the old regimeremained in place. The managerswere able to capturea partof the privatizationproceeds far in excess of the achieve- ments of the old guardin the other economies. As early advisors on the privatizationprocess, the authorsand I arguedstrongly for speed above perfection in the distributionof shares. For the general success of the reforms,which were extremelyprecarious at the start, it was important to "makefacts," by establishingwidespread private propertyrights. If that meant heavy insiderrepresentation, that was a cost that should be accepted. As could be expected, many state managersand workerswho were initiallyopposed to marketand politicalreforms became support- ers after being vested with propertyrights in their enterprises. From a distributionalpoint of view, the inequities of insider distributionwere temperedby the government'sinsistence that workers, not managers, receive the bulk of the shares. Recent news fromthe trenchesamplifies the fact that incumbentman- agers are attemptingto dig in yet further. The existing corporate law gives weak powers to the boardof directors(or "supervisoryboard," in Russianlaw), and strongpowers to the managers.Moreover, managers in many enterprisesare leadingefforts to reissue corporatecharters to lengthentheir tenure and weaken the boards still further.These are un- settling conclusions of a survey of firmsthat the authorsand I cospon- sored this summercarried out by KatharinaPistor. ' This may be a major

1. Pistor (1993). MaximBoycko, Andrei $hleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 187 explanationof the low voucher prices, since as minorityowners of the enterprises,voucher investors will have little protectionover theirinter- ests. It would be worthwhileto test whetherinvestors are willingto pay muchmore for enterpriseshares when they obtaina controllingblock as partof the purchase. Does a precedent for Russia lie with China, where the old elite has kept its position but economic dynamismhas nonetheless been estab- lished? Not really, since the control of the state enterpriseson the Chi- nese economy was always markedlyless than in Russia.2State enter- prises in Chinanever employed more than 20 percentof the laborforce, comparedwith 90 percent in Russia. China'sdynamism has come in the nonstate sector, which grew from the bottom up after 1978. In Russia, nearlyeverybody is still tied to the state system throughbudgetary sub- sidies, tradeprotection, and financialcredits, so that bottom-upgrowth will be as dynamicas in Chinaonly if the subsidy system can firstbe dis- mantled. The most importantquestion for Russia is whether real competition will accompany privatization,since competition together with private propertyis a sine qua non of a functioningmarket system. Will Russia's existing enterprises, whether state-owned or newly privatized, be put on a level playingfield with new entrantsand foreigncompetitors? This questionwill be as importantas formalownership transfer and corporate governancein determiningthe natureof Russia's economic restructur- ing. Indeed, in BPEA, 1:1993, Brian Pinto, Marek Belka, and Stefan Krajewski demonstrated that hard-budgetconstraints and vigorous product markets in Poland are provokingrestructuring even in enter- prises still in state hands. The authors are skeptical about the prospects for vigorous product marketcompetition in Russia. They are also pessimisticabout the pros- pects for effective bankinginstitutions procedures and bankruptcypro- cedures. They mightbe rightabout prospects for instillingmarket com- petition in Russia, but then the consequences would be devastating. Withor withoutprivatization, Russia will have a crippledeconomy and society. Fortunately, the authors'judgment is premature.The struggle for competitionand openness is hardlylost. On the politicalfront, Yeltsin's showdownwith the parliamentis likely to be viewed in retrospectas the

2. See Sachs and Woo (1993)for a detailedcomparison. 188 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 last stand of communismin Russia, and the beginningof open demo- cratic competition. The breakthroughto new elections gives the best chance for the rise of a new, competitive political class representinga much broaderarray of interests than the old guard. On the economic side, the success of the reformersin pushing for real competition has tendedto move in parallelwith theirpolitical strength.For example, af- ter the Octoberconfrontations with the parliament,the reform-minded financeminister was able to cancel cheap centralbank credits to enter- prises; eliminate the practice of "netting out" interenterprisearrears, therebyhardening the enterprises'budget constraints; and tightenover- all creditconditions in the economy in orderto reduce inflationand pro- mote restructuring. I found myself a bit perplexedat the paper's policy conclusions. The authors put great stress on regional enterprise funds capitalized by Westernaid, yet early on they rejectedPolish-style mutual funds for fear that "state-sponsoredfunds owning large stakes in Russian companies would become politicized and hence be unableto enforce restructuring policies." They also ratherboldly dismiss the entire bankingsystem as hopeless, even though Russian banks differ enormously in structure, capital adequacy, and reliance on central bank financing.The World Bank is currentlyundertaking a majorprogram to help restructureand strengthenRussian banks, and it is findingmany cases of serious, pro- fessional, market-orientedbanks. A more balancedassessment of prior- ities, includingbanking reform, trade liberalization,and capital market development,would add credibilityto this otherwise excellent paper.

