Domar Source: the Journal of Economic History, Vol

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Domar Source: the Journal of Economic History, Vol Economic History Association The Causes of Slavery or Serfdom: A Hypothesis Author(s): Evsey D. Domar Source: The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 30, No. 1, The Tasks of Economic History (Mar., 1970), pp. 18-32 Published by: Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2116721 Accessed: 18-09-2015 10:24 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/ info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Cambridge University Press and Economic History Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Economic History. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 129.199.207.113 on Fri, 18 Sep 2015 10:24:51 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions The Causes of Slaveryor Serfdom: A Hypothesis I THE purposeof thispaper is to present,or morecorrectly, to revive,a hypothesisregarding the causes of agriculturalserf- dom or slavery (used here interchangeably).The hypothesiswas suggestedby Kliuchevsky'sdescription of the Russian experience in the sixteenthand seventeenthcenturies, but it aims at a wider applicability.' Accordingto Kliuchevsky,from about the second half of the fif- teenthcentury Russia was engaged in long hard wars against her westernand southernneighbors. The wars requiredlarge forcesthat the statefound impossible to supportfrom tax revenuealone. Hence the governmentbegan to assign lands (pomestia) to the servitors, who were expected to use peasant labor (directlyand/or via pay- mentsin kind and/ormoney) for theirmaintenance and weapons. In exchange,the servitorgave the peasants a loan and permitted them,free men as yet,to workall or part of his land on theirown. The systemworked rather badly, however,because of shortageof labor. Severe competitionamong landownersdeveloped, the ser- vitorsbeing bested by lay and clerical magnates. Things became particularlydifficult for the servitorsafter the middle of the six- teenthcentury when the centralareas of the state became depop- ulated because of peasant migrationinto the newlyconquered areas in the east and southeast.Under the pressureof the servingclass For many helpfulcomments on an earlierdraft, I am gratefulto the following persons: AbrahamBecker, Oleg Hoeffding,Clayton La Force, Edward Mitchell, WilliamParker, George Rosen, Matthew Edel, PeterTemin, Helen Turinand Charles Wolf, Jr. Alexander Gerschenkron'searlier suggestionswere also very helpful. Thanksare also due Ann Peet forher excellentresearch assistance. I am also gratefulto the RAND Corporationfor its supportof an earlierversion of this study (20 October 1966), and to the National Science Foundationfor its assistance(Grant No. NSF-GS-2627) in revisingand extendingthe firstdraft. Neither these two organizations,nor the personslisted above, are responsiblefor the views expressedhere. 1 V. Kliuchevsky,Kurs russkofistorii (Moscow: Gosudarstvennoesotsial'no-eko. nomicheskoeizdatel'stvo, 1937). The originalwork was publishedin 1906. All my referencesapply to the 1937 edition.An English translationby C. J. Hogarth,A Historyof Russia,was publishedin New York by Russell and Russellin 1960. For specificreferences, see Part II. is This content downloaded from 129.199.207.113 on Fri, 18 Sep 2015 10:24:51 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Causes of Slavery 19 and forcertain other reasons, the governmentgradually restricted the freedomof peasants,already hopelessly in debt to theirland- lords,to move.They became enserfed by themiddle of the seven- teenthcentury, though the processitself continued for many dec- ades to come. Thisis a veryrough summary of Kliuchevsky's story which hardly does himjustice but whichwill servemy purposesuntil Part II. Like manya historian,he assembledand describedthe relevant facts(and in beautifulRussian at that) and stoppedjust shortof an analyticalexplanation. The economistwould recastKliuchevsky's account as follows: The servitorstried to live offrents (in one formor another)to be collectedfrom their estates. But the estatescould not yielda sig- nificantamount of rentfor the simplereason that land in Russia was not sufficientlyscarce relativeto labor,and ironically,was made even less scarceby