Socio-Economic Influences of Population Density∗

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Socio-Economic Influences of Population Density∗ Jul. 2009, Volume 8, No.7 (Serial No.73) Chinese Business Review, ISSN 1537-1506, USA Socio-economic influences of population density∗ Yuri A. Yegorov (Department of Industry, Energy and Environment, University of Vienna, Vienna A-1210, Austria) Abstract: While population density represents an important socio-economic parameter, its role is rarely studied in the economic literature (contrary to natural sciences). Population density plays an important role in harvesting societies, i.e. those that depend on agriculture and natural resources. With the development of industry and services and emergence of urban areas, population density becomes less economically important unless we consider aspects related to pollution. There exists a phase transition between rural and urban area which makes population density less important in urban area contrary to rural. However, the economic influence of population density in harvesting societies is also not straight forward. Too high population density decreases the natural endowment per capita, but eases the development of infrastructure, leading to existence of an optimal population density for economic growth. It also influences the demand for a monopolistic product, where too little density can lead to non-survival of a monopoly. Emergence of ethnic communities is based on more cooperative behavior in the case of low cultural and physical distances. At the same time, higher probability of large projects (like infrastructure) leads to development of cooperative behavior in the society. Elaboration along these lines leads to the conclusion that population density positively correlates with individualistic (non-cooperative, non-altruistic) behavior, through less time spent in cooperative infrastructure projects and higher frequency of meetings between individuals that with some probability lead to non-cooperative games. Key words: population density; economic development; optimization; cooperation 1. Introduction Countries differ not only in purely economic parameters (like GDP per capita, capital investment, etc.) but also in geographical characteristics that also influence economics. The development of GIS in recent years allows for measurement of not only aggregate macroeconomic characteristics of a country, but also of spatially distributed parameters. Population density and its spatial pattern is one of such characteristics. It plays an important role not only on economic but also on social aspects of life. First, potential influences of population density and associated heterogeneity will be outlined. Then, the corresponding economic models will be presented. Finally, the economic consequences will be analyzed and some country examples will be provided. 1.1 Discussions in literature Despite the fact that continuous spatial structures (and only such models can deal with population density) do not play major role in contemporary economic studies, such models were important in 1930-ies, starting from spatial oligopoly by Hotelling (1929) and models of monopolistic competition in space by Chamberlin (1933). A ∗ The work of Yuri A. Yegorov on this paper was partly financed by Austrian National Bank through the Jubiläumfonds project (No. 12826). Yuri A. Yegorov, Ph.D., Department of Industry, Energy and Environment, University of Vienna; research fields: economics and business. 1 Socio-economic influences of population density good survey of such models was done by Beckmann and Thisse (1986). Although new economic geography (see works of Krugman) claims to describe spatial economies, in most of its models it reduces geographical space to only two points, making it impossible to discuss the role of population density. Even telecom coverage (and thus efficiency) depends on distribution of population in space. Covering metropolitan areas is low per capita investment, and average density of population plays here less important role than urban-rural split. Here Krugman may be right that population density is not so crucial, but there are many other socio-economic activities where the situation is opposite. This article will focus on them. Population density is important not only for production activities, but also for social behavior. Wirth (1938) suggests that an increase in population density puts stress on humans, causing increased levels of social disorder, like crimes. Ladd (1992) studies the effects of population density on local public spending. While most planners argue that population density is good due to economies of density in the production of certain services, she had found empirically J-shaped curve of public spending per capita. It is clear why at low population densities costs per capita are high and why they decline as population density grows. However, after reaching some threshold density (she found it to be 250 people per square mile) per capita costs of public safety start to grow again. Westlund (1999) studies the factors that influence interregional cooperation. While natural factors (geographical, physical) have slow influence on change, cost and technical-logistical factors can generate rapid change in inter-regional interactions. Monnesland and Westlund (1999) evaluate Interreg programs between Sweden and Norway. They focus on population density and distance as factors influencing potential for interaction between regions in space. The factor of population density plays a crucial role in the mechanism of urban-rural split. As it was shown in the paper (Yegorov, 2005a), farming activity is possible in homogeneous space. When industrial technology emerges, it requires some minimum number of workers to cover at least fixed costs, and thus it starts first in one location. When the location of a city is chosen, it will create such rental price of land in space that new agricultural location rent will emerge. Land will be more expensive closer to the city, and thus land lots will be of less size there. Why the markets will be located in cities? Because they represent points with maximal concentration of population, and total transport cost that society pays will be minimal if they are located there. Finally equilibrium will emerge, where net income per farmer is exactly equal to net income per worker, and everybody consumes equal proportion of agricultural and industrial good. Population density can also influence the optimal country size. In the paper (Yegorov, 2005b), country is modelled as uniformly populated square with side a, and population density ρ. The revenue is assumed to be proportional to the territory: TR=αa². The total cost of running a country has several components: communication costs-the number of citizens multiplied to the average distance to the centre and unit transport cost; costs of protecting borders, which is proportional to the length of borderline, and cost of having government. The country’s objective depends on political regime. In the case of democracy the surplus per capita is maximized, while in the case of dictatorship—overall surplus. In both cases population density influences an optimal spatial size of a country. 