General Discussion

Severalpanel membersdiscussed the prospectsfor reformin Russia. RichardCooper emphasized Jeff Sach's argumentthat no modernecon- omy could work well without product marketcompetition, and asked where that was going to come from in the case of Russia:from new en- trants at the small firm level, as in China, or from foreign trade, as in Poland, ,and the Czech Republic?He suggested that foreign tradeis the only practicalalternative for Russia, and that it is therefore important to focus on the barriers to import competition. Charles Schultze noted that privatizationwould fail so long as firmscould rely Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 189 on subsidies ratherthan painfulrestructuring. Consequently, subsidies must be made expensive for politiciansto offset pressurefor them from interested parties, including managers, workers, and shareholders. BarryEichengreen suggested that the variationin success of privatiza- tion across regions mostly reflects the presence of moribundelements of the military-industrialcomplex in certain regions. In these regions, privatizationis not very advanced, and politicians are not inclined to- wardreform. Respondingto these comments, RobertVishny agreedthat although product competitionmight be the long-runsavior of the Russian econ- omy, in the short run it presents many local and regionalpolitical prob- lems. For example, foreign trade becomes highly politicized where do- mestic monopolies exist. Andrei Shleifer reportedthat althoughthere are antimonopolycommissions in every region, there is no interest in competition; these commissions are primarilyinterested in protecting theirregion's firms.He also indicatedthat, althoughthere is some entry of smallfirms in services, new entrantshave played a much smallerrole in Russia than in China, Poland, or the Czech Republic. Sachs added that, in 1992, only 4 percent of the industriallabor force worked in pri- vate firmsthat were not once owned by the state. In response to questionsabout the outlookfor reform,the authorsin- dicated that they were gloomy about the short-runprospects. Shleifer indicatedthat the paperfocused on Russianprivatization not because it has been particularlysuccessful, but because for now it appears to be the only avenue for makingprogress in corporategovernance. Vishny added that, nonetheless, there are at least some hopefulelements in the privatizationunderway. Privatizationprovided workers and managers with moreopportunity to benefitfrom efficiency, an incentivethat could lead to a reduced demand for subsidies as firms began to pursue effi- ciency in their own interest. He also stressed that under privatization, managers' reputationsbecome important;they have shareholdersto answerto and they can be embarrassedin the press. In response to questions, Maxim Boycko elaboratedon the paper's explanationfor the low relative valuationsof Russian firms. First, po- tentialinvestors may fear that firmswill be controlledby politiciansand will not maximize profits. Second, potential investors may fear that, even if value is created, workers and managers,rather than sharehold- ers, will captureit. RobertShiller found these explanationsinsufficient, 190 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993 arguingthat it is hardto believe that the averageinvestor gives the aver- age firmalmost no chance of earningprofits and returningthem to in- vestors. Severalparticipants focused on the issue of who does andwho should controlthese enterprises.Paul Romer drew a parallelbetween the politi- cal control of capitalallocation in Russia and the role of governmentin the . He noted thatthe role of the governmentin U.S. capi- tal allocation also presents problems, with the savings and loan crisis providingan example of drastic failure. He stressed that to devise the best policies, it is necessary to learn much more about which sorts of institutionsand political mechanismsactually work and which are vul- nerableto failure. Fred Pryornoted that the informationabout Russian firmsavailable to investors and shareholderswas woefully inadequate, makingit difficultfor them to become knowledgeableabout firms and to exercise any control. WilliamBlack, makinga similarpoint in starker terms, suggested that inexperiencedinvestors would be vulnerableto fraudand that this mightprovide importantpolitical ammunition for op- ponents of reform. Vishny agreed with Pryor's suspicion that outside shareholdersare not sufficiently informed, and that this helped keep control in the hands of insiders. said that in Poland, the former Czechoslovakia,and Hungaryare differentthan in Russia, and that the authors' descriptionof the process should not be generalizedto these other countries. In these other countries,there is not muchof a problem with politiciansattempting to retain control of firms, althoughfirms do lean on politiciansfor help when they get into trouble.Nonetheless, with firms more or less on their own, workers and managersface different incentives than they now do in Russia. Ned Phelps raisedthe possibility that workers may have more power to resist managementthan the au- thors suggested; otherwise, why was it necessary to give them the op- portunityto hold so manyshares? He also noted that the wave of protec- tion rackets and bribery is probably an important drag on private investmentand enterprise. Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny 191