Russianconquests. The scarcefactor of productionwas not land but labor.Hence it was the ownership of peasantsand not of land thatcould yield an incometo the ser- vitorsor to anynon-working landowning class. A simpleeconomic model may sharpenthe argument(if any sharpeningis needed) and help to developit further.Assume that labor and land are the onlyfactors of production(no capitalor management),and that land of uniformquality and locationis ubiquitous.No diminishingreturns in the applicationof labor to land appear;both the averageand the marginalproductivities of laborare constantand equal, and if competitionamong employers raiseswages to thatlevel (as would be expected),no rentfrom land can arise,as Ricardodemonstrated some time past. In the ab- senceof specificgovernmental action to the contrary(see below), the countrywill consistof family-sizefarms because hiredlabor, in anyform, will be eitherunavailable or unprofitable:the wage of a hiredman or theincome of a tenantwill have to be at leastequal to whathe can makeon his ownfarm; if he receivesthat much, no surplus(rent) willbe leftfor his employer.A non-workingclass of servitorsor otherscould be supportedby the governmentout of taxeslevied (directlyor indirectly)on the peasants,but it could not supportitself from land rents. As a steptoward reality, let us relaxthe assumption of theubiq- uityof uniformland, and let capital (clearingcosts, food, seeds, livestock,structures and implements)and managementbe included This content downloaded from 129.199.207.113 on Fri, 18 Sep 2015 10:24:51 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 20 Evsey D. Domar amongthe factorsof production.Owners of capital,of superior skilland ofbetter-than-average land will now be able to pay a hired manhis due (or to use a tenant)and stillobtain a surplus.But so longas agriculturalskills can be easilyacquired, the amount of cap- ital forstarting a farmis small,and the per capita incomeis rel- ativelyhigh (because of theample supply of land), a good worker shouldbe able to saveor borrowand starton hisown in time.Most of the farmswill stillbe moreor less family-size,with an estate usinghired labor (or tenants)here and therein areasof unusually good (in fertilityand/or in location)land, or specializingin activ- itiesrequiring higher-than-average capital intensity, or skillfulman- agement.But untilland becomesrather scarce, and/or the amount ofcapital required to starta farmrelatively large, it is unlikelythat a largeclass of landowners, such as requiredby theMuscovite gov- ernment,could be supportedby economicforces alone. The Amer- ican Northin the Colonialperiod and in the nineteenthcentury wouldbe a good exampleof an agriculturalstructure of thistype. So farthe institutionalstructure has been shapedby economic forcesalone without direct interference by the government.2Sup- pose now thatthe governmentdecides to create,or at least to fa- cilitatethe creationof, a non-workingclass of agriculturalowners. As a firststep, it givesthe membersof thisclass the sole rightof ownershipof land. The peasantswill now have to workfor the landowners,but so longas theworkers are freeto move,competi- tionamong the employerswill drivethe wage up to the value of the marginalproduct of labor,and since the latteris stillfairly close to the value of the averageproduct (because of the abun- danceof land) littlesurplus will remain. The Russiansituation prior to thepeasants' enserfment corresponds to thiscase. The nextand finalstep to be takenby the governmentstill pur- suingits objectiveis the abolitionof the peasants'right to move. Withlabor tied to land or to the owner,competition among em- ployersceases. Now the employercan derivea rent,not fromhis land,but fromhis peasantsby appropriatingall or mostof their incomeabove some subsistence level.3 That Russian serfs could stay alive,and evento multiply,while working for themselves half-time 2 I mean by the "government"any organizationcapable of maintainingsome measureof law and orderand particularlyof usingnon-economic compulsion. It can be a king,an assemblyof landowners,a magnate,etc. 3 He may be restrainedby customand by the fearthat his serfscan run away-a commonoccurence in Russia. This content downloaded from 129.199.207.113 on Fri, 18 Sep 2015 10:24:51 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Causes of Slavery 21 and less suggeststhat the productivityof theirlabor (with poor technique,little capital, but abundantland) musthave been quite high. To recapitulate,the strongversion of thishypothesis (without capital,management, etc.) assertsthat of thethree elements of an agriculturalstructure relevant here-free land, freepeasants, and non-workinglandowners-any two elements but never all threecan existsimultaneously. The combinationto be foundin realitywill depend on the behaviorof politicalfactors-governmental mea- sures-treatedhere as an exogenousvariable. The presenceof thisexogenous political
