Forget Secular Stagnation, the Bond Market Is Pricing in Secular Stagflation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Forget Secular Stagnation, the Bond Market Is Pricing in Secular Stagflation Forget secular stagnation, Jan von Gerich the bond market is pricing in secular stagflation Nordea Research, 21 February 2017 Everybody seems to be talking about secular stagnation, or the prospect of low or no growth for the foreseeable future. However, what the bond market is currently pricing in is even more frightening: inflation without growth. Does the recent rise in yields really signal expectations of a brighter future? The current low level of nominal interest rates is often taken as a testament that the bond market has lost all hope that the economy would ever rebound. Correspondingly, the recent rise in US bond yields, partly driven by the election of Donald Trump, is generally seen as signalling increased confidence of faster economic growth. This is by far not the whole story. While there are many factors driving the level of long yields, which is ultimately determined by the laws of supply and demand, the economic interpretation of long nominal interest rates is that their level illustrates expectations of real economic growth added with inflation. As a result, higher rates usually indicate brighter growth prospects and vice versa. However, merely looking at nominal rates makes it impossible to conclude, whether higher rates are driven by higher inflation or real growth expectations. A decomposition of long nominal yields into so called real yields and inflation expectations gives a better picture of what the bond market is actually pricing in. Such decomposition reveals some startling findings. First, the level of long nominal yields is mostly accounted for by inflation expectations, while real yields are low or even negative. Second, the rise in nominal yields has been driven by higher inflation expectation, not so much by higher real yields. The current level of nominal yields explained almost fully by inflation expectations nexus.nordea.com/research Current real yields illustrate more than just weak growth prospects… Real yields are what drive the economy and are a major determinant of how easy monetary policy is. From that perspective, the current low real yields can be seen as welcome in trying to bring life into the economy. Apart from weak economic performance, the low real yields illustrate the exceptional central bank stimulus measures, including the massive bond purchase programmes. …but the picture longer out very grim However, the outlook appears much gloomier, when one looks at how the bond market expects real yields to develop going forward. In the US, the 5-year real yield is priced to top at just above 0.5% in the 2030s and start to fall again after that. The economic interpretation of this is that the bond market does not expect US real growth to be much higher than 0.5% annually on average over any 5-year period going forward. Even in the past 10 years, which incorporates the Great Recession, average annual growth has been around 1.3%. The picture for the Euro area is even gloomier. Forward 5-year EUR real rates reach their highs of -0.10% in the 2020s and start to fall again longer out – in other words, an outlook of no economic growth whatsoever. By comparison, the past 10 years has seen growth average some 0.8% despite the financial crisis and the sovereign debt crisis. nexus.nordea.com/research Long real forward rates do not illustrate really any growth expectations It gets worse – the market is pricing in inflation without growth Could the market just be pricing in a scenario, where the central banks are forced to continue ultra-easy monetary policy and keep real yields at artificially low levels over an extended period of time in a desperate attempt to try to lift inflation towards the target? The pricing of inflation expectations overrules such interpretation. Implied 5-year US inflation expectations are expected to be close to 2.5% over the next 25 years. Even in the Euro area, implied 5-year inflation expectations rise above 2% in around ten years’ time and stay there. Central banks are thus expected to reach their inflation targets, and should not have a reason to continue exceptionally accommodative monetary policies. The inflation picture is priced to normalize nexus.nordea.com/research In conclusion, the bond market is pricing in a scenario of very low or no growth even in the longer run – something one might call secular stagnation. However, as the market is pricing in inflation at the same time, secular stagflation is a more appropriate term, an even grimmer prospect. President Trump has not done really anything to change that picture. The bond market pricing illustrates that what the economy really needs is longer-term reforms to lift production capacity. The US economy certainly does not need short-term fiscal stimulus to push inflation expectations even higher. nexus.nordea.com/research Disclaimer and legal disclosures Origin of the publication or report The perception of opinions or recommendations such as Buy or Sell or This publication or report originates from: Nordea Bank AB (publ), including similar expressions may vary and the definition is therefore shown in the its branches Nordea Danmark, filial af Nordea Bank AB (publ), Sverige, research material or on the website of each named source. Nordea Bank AB (publ), filial i Finland and Nordea Bank AB (publ), filial i Norge (together “Nordea”) acting through their unit Nordea Markets. Limitation of liability Nordea or other associated and affiliated companies assume no liability as Nordea Bank AB (publ) is supervised by the Swedish Financial Supervisory regards to any investment, divestment or retention decision taken by the Authority and the branches are supervised by the Swedish Financial investor on the basis of this publication or report. In no event will Nordea or Supervisory Authority and the Financial Supervisory Authorities in their