Thomas C. Schelling

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Thomas C. Schelling Chancellor's Distinguished Fellows Program 2007-2008 Selective Bibliography UC Irvine Libraries Thomas C. Schelling 6 March 2008 Prepared by: Daniel C. Tsang Economics, Political Science, Asian American Studies & Acting Film & Media Studies Bibliographer [email protected] Table of Contents Books by Schelling……………………………….………….. 1 Book Chapters by Schelling ..………...……………………… 2 Rand and Other Reports by Schelling………………………... 5 Journal and Magazine Articles by Schelling……….……….... 5 Newspaper Articles by Schelling….….……………………… 7 Web Articles by Schelling………………….………………... 8 Books and Theses about Schelling….………………………... 8 Articles about Schelling…………………………....……….... 9 Reviews of Schelling’s Books…….….……………………… 11 Web Articles about Schelling……...……….………………... 13 Articles cited may contain hyperlinks to UCI-licensed resources. To connect from off-campus: http://www.lib.uci.edu/services/how/connect.html Pagination may refer only to first page of the cited article. Books by Schelling Micromotives and Macrobehavior. New York: Norton, 2006. New edition. Langson Library Call Number H61 .S355 2006 1 Strategies of Commitment and Other Essays. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2006. Langson Library Call Number HB846.8 .S34 2006 The Western Community and the Gorbachev Challenge. Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, 1989. Co-edited with Armand Clesse. Langson Library Call Number DK286.5 .W48 1989 Choice and Consequence. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1984. Langson Library Call Number H35 .S335 1984 Incentives for Environmental Protection. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1983. Editor. Langson Library Call Number HC79.E5 I513 1983 Thinking Through the Energy Problem. New York: Committee for Economic Development, 1979. Langson Library Call Number HD9502.U52 S32 Micromotives and Macrobehavior. New York: Norton, 1978. Langson Library Call Number H61 .S355 1978 Arms and Influence. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1966. Langson Library Call Number U104 .S33 Strategy and Arms Control. New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1961. Langson Library Call Number UA11 .S27 The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1960. Langson Library Call Number BF637.N4 S3 c. 2 International Economics. Boston, MA: Allyn and Bacon, 1958. Langson Library Call Number HF1411 .S297 National Income Behavior: An Introduction to Algebraic Analysis. New York: McGraw- Hill, 1951. Based on his Ph.D thesis at Harvard University, 1951. Langson Library Call Number HA40.I5 S35 Book Chapters by Schelling “The Marshall Plan: A Model for What?” In: John Agnew and J. Nicholas Entrikin, eds. The Marshall Plan Today: Model and Metaphor. New York: Routledge, 2004. http://www.economicsnetbase.com/books/2732/0714655147ch9.pdf "Commitment: Deliberate vs. Involuntary." In: Randloph M. Nesse, ed. Evolution and the Capacity for Commitment. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2001. 2 "Commitment." In: Peter Newman ed. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law. Macmillan, 1998. "Comment." In: Climate Change Policy, Economic Growth, and Environmental Quality. Washington DC: American Council for Capital Formation, Center for Policy Research, April 1998. "Social Mechanisms and Social Dynamics." In: Peter Hedström and Richard Swedberg, eds. Social Mechanisms: An Analytical Approach to Social Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998. Langson Library Call Number HM24 .S54426 1998 "Why Does Economics Help Only With Easy Problems?" In: Peter A. G. van Bergeijk, et al, eds. Economic Science and Practice: The Roles of Academic Economists and Policy- makers. Lyme, NH: Edward Elgar, 1997, 134-146. Langson Library Call Number HB74.P65 E356 1997 "The Role of Nuclear Weapons." In: L. Benjamin Ederington and Michael J. Mazarr, eds. Turning Point: The Gulf War and U. S. Military Strategy. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1994. Langson Library Call Number UA23 .T85 1994 "Greenhouse Effect." In: David R. Henderson, ed. The Fortune Encyclopedia of Economics. New York: Warner Books, 1993, 447-452. Langson Library Call Number HB61 .F67 1993 “The Global Dimension." In: Graham Allison and Gregory F. Treverton, eds. Rethinking America's Security: Beyond Cold War to New World Order. New York: Norton, 1992, 196-210. Langson Library Call Number UA23 .R458 1992 "Economic Responses to Global Warming: Prospects for Cooperative Approaches." In: Rudiger Dornbush and James M. Poterba, eds. Global Warming: Economic Policy Responses. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991. Langson Library Call Number HC79.A4 G56 1991 "Cigarette Smoking: A Study of Change in Behavior." In: Martin Shubik, ed. Risk, Organizations, and Society. Boston: Kluwer, 1991, 129-42. "The Marshall Plan: A Rehearsal for the Atlantic Alliance." In: Armand Clesse and Archie C. Epps, eds. Present at the Creation: The Fortieth Anniversary of the Marshall Plan. New York: Harper and Row, 1990, 60-69. Langson Library Call Number HC240 .P68 1990 "Global Environmental Forces." In: John L. Helm, ed. Energy: Production, Consumption, and Consequences. National Academy Press, 1990, 75-84. 3 Science Library Bar Call Number TJ163.15 .E5384 1990 "Life, Liberty or the Pursuit of Happiness." In: Isabel V. Sawhill, ed. Challenge to Leadership: Economic and Social Issues for the Next Decade. Washington DC: The Urban Institute, 1988. Langson Library Call Number HC106.8 .C465 1988 "Value of Life." In: John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, eds. The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. IV. London: Macmillan, 1987, 793-6. Langson Library Reference Call Number HB61 .N49 1987b v.4 "The Role of War Games and Exercises." In: Ashton B. Carter et al., eds. Managing Nuclear Operations. The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., 1986, 426-444. Langson Library Call Number U263 .M324 1987 c.2 "Against Backsliding." In: Alejandro Foxley et al., eds. Development, Democracy and the Art of Trespassing: Essays in Honor of Albert O. Hirschman. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press, 1986, 233-238. Langson Library Call Number HD74 .D48 1986 "Whose Business Is Good Behavior?" In: Winthrop Knowlton and Richard Zeckhauser, ed. American Society: Public and Private Responsibilities. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, 1986, 153-180. Langson Library Call Number HN53 .A64 1986 "Policy Analysis as a Science of Choice." In: R. S. Ganapathy et al., eds. Public Policy and Policy Analysis in India. Sage Publications, 1985, 19-29. "The Mind as a Consuming Organ," In: Jon Elster, ed. The Multiple Self. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985. Langson Library Call Number BD450 .M78 1986 "Energy Security: International Implications." In: Richard J. Gonzalez, Raymond W. Smilor, and Joel Darmstadter, eds. Improving U.S. Energy Security. Cambridge, MA., Ballinger, 1985. Langson Library Call Number HD9502.U52 I48 1985 "Common Security and the Limitation of War." In: Stockholm International Peace Research Institute. Policies for Common Security. Philadelphia: Taylor and Francis, 1985, 129-33. Langson Library Call Number JX1952 .P585 1985 "Alternative Sources of Middle East Conflict." In: Nissan Oren, ed. Images and Reality in International Politics. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1984, 206-210. Langson Library Call Number JX1391 .I535 1984 4 "Confidence in Crisis." In: Karl Kaiser, ed., Confidence-Building Measures. Forschungsinstitut des Deutschen Gesellschaft fur Auswartige Politik, December 1983. "Arrangements for Reciprocal Assurance." In: Hilliard Roderick and Ulla Magnusson, eds. Avoiding Inadvertent War: Crisis Management. Austin, TX: Lyndon B. Johnson School of Public Affairs, University of Texas, 1983, 123-30. Langson Library Call Number JX1974.8 .A96 1983 "Climate Change: Implications for Welfare and Policy." In: Changing Climate: Report of the Carbon Dioxide Assessment Committee. The National Academy Press, 1983. Science Library Bar Call Number QC981.8.C5 C44 1983 Rand and Other Reports by Schelling Strategy and Self-command . Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corporation, 1985. Langson Library Call Number BF632 .S33 1985 A Tribute to Bernard Brodie and (Incidentally) to Rand. Santa Monica, CA: Rand, 1979. Langson Library Call Number: AS36 .R28 no.6355 Models of Segregation. Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corp., 1969. Science Library Bar Call Number Q180.A1 R36 no. 6014 The Role of Theory in the Study of Conflict. Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corp., 1960. Science Library Bar Call Number Q180.A1 R36 no. 2515 International Cost-sharing Arrangements. Princeton, NJ: International Finance Section, Dept. of Economics and Sociology, Princeton University, 1955. Langson Library Call Number HG136 .P7 no.24 Journal and Magazine Articles by Schelling “Nuclear Deterrence for the Future.”Issues in Science and Technology 23/1 (Fall 2006), 50-52. “What Makes Greenhouse Sense?” Foreign Affairs (May/June 2002). http://www.foreignaffairs.org/20020501facomment8138-p0/thomas-c-schelling/what- makes-greenhouse-sense.html "Intergenerational and International Discounting," Risk Analysis 20/6 (2000), 833-838. “Some Economics of Global Warming.” American Economic Review 82/1, 1992, 1. http://sedac.ciesin.org/mva/iamcc.tg/articles/SC1992/SC1992.html 5 "The Legacy of Hiroshima: A Half-Century Without Nuclear War.” Philosophy & Public Policy 20/2-3 (Summer 2000). http://www.puaf.umd.edu/IPPP/Summer00/legacy_of_hiroshima.htm "Remembering Mancur Olson." Southern Economic Journal 66/3 (2000), 793-800. "The Environmental Challenges of Power Generation." The Energy Journal 19/2 (1998), 115-128. "The Cost of Combatting Global Warming," Foreign Affairs 76/6 (November/December1997), 8-14. "The Contradiction
Recommended publications
  • ON the EARLY HISTORY of EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS Alvin E
    ON THE EARLY HISTORY OF EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS Alvin E. Roth I. INTRODUCTION In the course of coediting the Handbook of Experimental Economics it became clear to me that contemporary experimental economists tend to carry around with them different and very partial accounts of the history of this still emerging field. This project began as an attempt to merge these "folk histories" of the origins of what I am confident will eventually be seen as an important chapter in the history and sociology of economics. I won't try to pin down the first economic experiment, although I am partial to Bernoulli (1738) on the St. Petersburg paradox. The Bernoullis (Daniel and Nicholas) were not content to rely solely on their own intuitions, and resorted to the practice of asking other famous scholars for their opinions on that difficult choice problem. Allowing for their rather informal report, this is not so different from the practice of using hypothetical choice problems to generate hypotheses about individual choice behavior, which has been used to good effect in much more modern research on individual choice. But I think that searching for scientific "firsts" is often less illuminating than it is sometimes thought to be. In connection with the history of an entirely different subject, I once had occasion to draw the following analogy (Roth and Sotomayor 1990, p. 170): Columbus is viewed as the discoverer of America, even though every school child knows that the Americas were inhabited when he arrived, and that he was not even the first to have made a round trip, having been preceded by Vikings and perhaps by others.
    [Show full text]
  • Who Are the Behavioral Economists and What Do They Say?