Recommended publications
  • Northerners' Perspectives on American Emancipation and the End of Russian Serfdom
    University of Central Florida STARS Honors Undergraduate Theses UCF Theses and Dissertations 2021 Northerners' Perspectives on American Emancipation and the End of Russian Serfdom Mariana S. Kellis University of Central Florida Part of the United States History Commons Find similar works at: https://stars.library.ucf.edu/honorstheses University of Central Florida Libraries http://library.ucf.edu This Open Access is brought to you for free and open access by the UCF Theses and Dissertations at STARS. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Undergraduate Theses by an authorized administrator of STARS. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Recommended Citation Kellis, Mariana S., "Northerners' Perspectives on American Emancipation and the End of Russian Serfdom" (2021). Honors Undergraduate Theses. 947. https://stars.library.ucf.edu/honorstheses/947 NORTHERNERS’ PERSPECTIVES ON AMERICAN EMANCIPATION AND THE END OF RUSSIAN SERFDOM By: MARIANA KELLIS A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Honors in the Major Program in History in the College of Arts and Humanities and in the Burnett Honors College at the University of Central Florida Orlando, Florida Spring Term, 2021 Thesis Chair: Barbara Gannon, Ph.D. Abstract This thesis explores the various perspectives that Northern Americans had on Russian serfdom and its emancipation. This era was significant to both Russia and the United States because each country experienced tremendous reforms including the abolitions of their unfree labor institutions. Generally, Northern Americans viewed serfdom as a milder form of forced labor and suspected that it would be eradicated soon. Abolitionists used rumors of Russian emancipation to advocate for the end of American slavery.
    [Show full text]
  • The Gulag As a Reinvention of Serfdom in Soviet Russia
    READING COPY ONLY NOT FOR CITATION The Gulag as a Reinvention of Serfdom in Soviet Russia By David J. Nordlander Intractable for centuries, forced labor has proven to be an enduring legacy of Russian history. What began as a gradual restriction of peasant movement in earlier times became institutionalized within a state that ultimately relied upon coercion as a chief lever of economic policy in both the tsarist and Soviet periods. The most notable measure of unfree labor, the institution of serfdom, constituted the base of a pyramid that upheld the tsarist polity. But the endemic problems of a cash-poor economy and imbalanced labor supply did not end with the Bolshevik Revolution, and thus helped shape the outlines of the Soviet era. The idealism of October quickly gave way to a harshening of labor policy, culminating in the extreme response of Stalinism that essentially led to a reenserfment of the peasantry and a pernicious expansion of the most repressive aspects of tsarism. The Gulag in particular encapsulated these trends and became the embodiment of Soviet coercion in the twentieth century. The continuities between the tsarist and Soviet epochs were both obvious and subtle. Imprisonment, exile, and restriction of movement were to be found in both eras, albeit in an even more harsh form under Stalin. While trumpeting an idealistic and 2 liberationist rhetoric, the Soviet experiment in reality soon revived and expanded upon the economic and political coercion of its tsarist predecessor. Just as significantly, social and cultural parallels also were noteworthy. In spite of their progressive cant, Soviet bosses essentially formed a new ruling elite that contentedly reshaped the privileges of power and formed a revived aristocracy.