other associated and affiliated companies be liable for direct, indirect or respective countries. incidental, special or consequential damages resulting from the information in this publication or report. Content of the publication or report This publication or report has been prepared solely by Nordea Markets. Risk information The risk of investing in certain financial instruments, including those Opinions or suggestions from Nordea Markets may deviate from mentioned in this document, is generally high, as their market value is recommendations or opinions presented by other departments in Nordea. exposed to a lot of different factors such as the operational and financial The reason may typically be the result of differing time horizons, conditions of the relevant company, growth prospects, change in interest methodologies, contexts or other factors. rates, the economic and political environment, foreign exchange rates, shifts in market sentiments etc. Where an investment or security is denominated in Opinions and price targets are based on one or more methods of valuation, a different currency to the investor’s currency of reference, changes in rates for instance cash flow analysis, use of multiples, behavioural technical of exchange may have an adverse effect on the value, price or income of or analyses of underlying market movements in combination with from that investment to the investor. Past performance is not a guide to considerations of the market situation and the time horizon. Key future performance. Estimates of future performance are based on assumptions of forecasts, price targets and projections in research cited or assumptions that may not be realized. When investing in individual shares, reproduced appear in the research material from the named sources. The the investor may lose all or part of the investments. date of publication appears from the research material cited or reproduced. Opinions and estimates may be updated in subsequent versions of the Conflicts of interest publication or report, provided that the relevant company/issuer is treated Nordea, affiliates or staff in Nordea, may perform services for, solicit anew in such later versions of the publication or report. business from, hold long or short positions in, or otherwise be interested in the investments (including derivatives) of any company mentioned in the Validity of the publication or report publication or report. All opinions and estimates in this publication or report are, regardless of source, given in good faith, and may only be valid as of the stated date of To limit possible conflicts of interest and counter the abuse of inside this publication or report and are subject to change without notice. knowledge, the analysts of Nordea Markets are subject to internal rules on sound ethical conduct, the management of inside information, handling of No individual investment or tax advice unpublished research material, contact with other units of Nordea and The publication or report is intended only to provide general and preliminary personal account dealing. The internal rules have been prepared in information to investors and shall not be construed as the basis for any accordance with applicable legislation and relevant industry standards. The investment decision. This publication or report has been prepared by Nordea object of the internal rules is for example to ensure that no analyst will Markets as general information for private use of investors to whom the abuse or cause others to abuse confidential information. It is the policy of publication or report has been distributed, but it is not intended as a Nordea Markets that no link exists between revenues from capital markets personal recommendation of particular financial instruments or strategies activities and individual analyst remuneration. Nordea and the branches are and thus it does not provide individually tailored investment advice, and members of national stockbrokers’ associations in each of the countries in does not take into account the individual investor’s particular financial which Nordea has head offices. Internal rules have been developed in situation, existing holdings or liabilities, investment knowledge and accordance with recommendations issued by the stockbrokers associations.
Recommended publications
  • How Secular Is the Current Economic Stagnation?
    How secular is the current economic stagnation? Maria Roubtsova ∗ September 30, 2016 Abstract From the burst of the dotcom bubble in 2000, until the global financial crisis that started in August 2007, the global economy was growing. During that phase, macroe- conomics went through an era of general optimism around the idea of having reached a great moderation, with high steady growth and low stable inflation. Central bankers thought they managed to dampen the economic cycles. This era came to an end fol- lowing the meltdown which started with the global financial crisis of 2007. And as among economic agents, macroeconomists’ general state of mind went from optimism to pessimism. Almost ten years since the beginning of the crisis, growth is not back to its pre-crisis trends. Therefore, macroeconomists are debating the notion of a secular stagnation. Is the economy on a long-term stagnation trend, if so, for what reasons, and how to address this situation? This paper offers a critical review of the debates among macroeconomists around this notion of secular stagnation, a concept which was invented by Alvin Hansen following the global economic crisis of the 1930s, and was brought back into the public debate largely by Lawrence Summers since the end of 2013. This literature review starts with a brief synthesis of the original debate about secular stagnation, launched by Hansen in 1938, and ended in the mid-1950s, since these debates inspired contemporary theorists. The second part highlights the main elements of neoclassical explanations for secular stagnation. The third part focuses on the Minskian idea of the end of a debt super-cycle.