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Heukelom, Floris Working Paper Who are the Behavioral Economists and what do they say? Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, No. 07-020/1 Provided in Cooperation with: Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam and Rotterdam Suggested Citation: Heukelom, Floris (2007) : Who are the Behavioral Economists and what do they say?, Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, No. 07-020/1, Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam and Rotterdam This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/86489 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu TI 2007-020/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper Who are the Behavioral Economists and what do they say? Floris Heukelom University of Amsterdam, and Tinbergen Institute.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Game Theory
    Economic game theory: a learner centred introduction Author: Dr Peter Kührt Introduction to game theory Game theory is now an integral part of business and politics, showing how decisively it has shaped modern notions of strategy. Consultants use it for projects; managers swot up on it to make smarter decisions. The crucial aim of mathematical game theory is to characterise and establish rational deci- sions for conflict and cooperation situations. The problem with it is that none of the actors know the plans of the other “players” or how they will make the appropriate decisions. This makes it unclear for each player to know how their own specific decisions will impact on the plan of action (strategy). However, you can think about the situation from the perspective of the other players to build an expectation of what they are going to do. Game theory therefore makes it possible to illustrate social conflict situations, which are called “games” in game theory, and solve them mathematically on the basis of probabilities. It is assumed that all participants behave “rationally”. Then you can assign a value and a probability to each decision option, which ultimately allows a computational solution in terms of “benefit or profit optimisation”. However, people are not always strictly rational because seemingly “irrational” results also play a big role for them, e.g. gain in prestige, loss of face, traditions, preference for certain colours, etc. However, these “irrational" goals can also be measured with useful values so that “restricted rational behaviour” can result in computational results, even with these kinds of models.
    [Show full text]
  • Arms and Influence by Thomas Schelling
    01 Arms and Influence By Thomas Schelling DESCRIPTION This is an influential book written during the Cold War addressing the concept of deterrence. The author’s purpose is to discuss the “diplomacy of violence” in which states use the ability to cause harm to other nations as bargaining power (deterrence and compellence). - Air University SIGNIFICANCE TO THE DETERRENCE COMMUNITY Thomas Schelling was one of the intellectual founders of US nuclear deterrence thinking, and his writing still resonates in the work of deterrence scholars and practitioners today. Schelling’s profound analysis of the impact of nuclear weapons on diplomacy and international relations is timeless and essential reading. This book provides an intellectual and historical basis for understanding contemporary nuclear deterrence issues. 02 The Case for U.S. Nuclear Weapons in the 21st Century By Brad Roberts DESCRIPTION The case against nuclear weapons has been made on many grounds—including historical, political, and moral. But, Brad Roberts argues, it has not so far been informed by the experience of the United States since the Cold War in trying to adapt deterrence to a changed world, and to create the conditions that would allow further significant changes to U.S. nuclear policy and posture. - Stanford Security Press SIGNIFICANCE TO THE DETERRENCE COMMUNITY Roberts draws on his experience and academic acumen in this thoughtful, well-researched book. Contrary to those scholars making calls for global nuclear disarmament, Roberts argues the need for and utility of U.S. nuclear weapons now and into the future. After a review of post- Cold War U.S. nuclear policies, Roberts provides in-depth analysis of some of the major nuclear proliferation and deterrence challenges for U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas C. Schelling [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Daniel B