    [Show full text]
  • State Capacity and the Rise and Fall of Serfdom in Europe
    STATE CAPACITY AND THE RISE AND FALL OF SERFDOM IN EUROPE Tracy Dennison California Institute of Technology March 2021 Motivations for This Project Two questions emerged from Voshchazhikovo study: 1) How do the estate- Summary: ➢Role of the state is key to understanding institutional context of serfdom ➢Serfdom is part of a weak state equilibrium; ruler must make concessions to other powerful actors to obtain services/revenues/cooperation. Serfdom is a constraint on fiscal aims of the crown. ➢In order to loosen this constraint, state has to be able to perform administrative functions that its noble agents perform in exchange for their privileges. ➢This happens gradually over 17th- 19th cc in Prussia (and earlier in much of western Europe). Decline of serfdom reflects underlying institutional reconfigurations. ➢In Russia serfdom is formally abolished, but the state still remains weak vis-à-vis other groups with limited options for surplus extraction. ➢Key difference: law - legal practices and processes - esp enforcement of property rights emerges as an important tool for states in western/central Europe but not in Russia ➢This suggestive finding has implications for our understanding of origins of ”inclusive”/”open access” institutions and emergence of strong central states Larger Political Economy of Serfdom Towns Merchants State Craft Guilds MerchantsNobles Peasants Even Larger Political Economy of Serfdom Towns Merchants State Craft Guilds MerchantsNobles CHURCH Peasants Institutional Framework of Serfdom Key Points (and Caveats): ➢State concedes privileges to different groups – all of which (including the state) are competing for surpluses - in exchange for: administration (tax collection, conscription), military service, revenue, loans, loyalty ➢These groups are not monolithic – nor is the state; there is internal conflict and there can be shifting alliances.
    [Show full text]
  • Serfs and the Market: Second Serfdom and the East-West Goods Exchange, 1579-1857
    Serfs and the Market: Second Serfdom and the East-West goods exchange, 1579-1857 Tom Raster1 Paris School of Economics [email protected] This version: June 2, 2019 Abstract Using novel shipment-level data on maritime trade between 1579 and 1856, this paper documents the evolution in grain exports from from Western to Eastern Europe and the rise of unfree labor in the former. Hypotheses first formulated more than 60 years ago, that export opportunities spurred labor coercion, motivate the exploration of this relationship. A new dataset of key labor legislation dates in the Baltic area captures de-jure unfree labor (e.g. serfdom or mobility bans). We also capture de-facto variation in coercion using existing data on coercion proxies (land holdings, serf manumission and/or wages) in Denmark, Prussia and Scania and novel household-level corvée data in Estonia. Our findings suggest that increases in grain prices and exports to the West happen, in many instances, concurrently with increases in de-jure and de-facto coercion in the East; thus, providing support for the hypothesis. Specifically, we observe that locations with better export potential see higher de-facto la- bor coercion; a finding that cannot be reconciled with existing models which predict less coercion in the proximity of cities due to outside options. We rationalize these findings in a new, open-economy labor coercion model that explains why foreign demand for grain is particularly likely to foster coercion. Our empirics may also be interpreted as evidence that Scania’s opening of the land market to peasants allowed them to benefit from trade and reduced labor coercion even in the absence of any coercion-constraining labor policies.
    [Show full text]
  • Russian Serfdom, Emancipation, and Land Inequality: New Evidence
    Russian Serfdom, Emancipation, and Land Inequality: New Evidence Steven Nafziger1 Department of Economics, Williams College May 2013 Note to Readers: This long descriptive paper is part of an even larger project - "Serfdom, Emancipation, and Economic Development in Tsarist Russia" - that is very much a work in progress. As such, some obvious extensions are left out. I apologize for any inconsistencies that remain. Abstract Serfdom is often viewed as a major institutional constraint on the economic development of Tsarist Russia, one that persisted well after emancipation occurred in 1861 through the ways that property rights were transferred to the peasantry. However, scholars have generally asserted this causal relationship with few facts in hand. This paper introduces a variety of newly collected data, covering European Russia at the district (uezd) level, to describe serfdom, emancipation, and the subsequent evolution of