    [Show full text]
  • Low Equilibrium Real Rates, Financial Crisis, and Secular Stagnation Lawrence H
    CHAPTER 2 Low Equilibrium Real Rates, Financial Crisis, and Secular Stagnation Lawrence H. Summers he past decade has been a tumultuous one for the US economy, characterized by the buildup of huge excesses in financial markets T during the 2001–2007 period; the Great Recession and its contain- ment; and, finally, a recovery that has been very slow by historical stan- dards and insufficient to bring the economy back even close to the levels of output that were anticipated before the recession. The containment of the Recession was no easy feat, since economic conditions initially looked worse than in the early months of the Great Depression. However, the economy is still struggling five years later, and the correct diagnosis of its ailment is requisite for applying the appropriate treatment going forward. Hence, in this paper I will therefore discuss what I label the new sec- ular stagnation hypothesis. This hypothesis asserts that the economy as currently structured is not capable of achieving satisfactory growth and stable financial conditions simultaneously. The zero lower bound on base nominal interest rates, in conjunction with low inflation, makes the achievement of sufficient demand to bring about full employment prob- lematic. If and when ways can be found to generate sufficient demand, they will likely be associated with unsustainable financial conditions. Secular stagnation was first suggested by Alvin Hansen in the late 1930s,1 but did not prove relevant given the rise in demand due to World War II and the massive pent-up demand for consumer and investment goods after the war. The difficulty that the US economy has had for many years in simultaneously achieving full employment, strong growth, and I am indebted to Simon Hilpert for extensive and excellent assistance in turn- ing my conference presentation into the current paper.
    [Show full text]
  • From Long-Term Growth to Secular Stagnation. a Theoretical Comparison Between Régulation Theory, Marxist Approaches and Present Mainstream Interpretations
    FROM LONG-TERM GROWTH TO SECULAR STAGNATION. A THEORETICAL COMPARISON BETWEEN RÉGULATION THEORY, MARXIST APPROACHES AND PRESENT MAINSTREAM INTERPRETATIONS Giovanni Scarano ISSN 2279-6916 Working papers (Dipartimento di Economia Università degli studi Roma Tre) (online) Working Paper n° 241, 2018 I Working Papers del Dipartimento di Economia svolgono la funzione di divulgare tempestivamente, in forma definitiva o provvisoria, i risultati di ricerche scientifiche originali. La loro pubblicazione è soggetta all'approvazione del Comitato Scientifico. Per ciascuna pubblicazione vengono soddisfatti gli obblighi previsti dall'art. l del D.L.L. 31.8.1945, n. 660 e successive modifiche. Copie della presente pubblicazione possono essere richieste alla Redazione. esemplare fuori commercio ai sensi della legge 14 aprile 2004 n.106 REDAZIONE: Dipartimento di Economia Università degli Studi Roma Tre Via Silvio D'Amico, 77 - 00145 Roma Tel. 0039-06-57335655 fax 0039-06-57335771 E-mail: [email protected] http://dipeco.uniroma3.it FROM LONG-TERM GROWTH TO SECULAR STAGNATION. A THEORETICAL COMPARISON BETWEEN RÉGULATION THEORY, MARXIST APPROACHES AND PRESENT MAINSTREAM INTERPRETATIONS Giovanni Scarano Comitato Scientifico: Fabrizio De Filippis Francesco Giuli Anna Giunta Paolo Lazzara Loretta Mastroeni Silvia Terzi FROM LONG-TERM GROWTH TO SECULAR STAGNATION. A THEORETICAL COMPARISON BETWEEN RÉGULATION THEORY, MARXIST APPROACHES AND PRESENT MAINSTREAM INTERPRETATIONS Giovanni Scarano* Roma Tre University Department of Economics [email protected] Abstract Since 2013 various eminent mainstream economists have proposed reviving the doctrine of “secular stagnation”. According to these authors, the only explanation for this new trend could be a negative Wicksellian natural rate of interest, produced by an excess of saving over investment at any positive interest rate.