    Thomas C. Schelling [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Daniel B. Klein Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 576-590 Abstract Thomas C. Schelling is among the 71 individuals who were awarded the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel between 1969 and 2012. This ideological profile is part of the project called “The Ideological Migration of the Economics Laureates,” which fills the September 2013 issue of Econ Journal Watch. Keywords Classical liberalism, economists, Nobel Prize in economics, ideology, ideological migration, intellectual biography. JEL classification A11, A13, B2, B3 Link to this document http://econjwatch.org/file_download/765/SchellingIPEL.pdf ECON JOURNAL WATCH Cowen, Tyler. 2011. Thomas Sargent, Nobel Laureate. Marginal Revolution, October 10. Link Klamer, Arjo. 1984. Conversations with Economists: New Classical Economists and Their Opponents Speak Out on the Current Controversy in Macroeconomics. Totowa, N.J.: Rowman & Allanheld. Sargent, Thomas J. 1984. Interview by Arjo Klamer. In Conversations with Economists: New Classical Economists and Their Opponents Speak Out on the Current Controversy in Macroeconomics by Klamer. Totowa, N.J.: Rowman & Allanheld. Sargent, Thomas J. 1998. Interview by Esther-Mirjam Sent. In The Revolving Rationality of Rational Expectations: An Assessment of Thomas Sargent’s Achievements by Sent, 163-178. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Sargent, Thomas J. 2008. Rational Expectations. In The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics, ed. David R. Henderson. Liberty Fund (Indianapolis). Link Sargent, Thomas J. 2010. Interview by Arthur Rolnick. The Region (Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis), September: 26-39. Link Sargent, Thomas J. 2011a. United States Then, Europe Now. Presented at Stockholm University, December 8.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Varied Roles of Rationality in Negotiation and Conflict Resolution
    University of Florida Levin College of Law UF Law Scholarship Repository UF Law Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship Spring 1998 Reasoning Along Different Lines: Some Varied Roles of Rationality in Negotiation and Conflict Resolution Jonathan R. Cohen University of Florida Levin College of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/facultypub Recommended Citation Jonathan R. Cohen, Reasoning Along Different Lines: Some Varied Roles of Rationality in Negotiation and Conflict Resolution, 3 Harv. Negot. L. Rev. 111 (1998), available at http://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/ facultypub/440 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at UF Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in UF Law Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of UF Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Reasoning Along Different Lines: Some Varied Roles of Rationality in Negotiation and Conflict Resolution Jonathan R. Cohent I. INTRODUCTION Much of our academic understanding of negotiation and conflict resolution has come through the lens of game theory. Game theory, like its parent discipline economics, typically builds upon the as- sumption that people are rational. Indeed, for many, the assumption of rational behavior lies at the core of the game theoretic approach.' Furthermore, the meaning of "rational" that is applied within game theory is typically the same as that used within other areas of eco- nomics: each person is presumed to act so as to make himself or her- self as well off as possible. Often this model goes by the label of utility maximization.
    [Show full text]
  • An Experimental Investigation of Focal Points in Explicit Bargaining
    Efficiency, Equality and Labelling: An Experimental Investigation of Focal Points in Explicit Bargaining Andrea Isoni, Anders Poulsen, Robert Sugden and Kei Tsutsui 20 November 2013 ♠ Abstract We investigate Schelling’s hypothesis that payoff-irrelevant labels (‘cues’) can influence the outcomes of bargaining games with communication. In our experimental games, players negotiate over the division of a surplus by claiming valuable objects that have payoff- irrelevant spatial locations. Negotiation occurs in continuous time, constrained by a deadline. In some games, spatial cues are opposed to principles of equality or efficiency. We find a strong tendency for players to agree on efficient and minimally unequal payoff divisions, even if spatial cues suggest otherwise. But if there are two such divisions, cues are often used to select between them, inducing distributional effects. Keywords : explicit bargaining, focal point, labels, salience, cheap talk JEL classification : C72, C78, C91 ♠ Isoni: Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry (UK), CV4 7AL, email: [email protected] . Poulsen: Centre for Behavioural and Experimental Social Science, University of East Anglia, Norwich (UK), NR4 7TJ, email: [email protected] . Sugden (corresponding author): Centre for Behavioural and Experimental Social Science and Centre for Competition Policy, University of East Anglia, Norwich (UK), NR4 7TJ, email: [email protected] . Tsutsui: Frankfurt School of Finance and Management, 60314 Frankfurt am Main, email: [email protected] . This research was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council of the UK (award no. RES-000-22-3322). 1 In The Strategy of Conflict , Thomas Schelling (1960: 53, 67–74) proposes the hypothesis that the outcomes of bargaining problems can be systematically influenced by ‘incidental details’ or (as they would now be called) properties of framing or labelling.