land holdings among the rural population into the 20th century. A series of simple empirical exercises describes several important ways that the institution of serfdom varied across European Russia; outlines how the emancipation reforms differentially affected the minority of privately owned serfs relative to the majority of other types of peasants; and connects these differences to long-run variation in land ownership, obligations, and inequality. The evidence explored in this paper constitutes the groundwork for considering the possible channels linking the demise of serfdom to Russia’s slow pace of economic growth prior to the Bolshevik Revolution. JEL Codes: N33, Keywords: Russia, economic history, serfdom, inequality, land reform, institutions 1 Tracy Dennison offered thoughtful questions at the onset of this project. Ivan Badinski, Cara Foley, Veranika Li, Aaron Seong, and Stefan Ward-Wheten provided wonderful research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • THE COMMUNIST MANIFESTO Freeman and Slave, Patrician And
    THE COMMUNIST MANIFESTO Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels A spectre is haunting Europe — the spectre of communism. All the powers of old Europe have entered into a holy alliance to exorcise this spectre: Pope and tsar, Metternich and Guizot, French Radicals and German police-spies. Where is the party in opposition that has not been decried as communistic by its opponents in power? Where is the opposition that has not hurled back the branding reproach of communism, against the more advanced opposition parties, as well as against its reactionary adversaries? Two things result from this fact: I. Communism is already acknowledged by all European powers to be itself a power. II. It is high time that Communists should openly, in the face of the whole world, publish their views, their aims, their tendencies, and meet this nursery tale of the spectre of communism with a manifesto of the party itself. To this end, Communists of various nationalities have assembled in London, and sketched the following manifesto, to be published in the English, French, German, Italian, Flemish and Danish languages. I. BOURGEOIS AND PROLETARIANS The history of all hitherto existing society is the history of class struggles. Freeman and slave, patrician and plebeian, lord and serf, guild- master and journeyman, in a word, oppressor and oppressed stood in constant opposition to one another, carried on an uninterrupted, now hidden, now open fight, a fight that each time ended, either in a revolutionary reconstitution of society at large, or in the common ruin of the contending classes. 240 THE COMMUNIST MANIFESTO 241 in the earlier epochs of history, we find almost everywhere a compli- cated arrangement of society into various orders, a manifold gradation of social rank.
    [Show full text]
  • Government Finance and Imposition of Serfdom After the Black Death
    Government Finance and Imposition of Serfdom after the Black Death Margaret E. Peters∗ University of California, Los Angeles Abstract After the Black Death, serfdom disappeared in Western Europe while making a resurgence in Eastern Europe. What explains this difference? I argue that serfdom was against the interests of the sovereign and was only imposed when the nobility, most of whom needed serfdom to maintain their economic and social standing, had leverage to impose their will. One way the nobility gained this power was through financing the military. Using data from the fourteenth to through the eighteenth centuries, I show that serfdom was imposed in areas where sovereigns had few other resources to pay for war or defense. This paper addresses the causes of a historical institution that scholars from Moore (1966) to Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) have argued played an important role in the development, or lack thereof, of democracy and long-term economic growth. ∗Department of Political Science, UCLA, 4289 Bunche Hall, Los Angeles, CA 90095, [email protected]. I would like to thank Jessica Clayton, Stephen Moncrief, and Mark Toukan for their research assistance. I would also like to thank Maarten Bosker, Davide Cantoni, David Stasavage, and Nico Voigtländer for sharing their data. and Allison Carnegie, Jeff Colgan, Mark Dincecco, Steve Haber, Seva Guinitsky, Andrew Kerner, Frances Rosenbluth, David Steinberg, Felicity Vabulas, and the participants of the Stanford Comparative Politics Workshop, the 2013 IPES Conference, the 2014 International Studies Association Annual Conference, and the Yale International Relations Workshop for their comments. All errors remain my own. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3320807 Introduction In Late Medieval and Early Modern Europe, the laws governing the lives of peasants in Europe diverged.