    [Show full text]
  • On Falling Neutral Real Rates, Fiscal Policy, and the Risk of Secular Stagnation
    BPEA Conference Drafts, March 7–8, 2019 On Falling Neutral Real Rates, Fiscal Policy, and the Risk of Secular Stagnation Łukasz Rachel, LSE and Bank of England Lawrence H. Summers, Harvard University Conflict of Interest Disclosure: Lukasz Rachel is a senior economist at the Bank of England and a PhD candidate at the London School of Economics. Lawrence Summers is the Charles W. Eliot Professor and President Emeritus at Harvard University. Beyond these affiliations, the authors did not receive financial support from any firm or person for this paper or from any firm or person with a financial or political interest in this paper. They are currently not officers, directors, or board members of any organization with an interest in this paper. No outside party had the right to review this paper before circulation. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of England, the London School of Economics, or Harvard University. On falling neutral real rates, fiscal policy, and the risk of secular stagnation∗ Łukasz Rachel Lawrence H. Summers LSE and Bank of England Harvard March 4, 2019 Abstract This paper demonstrates that neutral real interest rates would have declined by far more than what has been observed in the industrial world and would in all likelihood be significantly negative but for offsetting fiscal policies over the last generation. We start by arguing that neutral real interest rates are best estimated for the block of all industrial economies given capital mobility between them and relatively limited fluctuations in their collective current account.
    [Show full text]
  • Secular Stagnation and Monetary Policy
    Secular Stagnation and Monetary Policy Lawrence H. Summers This article is based on the author’s Homer Jones Memorial Lecture delivered at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, April 6, 2016. (JEL E52, E61, H50) Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Second Quarter 2016, 98(2), pp. 93-110. http://dx.doi.org/10.20955/r.2016.93-110 have been engaged in thinking, writing, provoking, and analyzing around the issue of secular stagnation: the issue of protracted sluggish growth, why it seems to be our I experience, and what should be done about it.1 This paper summarizes my current thinking on those topics and reflects on the important limits monetary policy experiences in dealing with secular stagnation. The recent sluggish performance of the economy, both in the United States and particu- larly abroad, motivates this discussion of secular stagnation. Figure 1 depicts successive esti- mates of potential GDP and the behavior of actual GDP for the United States. While the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) finds a much lower output gap than it did in 2009, that is wholly the result of downward revisions to its estimate of potential GDP (see Figure 2). Relative to what the CBO thought potential was in 2007, the gap has never been greater. The situation is more negative in Europe, shown in Figure 3, where actual GDP has performed worst and the magnitude of the downward revision has been substantially greater. The contrast between what happened after the fall of 2008 and what happened after the fall of 1929 was a notable macro-economic achievement.
    [Show full text]
  • Negative Natural Interest Rates and Secular Stagnation: Much Ado About Nothing? a Note * Leon Podkaminer [The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies]
    real-world economics review, issue no. 90 subscribe for free Negative natural interest rates and secular stagnation: much ado about nothing? A note * Leon Podkaminer [The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies] Copyright: Leon Podkaminer 2019 You may post comments on this paper at https://rwer.wordpress.com/comments-on-rwer-issue-no-90/ Abstract This note is critical of the concept of a natural interest rate and doubts the relevance of claims about the “natural” interest rates becoming negative recently. JEL Codes E13, E31 Keywords natural interest rates, secular stagnation, zero lower bound, DSGE “There is a certain rate of interest on loans which is neutral in respect to commodity prices, and tends neither to raise nor to lower them. This is necessarily the same as the rate of interest which would be determined by supply and demand if no use were made of money and all lending were effected in the form of real capital goods…” (Knut Wicksell, 1936 [1898], p. 102. Secular stagnation and the negative natural rates of interest Like other key variables of mainstream macroeconomics (potential output and output gap) the “natural” (or “neutral”) interest rate is unobservable – and thus not subject to measurement.1 (Actually, the key mainstream “unobservable variables” are intimately related to one another.) Despite its ghostly appearance the natural interest rate (commonly denoted as r*) plays quite a prominent role in the mainstream monetary theories – and, apparently, also for the practice of monetary policy making. The size of r* is often claimed to be an essential benchmark for monetary policy – and the research departments at central banks busy themselves with attempts at “guesstimating” its numerical values.