References

Aghion,Philippe, and Olivier Jean Blanchard. 1993. "On the Speed of Transition in CentralEurope." Unpublished paper. Massachusetts Institute of Technol- ogy (June). Atkinson, Anthony B., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1980. Lectures on Public Eco- nomics. London:McGraw-Hill. Blanchard,Olivier, and others. 1991. Reform in Eastern Europe. Cambridge, Mass.: MITPress. Blanchard,Olivier J., and MarekDabrowski. 1993. "TheProgress of Restruc- turing in Poland." In Post-Communist Reform: Pain and Progress. Cam- bridge,Mass.: MITPress. Boycko, Maxim,and AndreiShleifer. 1993."The Politics of RussianPrivatiza- tion." In Post-Communist Reform: Pain and Progress. Cambridge, Mass.: MITPress. Boycko, Maxim, AndreiShleifer, and RobertW. Vishny. 1993a."A Theory of Privatization."Unpublished paper. The State Committeeon the Manage- ment of State Property,Harvard University, and the University of Chicago (May). . 1993b."Voucher Privatization." Working Paper 85. Chicago:Center for the Study of the Economy and the State, Universityof Chicago. Brown, AnnetteN., BarryIckes, and RandiRyterman. 1993. "The Myth of Mo- nopoly:A New View of IndustrialStructure in Russia."Unpublished paper. WorldBank (June). Dewatripont,Mathias, and Eric Maskin. 1990. "Creditand Efficiencyin Cen- tralizedand DecentralizedEconomies." Unpublished paper. Universite Li- bre de Bruxellesand HarvardUniversity (July). Frydman,Roman, and AndrzejRapaczynski. 1991. "Marketsand Institutions in LargeScale Privatization:An Approachto Economicand Social Transfor- mation in Eastern Europe." In Reforming Central and Eastern European Economies: Initial Results and Challenges, edited by Vittorio Corbo, Fa- brizioCoricelli, and Jan Bossak. Washington:World Bank. Frydman,Roman, AndrzejRapaczynski, and John S. Earle. 1993. ThePriva- tization Process in Russia, , and the Baltic States. Budapest: Central EuropeanUniversity Press. Grossman,Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart. 1986. "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership:A Theoryof Verticaland LateralIntegration." Journal of Politi- cal Economy 94(4): 691-719. Hart, Oliver D. 1983. "The MarketMechanism as an Incentive Scheme."Bell Journal of 14(2): 366-82. Joint Study. 1991.A Studyof the Soviet Economy, 3 vols., by the International MonetaryFund, the WorldBank, the Organisationfor Economic Coopera- tion and Development,and the EuropeanBank for Reconstructionand De- 192 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1993

velopment. Paris: Organisationfor Economic Cooperation and Devel- opment. Laffont, Jean-Jacques, and Jean Tirole. 1993. A Theory of Incentives in Procure- ment and Regulation. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Lipton, David, and Jeffrey D. Sachs. 1990. "Privatizationin Eastern Europe: The Case of Poland."BPEA, 2:1990, 293-333. Mueller,Dennis C. 1989.Public Choice II. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press. Nellis, John. 1988."Contract Plans and PublicEnterprise Performance." World Bank Staff WorkingPaper 118. Washington:World Bank. Pinto, Brian, Marek Belka, and Stefan Krajewski. 1993. "TransformingState Enterprisesin Poland:Evidence on Adjustmentby ManufacturingFirms." BPEA, 1:1993, 213-61. Pistor, Katharina.1993. "Privatizationand CorporateGovernance in Russia- An EmpiricalStudy." Paper preparedfor the Workshopon Economic Re- form, Centerfor InternationalSecurity and ,Stanford Univer- sity (November). Sachs, Jeffrey D. 1992. "Privatizationin Russia: Some Lessons from Eastern Europe." American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 82(2): 43-8. . 1993. "Prospectsfor MonetaryStabilization in Russia." Unpublished paper.Harvard University (June). , and Wing Thye Woo. 1993. "StructuralFactors in the Economic Re- forms of China, EasternEurope, and the FormerSoviet Union." Economic Policy (forthcoming). Shleifer,Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1986."Large Shareholders and Corpo- rate Control." Journal of Political Economy 94(3): 461-88. . 1992. "Privatizationin Russia: First Steps." Unpublishedpaper. Har- vardUniversity and the Universityof Chicago(October). Vining,Aidan R., andAnthony E. Boardman.1992. "Ownership versus Compe- tition:Efficiency in PublicEnterprise." Public Choice 73(2):205-39. WorldBank. 1993a."Russia: The BankingSystem in Transition."Unpublished paper.Agriculture, Industry, and Finance Division, CountryDepartment III, Europeand CentralAsia Region, WorldBank (May 26). . 1993b. "Subsidies and Directed Credits to Enterprisesin Russia: A Strategyfor Reform."Unpublished paper. CountryOperations Division 2, ECA CountryDepartment III, WorldBank (April8).