    [Show full text]
  • Macmaster2016.Pdf (2.463Mb)
    This thesis has been submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for a postgraduate degree (e.g. PhD, MPhil, DClinPsychol) at the University of Edinburgh. Please note the following terms and conditions of use: This work is protected by copyright and other intellectual property rights, which are retained by the thesis author, unless otherwise stated. A copy can be downloaded for personal non-commercial research or study, without prior permission or charge. This thesis cannot be reproduced or quoted extensively from without first obtaining permission in writing from the author. The content must not be changed in any way or sold commercially in any format or medium without the formal permission of the author. When referring to this work, full bibliographic details including the author, title, awarding institution and date of the thesis must be given. The Transformative Impact of the Slave Trade on the Roman World, 580 - 720 Thomas J. MacMaster Thesis submitted for PhD The University of Edinburgh 2015 T. J. MacMaster, The Transformative Impact of the Slave Trade on the Roman World, 1 580-720 T. J. MacMaster, The Transformative Impact of the Slave Trade on the Roman World, 2 580-720 Declaration: This is to certify that that the work contained within has been composed by me and is entirely my own work. No part of this thesis has been submitted for any other degree or professional qualification. Signed: T. J. MacMaster, The Transformative Impact of the Slave Trade on the Roman World, 3 580-720 T. J. MacMaster, The Transformative Impact of the Slave Trade on the Roman World, 4 580-720 Table of contents 4 List of Abbreviations 6 Introduction: Slave trading between antiquity and the middle ages 8 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Is That Racist?: One White Family Interrogating Whiteness
    IS THAT RACIST?: ONE WHITE FAMILY INTERROGATING WHITENESS AND CONSTRUCTING ANTIRACIST CURRICULUM A DISSERTATION IN Curriculum and Instruction and Educational Leadership Policy and Foundations Presented to the Faculty of the University of Missouri-Kansas City in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY by RHIANNA KAY THOMAS M.A., University of Missouri-Kansas City, 2008 B.A., Avila University, 2003 Kansas City, Missouri 2019 IS THAT RACIST? ONE WHITE FAMILY INTERROGATING WHITENESS AND CONSTRUCTING ANTIRACIST CURRICULUM Rhianna Kay Thomas, Candidate for the Doctor of Philosophy Degree University of Missouri-Kansas City, 2019 ABSTRACT Despite attempts by white teachers and families to avoid talk about race (Apfelbaum, Paulker, Ambady, Sommers, & Norton, 2008; Bartoli, Michael, Bentley- Edwards, Stevenson, Shor, & McClain, 2016; Boutte, López-Robertson, & Powers- Costello, 2011; Lesane-Brown, Brown, Tanner-Smith, & Bruce, 2010; Pahlke, Bigler, & Suizzo, 2012; Vittrup & Holden, 2010), children learn race and racism at a young age (Derman-Sparks & Edwards, 2010; Miller, 2015; Park, 2011; Van Ausdale & Feagin, 2001). While there is a limited body of literature on racial socialization in schools (Park, 2011; Priest, Walton, White, Kowal, Baker, & Paradies, 2016; Van Ausdale & Feagin, 2001) and white racial socialization in the home (Bartoli et al., 2016; Miller, 2015; Vittrup & Holden, 2011), this study examines the ways white children come to understand race in the context of an emergent antiracist home curriculum. Using a critical sociocultural orientation, this study employs parent child autoethnography and poetic inquiry to demonstrate how two white children used race words, metaphor, analogy, and political action to construct understandings of race. iii APPROVAL PAGE The faculty listed below, appointed by the Dean of the School of Graduate Studies, have examined a dissertation entitled “Is That Racist? One White Family Interrogating Whiteness and Constructing Antiracist Curriculum” presented by Rhianna K.
    [Show full text]
  • Serfdom and State Power in Imperial Russia
    Roger Bartlett Serfdom and State Power in Imperial Russia The institution of serfdom has been a central and much debated feature of early modern Russian history: it has sometimes been described as Russia’s ‘peculiar institution’, as central to the Russian experience as black slavery has been to the American.1 It is striking, however, that the rise and dominance of serfdom within Muscovite/Russian society coincided closely in historical terms with the rise to European eminence and power of the Muscovite state and Russian Empire. The subjection of the peasantry to its landlord masters was finally institutionalized in 1649, at a time when for most of the rest of Europe Muscovy was a little-known and peripheral state, in John Milton’s words, ‘the most northern Region of Europe reputed civil’.2 When Peter I proclaimed Russia an empire, in 1721, it had displaced Sweden to become the leading state of Northern Europe; one hundred years later Russia was the premier European land power. Its loss of international status after the Crimean War in 1856 helped to precipitate the abolition of serfdom (1861); but the ‘Great Reforms’ of the 1860s did not enable it to regain the international position achieved after the Napoleonic Wars. Thus the period of history from the mid-seventeenth to mid-nineteenth centuries, when serfdom became a securely entrenched legal and economic institution, was also the period in which Russia — the Muscovite state and Russian Empire — became relatively more powerful than at any other time in its history before 1945. This article seeks to examine some of the features of serfdom in Russia, to look briefly at its place in the structure and dynamics of Russian society, and to investigate the relationship between the establish- ment of serfdom in practice and the success of Russian govern- ments both in domestic affairs and on the international stage.