    [Show full text]
  • Voting Systems, Honest Preferences and Pareto Optimality Author(S): Richard Zeckhauser Source: the American Political Science Review, Vol
    Voting Systems, Honest Preferences and Pareto Optimality Author(s): Richard Zeckhauser Source: The American Political Science Review, Vol. 67, No. 3 (Sep., 1973), pp. 934-946 Published by: American Political Science Association Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1958635 Accessed: 27-05-2020 22:08 UTC REFERENCES Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1958635?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Political Science Review This content downloaded from 206.253.207.235 on Wed, 27 May 2020 22:08:36 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Voting Systems, Honest Preferences and Pareto Optimality* RICHARD ZECKHAUSER Harvard University "In a capitalist democracy there are essentially A Desirable Voting Scheme two methods by which social choices can be made: In the market, an individual indicates his pref- voting, typically used to make 'political' decisions, erences through his purchases and sales. In and the market mechanism, typically used to make general, these tracings are insufficient to define an 'economic' decisions."' To economists, the freely individual's complete preference mapping, but functioning competitive market mechanism has from the standpoint of efficiency this creates no alluring structural properties.2 If each individual difficulties.
    [Show full text]
  • Rational Expectations: Retrospect and Prospect
    Rational Expectations: Retrospect and Prospect A Panel Discussion with Michael Lovell Robert Lucas Dale Mortensen Robert Shiller Neil Wallace Moderated by Kevin Hoover Warren Young CHOPE Working Paper No. 2011-10 30 May 2011 Rational Expectations: Retrospect and Prospect A Panel Discussion with Michael Lovell Robert Lucas Dale Mortensen Robert Shiller Neil Wallace Moderated by Kevin Hoover † Warren Young * 30 May 2011 †Department of Economics and Department of Philosophy, Duke University. Address: Box 90097, Durham, NC 27278, U.S.A. E-mail [email protected] *Department of Economics, Bar Ilan University. Address: Department of Economics, Bar Ilan University, Ramat Gan 52900, Israel. E-mail: [email protected] 1 Abstract of Rational Expectations: Retrospect and Prospect The transcript of a panel discussion marking the fiftieth anniversary of John Muth’s “Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements” ( Econometrica 1961). The panel consists of Michael Lovell, Robert Lucas, Dale Mortensen, Robert Shiller, and Neil Wallace. The discussion is moderated by Kevin Hoover and Warren Young. The panel touches on a wide variety of issues related to the rational-expectations hypothesis, including: its history, starting with Muth’s work at Carnegie Tech; its methodological role; applications to policy; its relationship to behavioral economics; its role in the recent financial crisis; and its likely future. JEL Codes: B22, B31, B26, E17 Keywords: rational expectations, John F. Muth, macroeconomics, dynamics, macroeconomic policy, behavioral economics, efficient markets 2 “Rational Expectations” 28 May 2011 Rational Expectations: Retrospect and Prospect: A Panel Discussion with Michael Lovell, Robert Lucas, Dale Mortensen, Robert Shiller and Neil Wallace, Moderated by Kevin Hoover and Warren Young The panel discussion was held in a session sponsored by the History of Economics Society at the Allied Social Sciences Association (ASSA) meetings in the Capitol 1 Room of the Hyatt Regency Hotel in Denver, Colorado on 7 January 2011.