    [Show full text]
  • Hyman Minsky Meets Secular Stagnation
    Hyman Minsky Meets Secular Stagnation Steven M. Fazzari* February 23, 2020 *Departments of Economics and Sociology, Washington University in St. Louis. This chapter has been informed by many years of lectures at the Hyman Minsky summer workshop sponsored by the Levy Economics Institute at Bard College. Comments from the participants at these workshops are gratefully acknowledged. In the aftermath of the 2007-2009 Great Recession and global financial crisis, the U.S. recovery has been weak. Indeed, more than a decade after the trough of the recession one might question the extent to which there has been any “recovery” at all. While real GDP has grown and the labor market has certainly improved, output in 2019 has not returned to anything close to its pre-crisis trend and there is no indication whatsoever that this gap will be closed in the years to come.1 This outcome has been labeled “secular stagnation,” most prominently by Lawrence Summers (2014). Although Hyman Minsky’s contributions to macroeconomics are wide- ranging, he is best known for his theory of financial instability, explaining the cyclical nature of capitalism. This chapter argues that Minsky’s insights also help explain recent U.S. secular stagnation when coupled with the dramatic rise of income inequality. In brief summary form, the argument is as follows. A major reason for stagnation is that high-income households recycle a substantially smaller share of their pre-tax income back into spending. Therefore, as inequality rises and most of the growth of income goes to the top slivers of the income distribution demand growth stagnates, other things equal.
    [Show full text]
  • US Economic Growth Is Over: the Short Run Meets the Long Run
    US Economic Growth is Over: The Short Run Meets the Long Run Robert Gordon Stanley G. Harris Professor in the Social Sciences, Northwestern University; NBER Distinguishing Between Secular No single image captures the present concern about secular stagnation and slowing Stagnation and Slow Long-term long-term economic growth better than The Growth Economist cover of July 19, 2014, showing a frustrated jockey dressed in the colors of the set of lively debates about future U.S. econom- American flag frantically trying to get some ic growth has engaged me as the lonely pro- movement from the gigantic but sluggish turtle Aponent of pessimism about the future against that he is riding. U.S. real GDP growth has grown three very talented proponents of what I have called at a turtle-like pace of only 2.1 percent per year in “techno-optimism.” In their best-selling book The the last four years, despite a rapid decline in the Second Machine Age (2013), Erik Brynjolfsson and unemployment rate from 10 to 6 percent. Almost all of that improvement in the unemployment rate Andrew McAfee have argued that the U.S. is at a has been offset by an unprecedented decline in “point of inflection” toward faster technological labor force participation, so that the ratio of change. In two public debates with them, I have lost employment to the working-age population has overwhelmingly; the techno-optimists have cap- hardly improved at all since the trough of the tured a consensus view that the future will be better recession, and as a result 10 million jobs have than the past, and that hope is understandable be- been lost forever.2 cause economic conditions in the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • A Model of Secular Stagnation
    IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES A Model of Secular Stagnation Gauti B. Eggertsson and Neil R. Mehrotra Discussion Paper No. 2015-E-9 INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF JAPAN 2-1-1 NIHONBASHI-HONGOKUCHO CHUO-KU, TOKYO 103-8660 JAPAN You can download this and other papers at the IMES Web site: http://www.imes.boj.or.jp Do not reprint or reproduce without permission. NOTE: IMES Discussion Paper Series is circulated in order to stimulate discussion and comments. Views expressed in Discussion Paper Series are those of authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of Japan or the Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies. IMES Discussion Paper Series 2015-E-9 July 2015 A Model of Secular Stagnation Gauti B. Eggertsson* and Neil R. Mehrotra** Abstract We propose an overlapping generations New Keynesian model in which a permanent (or very persistent) slump is possible without any self-correcting force to full employment. The trigger for the slump is a deleveraging shock, which creates an oversupply of savings. Other forces that work in the same direction and can both create or exacerbate the problem include a drop in population growth, an increase in income inequality, and a fall in the relative price of investment. Our model sheds light on the long persistence of the Japanese crisis, the Great Depression, and the slow recovery out of the Great Recession. It also highlights several implications for policy. Keywords: Secular stagnation; monetary policy; zero lower bound JEL classification: E31, E32, E52 *Brown University (E-mail: [email protected]) **Brown University (E-mail: [email protected]) We would like to thank Olivier Blanchard, John Cochrane, Benjamin Keen, and Paolo Pesenti for helpful discussions and seminar participants at the Bank of England, Boston University, Brown University, European Central Bank, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Dallas, London School of Economics, LUISS Guido Carli, NBER Summer Institute MEFM and EFG meetings for comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Secular Stagnation Or Technological Lull? Valerie A. Ramey University Of