1.2 Paper structure This is a theoretical paper using some abstract set up that can have some difference with reality. For example, there are no countries with uniform spread of population over space, but such an abstraction may be better than spaceless model. Moreover, it does not use any fixed spatial grid (typical for all CGE models) but compare structures that can exist on different grids if we deform the space. Thus, we can compare countries that are 2 Socio-economic influences of population density identical in all other economic parameters except for population density. Here are several fields where the role of population density seems to play an important role. 1.2.1 Low versus high population density Suppose that population density is uniform. We know that this is never the case (it is enough to contrast urban and rural areas), but it is convenient to start comparison from simple cases. If natural resources are spread evenly over space, then lower population density implies higher per capita endowment in natural resources. But to do harvesting, it is important to build network of infrastructure (to bring them to production centre, or to export). Typically transport cost per unit of resources to reach world market or a plant using them as input is higher when population density is lower. What factor would prevail? The paper shows that there exists some optimal population density, when production per capita is maximized and economic growth can be the highest (Yegorov, 2005a). 1.2.2 Spatial heterogeneity I: Rural-urban split Every spatial structure has some natural resources on it and also some centres (cities, industrial complexes), where some concentration takes place due to some scale economies. In this environment we have few more parameters: (a) average city size, (b) average distance between cities, (c) share of rural population (implying rural population density; relevant for agriculture). Rural-urban split has been considered in Yegorov (2005a). A line-land was considered there: equidistant cities on a line with heterogeneous population density between cities. There was a balance between production of industrial and agricultural good, and farmers in different locations were indifferent to reach the markets located in the closest city (like in von Thünen model). 1.2.3 Spatial heterogeneity II: Developed versus undeveloped land Here we focus on countries with large size having a fraction that is little developed.
Recommended publications
  • CEP Discussion Paper No 1561 July 2018 Quantifying Wide Economic
    ISSN 2042-2695 CEP Discussion Paper No 1561 July 2018 Quantifying Wide Economic Impacts of Agglomeration for Transport Appraisal: Existing Evidence and Future Directions Daniel J. Graham Stephen Gibbons Abstract This paper is concerned with the Wider Economic Impacts (WEIs) of transport improvements that arise via scale economies of agglomeration. It reviews the background theory and empirical evidence on agglomeration, explains the link between transport and agglomeration, and describes a three step procedure to appraise agglomeration impacts for transport schemes within Cost Benefit Analysis (CBA). The paper concludes with a set of recommendations for future empirical work on agglomeration and transport appraisal. Key words: agglomeration, transport, cost benefit analysis JEL: R1; R47 This paper was produced as part of the Centre’s Urban and Spatial Programme. The Centre for Economic Performance is financed by the Economic and Social Research Council. Daniel J. Graham, Imperial College, London. Stephen Gibbons, London School of Economics and Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics. Published by Centre for Economic Performance London School of Economics and Political Science Houghton Street London WC2A 2AE All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means without the prior permission in writing of the publisher nor be issued to the public or circulated in any form other than that in which it is published. Requests for permission to reproduce any article or part of the Working Paper should be sent to the editor at the above address. D.J Graham and S.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization and Infectious Diseases: a Review of the Linkages
    TDR/STR/SEB/ST/04.2 SPECIAL TOPICS NO.3 Globalization and infectious diseases: A review of the linkages Social, Economic and Behavioural (SEB) Research UNICEF/UNDP/World Bank/WHO Special Programme for Research & Training in Tropical Diseases (TDR) The "Special Topics in Social, Economic and Behavioural (SEB) Research" series are peer-reviewed publications commissioned by the TDR Steering Committee for Social, Economic and Behavioural Research. For further information please contact: Dr Johannes Sommerfeld Manager Steering Committee for Social, Economic and Behavioural Research (SEB) UNDP/World Bank/WHO Special Programme for Research and Training in Tropical Diseases (TDR) World Health Organization 20, Avenue Appia CH-1211 Geneva 27 Switzerland E-mail: [email protected] TDR/STR/SEB/ST/04.2 Globalization and infectious diseases: A review of the linkages Lance Saker,1 MSc MRCP Kelley Lee,1 MPA, MA, D.Phil. Barbara Cannito,1 MSc Anna Gilmore,2 MBBS, DTM&H, MSc, MFPHM Diarmid Campbell-Lendrum,1 D.Phil. 1 Centre on Global Change and Health London School of Hygiene & Tropical Medicine Keppel Street, London WC1E 7HT, UK 2 European Centre on Health of Societies in Transition (ECOHOST) London School of Hygiene & Tropical Medicine Keppel Street, London WC1E 7HT, UK TDR/STR/SEB/ST/04.2 Copyright © World Health Organization on behalf of the Special Programme for Research and Training in Tropical Diseases 2004 All rights reserved. The use of content from this health information product for all non-commercial education, training and information purposes is encouraged, including translation, quotation and reproduction, in any medium, but the content must not be changed and full acknowledgement of the source must be clearly stated.