    [Show full text]
  • EAP Volume 3 Issue 1 Cover and Front Matter
    ECONOMICS AND PHILOSOPHY Cambridge University Press Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 170.106.35.76, on 28 Sep 2021 at 03:06:27, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0266267100002698 ECONOMICS AND PHILOSOPHY Editors Daniel M. Hausman Michael S. McPherson Carnegie-Mellon University Williams College Editorial Board Kenneth Arrow, Stanford University; Mark Blaug, University of London Institute of Education; Robert Cooter, University of California, Berkeley; Neil de Marchi, Duke University; Ronald Dworkin, Oxford University and New York University Law School; Jon Elster, University of Oslo and University of Chicago; Frank Hahn, Cambridge University; Albert Hirschman, Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton; Sidney Morgenbesser, Columbia University; Donald McCIoskey, University of Iowa; Derek Parfit, All Souls College, Oxford University; John Roemer, University of California, Davis; Alexander Rosenberg, Syra- cuse University; Thomas Schelling, Harvard University; Amartya Sen, All Souls College, Oxford Univer- sity; Christopher Sims, University of Minnesota; Hal Varian, University of Michigan Aims and Scope Economics and Philosophy is a semi-annual history, while ethics and political philosophy journal designed to foster collaboration be- must depend on what we know about human tween economists and philosophers and to aims and interests and about the principles, bridge the increasingly artificial disciplinary benefits, and drawbacks of different forms of boundaries that divide them. Economists more social organization and more acknowledge that their work in both Papers in Economics and Philosophy will positive and normative economics depends on explore the foundations of economics as both methodological and ethical commitments that a predictive/explanatory enterprise and a nor- demand philosophical study and justification.
    [Show full text]
  • Course Information
    ECON 452: Senior Seminar Sweet Briar College, Fall 2012 Sherry Forbes Gray 317 T/R 1030-1200 434.381.6177 [email protected] j j j Course Information Description The original will of Alfred Nobel (1895) established Nobel Prizes in only five fields - physics, chemistry, medicine or physiology, literature, and peace - and the Prize continues to be considered one of the most prestigious awards for advances in those fields today. But in 1968, the Sveriges Riksbank established a Nobel Prize in the field of Economic Sciences, establishing an award for economists who "have during the previous year rendered the greatest service to mankind." But why economics? Nobel Prizes were not originally established for any field in the social sciences, so why was economics the only one to get a Nobel Prize? What is this "service" that economists provide, and what is the relevance of this "science of economics" for today’s problems? These are the questions we are going to address in this seminar as we study the contributions of the Nobel laureates. Specifically, we are going to examine 1.) the development of modern economics through the contributions of the Nobel Prize winners in economics, and 2.) how those ideas influenced (and continue to influence) every day life and how we think about the "big ideas" of today. Economics is not a "settled" discipline - the development of economic ideas and of economics as a science has not been neat, organized, or even at times very coherent. Why is there so much controversy? Much of the debate, of course, revolves around the appropriate role for government and how much we should rely on free markets or government intervention to solve society’sproblems.
    [Show full text]
  • 176 Ethics October 2007 Schelling, Thomas C. Strategies Of
    176 Ethics October 2007 Schelling, Thomas C. Strategies of Commitment and Other Essays. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2006. Pp. 360. $39.95 (cloth); $19.95 (paper). In this collection of essays, Thomas Schelling surveys his work of the past five decades. The lead essay revisits his long-standing interest in the strategic logic of commitment, an idea which serves as a leitmotif throughout the book. Though this book is a delightful read, it cannot be recommended to the specialist except as history. Most of the leading strategic ideas will be familiar to anyone trained in game theory. In fairness, many will be familiar as a result of Schelling’s influence, but the point is that most of the ideas have been extended and stated more rigorously elsewhere. Similarly, philosophers interested in the various pe- culiarities and perversities of instrumental rationality would do better to consult Jon Elster’s inevitable contribution on the matter. That being said, the book can be warmly recommended to nonspecialists as a beautifully written survey of the astonishing range of applications for Schelling’s key idea: in the words of his Nobel citation, “that a party can strengthen its position by overtly worsening its own options.” The book consists of nineteen essays (only one new) organized into several clusters. STRATEGIES OF COMMITMENT When Schelling speaks of commitment, he understands the concept as follows: “becoming committed, bound, or obligated to some course of action or inaction or to some constraint on future action. It is relinquishing some options, eliminating some choices, surrendering some control over one’s future behavior.
    [Show full text]