    Secular Stagnation or Technological Lull? Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and NBER May 2020 Forthcoming Journal of Policy Modeling Abstract The slow recovery of the economy from the Great Recession and the lingering low real interest rates have led to fears of “secular stagnation” and calls for government aggregate demand stimulus to lift the growth rate of the economy. I present evidence that the current state of the U.S. economy does not satisfy the conditions for secular stagnation, as originally defined by Alvin Hansen (1939). Instead, the U.S. is experiencing a period of low productivity growth. I suggest that long intervals of sluggish productivity growth may be natural in an economy whose growth is driven by technological revolutions that are large, infrequent, and randomly‐timed. If this is the case, then the best description of the recent experience of the U.S. economy is a technological lull. In this situation, traditional government aggregate demand stimulus policies are not the appropriate response. Instead policies that can increase the rate of innovation and its diffusion may be more appropriate. Keywords: secular stagnation, productivity growth, technology, innovation Presented at the January 3, 2020 AEA session “The United States Economy: Growth, Stagnation or New Financial Crisis?” in San Diego. I wish to thank Dominick Salvatore for organizing the panel. This material is based on research supported by National Science Foundation Grant No. 1658796. 1. Introduction The expansion of the U.S. economy that began in June 2009 is likely to be the longest expansion on record. Nevertheless, lower average GDP growth and the prolonged era of very low interest rates have led observers such as Larry Summers (2014, 2016) to argue that the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Has Consumption Remained Moderate After the Great Recession?!
    Why Has Consumption Remained Moderate after the Great Recession? Luigi Pistaferriy October 2016 Abstract Aggregate data show that after the end of the Great Recession consumption growth has been slower than what income growth and net worth appreciation would have suggested. Why? I discuss the role of various explanations that have surfaced in the literature, such as wealth e¤ects, …nancial frictions, debt overhang, etc. I conclude that while …nancial frictions, directly or indirectly, were the trigger for the sharp decline and subsequent weakness of consumption in the aftermath of the crisis, in recent times the slow recovery is better explained by low consumer con…dence and heightened uncertainty. This paper was originally prepared for the conference: “The Elusive "Great" Recovery: Causes and Implications for Future Business Cycle Dynamics”. Thanks to Mike Shi for excellent research assistance, Adrien Auclert and Tullio Jappelli for detailed comments, and Karen Dynan and Atif Mian for discussion. All errors are mine. yDepartment of Economics, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305 (email: [email protected]), NBER, SIEPR, and CEPR. 1 Introduction The performance of the US economy in the post-Great Recession period has been, in the words of Bob Hall (2016), "abysmal". After almost seven years from the o¢ cial end of the downturn, real GDP is still below its normal growth path. Personal consumer expenditure, the largest component of GDP (67% when the recession started), has followed a similar weak growth path. After declining precipitously at the onset of the Great Recession, it has grown only moderately during the subsequent recovery, despite rebounds in disposable income and net worth, improved employment prospects, and a decline in overall debt levels (deleveraging).
    [Show full text]
  • Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes and Cures Rates and Extraordinary Central Bank Manoeuvres
    e Six years after the Global Crisis, the recovery is still anaemic despite years of near-zero interest Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes and Cures rates and extraordinary central bank manoeuvres. Is ‘secular stagnation’ to blame? Secular Stagnation: This eBook gathers the thinking of leading economists including Larry Summers, Paul Krugman, Robert Gordon, Olivier Blanchard, Richard Koo, Barry Eichengreen, Ricardo Caballero, Ed Facts, Causes and Cures Glaeser and a dozen others. A fairly strong consensus emerged on four points. • Secular stagnation (SecStag) means that negative real interest rates are needed to equate saving and investment at full-employment output levels. • The key worry is that SecStag will make it hard to achieve full employment with low Edited by Coen Teulings and inflation and financial stability using macroeconomic policy as it is currently structured Richard Baldwin and operated. • It is too early to tell whether secular stagnation is to blame, but uncertainty is not an excuse for inaction. Policymakers should start thinking about solutions; if secular stagnation sets in, today’s toolkit will be inadequate. • Europe has more to fear from the possibility of secular stagnation than the US, given its slower overall growth and its lack of pro-growth reforms and more constrained policy framework. The authors point to two classes of solutions: ‘Prevention’ (raising long-run growth potentials) and ‘symptomatic treatment’ (raising the inflation target to alleviate the zero lower bound problem, and using fiscal policy to
    [Show full text]