    [Show full text]
  • Hayek Road to Serfdom.Indd
    The Road to Serfdom by Friedrich A. Hayek (1899–1992) CHAPTER 6 PLANNING AND THE RULE OF LAW Recent studies in the sociology of law once more confirm that the fundamental principle of formal law by which every case must be judged according to general rational precepts, which have as few exceptions as possible and are based on logical subsumptions, obtains only for the liberal competitive phase of capitalism. ―Karl Mannheim 1 Nothing distinguishes more clearly conditions in a free country from those in a country under arbitrary government than the observance in the former of the great principles known as the Rule of Law. Stripped of all technicalities, this means that government in all its actions is bound by rules fixed and announced beforehand— 5 rules which make it possible to foresee with fair certainty how the authority will use its coercive powers in given circumstances and to plan one’s individual affairs on the basis of this knowledge.1 Though this ideal can never be perfectly achieved, since legislators as well as those to whom the administration of the law is intrusted are fallible men, the essential point, that the discretion left to the executive organs 10 wielding coercive power should be reduced as much as possible, is clear enough. While every law restricts individual freedom to some extent by altering the means which people may use in the pursuit of their aims, under the Rule of Law the govern- ment is prevented from stultifying individual efforts by ad hoc action. Within the known rules of the game the individual is free to pursue his personal ends and desires, 15 certain that the powers of government will not be used deliberately to frustrate his efforts.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Causes of Slavery Or Serfdom and the Roads to Agrarian Capitalism: Domar’Shypothesisrevisited
    On the Causes of Slavery or Serfdom and the Roads to Agrarian Capitalism: Domar’sHypothesisRevisited Jonathan Conning∗ November 2004 Abstract I propose a simple general equilibrium formalization of Domar’s famous hy- pothesis on the causes of slavery or serfdom that emphasizes the interactions between factor endowments, the nature of the production technologies, and the initial distribution of property rights over land. The model provides a frame- work within which to understand the choice between slavery, serfdom, and free labor and tenancy equilibria with or without bonded labor-service obligations. The model also sheds light on the ‘Agrarian Question’ regarding why some otherwise similar regions transitioned to free-labor agrarian capitalism via an ‘American road’ dominated by independent family farms while others followed a ‘Junker road’ with production dominated by large estates surrounded by small semi-proletarianized peasant households. The model is built around an otherwise canonical general equilibrium trade model adapted to allow for the endogenous emergence of land oligopoly and labor oligopsony power distortions that shape the pattern of agrarian production organization. ∗Special thanks to Doug Gollin, Timothy Guinnane, Francois Maniquet, Agostino Mantegna, Mario Pastore, James A. Robinson and Robert Thornton for helpful discussions of topics addressed in this paper as well as seminar participants at Yale, Namur and the CUNY Graduate Center. Contact information: Department of Economics, Hunter College and the Graduate Center (CUNY), 695 Park Avenue, New York, NY 10021; e-mail: [email protected]. 1 1 Introduction “[I]n the context of universal history, free labour, wage labour, is the peculiar institution (historian Moses Finley, 1976).” Coerced labor arrangements or ‘voluntary’ but servile labor forms of one form or another have played an important role in the organization of production for the better part of human civilization and in almost all known societies.
    [Show full text]