    [Show full text]
  • Litter Pollution in Densely Versus Sparsely Populated Areas: Dog River Watershed
    LITTER POLLUTION IN DENSELY VERSUS SPARSELY POPULATED AREAS: DOG RIVER WATERSHED Gabrielle M. Hudson, Department of Earth Sciences, University of South Alabama, Mobile, AL 36688. E-mail: [email protected]. It is commonly known that when humans populate an area that area is usually subject to some environmental degradation. One of the more common aspects of environmental degradation is litter. This type of degradation is no stranger to the Dog River watershed. For years residents have seen the rivers in this watershed covered in trash, specifically after rain events. The vast majority of the trash is a result of litter from roadsides being carried into the river via drainage pipes. This paper is a comparative study of litter in areas of varying population densities in the Dog River watershed. It seeks to distinguish between the amount of litter found in densely populated areas and sparsely populated areas, and to find out if there is a correlation between population density and litter. I utilize GIS to map population density of the Dog River watershed, and analyze and compare the amounts of litter in areas of sparse and dense populations. The results show that there is no correlation between population density and litter. It also shows that there is no difference in the amounts of litter found in densely and sparsely populated areas. Keyword: litter, population density, watershed Introduction Pollution has long been an issue in the Dog River watershed, in particular litter pollution. The extent of the pollution has not gone unnoticed. There are groups of people and organizations who have taken increased interest in the Dog River watershed with intentions of reducing pollution, including Dog River Clearwater Revival and its numerous volunteers.
    [Show full text]
  • Evidence from Ghanaian Railways∗
    Colonial Investments and Long-Term Development in Africa: Evidence from Ghanaian Railways∗ Remi JEDWABa Alexander MORADIb a Department of Economics, George Washington University, and STICERD, London School of Economics b Department of Economics, University of Sussex This Version: October 14th, 2012 Abstract: What is the impact of colonial public investments on long-term development? We investigate this issue by looking at the impact of railway construction on economic develop- ment in Ghana. Two railway lines were built by the British to link the coast to mining areas and the hinterland city of Kumasi. Using panel data at a fine spatial level over one century (11x11 km grid cells in 1891-2000), we find a strong effect of rail connectivity on the pro- duction of cocoa, the country’s main export commodity, and development, which we proxy by population and urban growth. First, we exploit various strategies to ensure our effects are causal: we show that pre-railway transport costs were prohibitively high, we provide ev- idence that line placement was exogenous, we find no effect for a set of placebo lines, and results are robust to instrumentation and nearest neighbor matching. Second, transportation infrastructure investments had large welfare effects for Ghanaians during the colonial period. Colonization meant both extraction and development in this context. Third, railway con- struction had a persistent impact: railway cells are more developed today despite a complete displacement of rail by other means of transport. We investigate the various channels of path dependence, including demographic growth, industrialization or infrastructure investments. Keywords: Colonialism; Africa; Transportation Infrastructure; Trade JEL classification: F54; O55; O18; R4; F1 ∗Remi Jedwab, George Washington University and STICERD, London School of Economics (e-mail: [email protected]).
    [Show full text]
  • The Empirics of New Economic Geography ∗
    The Empirics of New Economic Geography ∗ Stephen J Redding LSE, Yale School of Management and CEPR y February 28, 2009 Abstract Although a rich and extensive body of theoretical research on new economic geography has emerged, empirical research remains comparatively less well developed. This paper reviews the existing empirical literature on the predictions of new economic geography models for the distribution of income and production across space. The discussion highlights connections with other research in regional and urban economics, identification issues, potential alternative explanations and possible areas for further research. Keywords: New economic geography, market access, industrial location, multiple equilibria JEL: F12, F14, O10 ∗This paper was produced as part of the Globalization Programme of the ESRC-funded Centre for Economic Performance at the London School of Economics. Financial support under the European Union Research Training grant MRTN-CT-2006-035873 is also gratefully acknowledged. I am grateful to a number of co-authors and colleagues for insight, discussion and comments, including in particular Tony Venables and Gilles Duranton, and also Guy Michaels, Henry Overman, Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, Peter Schott, Daniel Sturm and Nikolaus Wolf. I bear sole responsibility for the opinions expressed and any errors. yDepartment of Economics, London School of Economics, Houghton Street, London, WC2A 2AE, United Kingdom. Tel: + 44 20 7955 7483, Fax: + 44 20 7955 7595, Email: s:j:redding@lse:ac:uk. Web: http : ==econ:lse:ac:uk=staff=sredding=. 1 1 Introduction Over the last two decades, the uneven distribution of economic activity across space has received re- newed attention with the emergence of the “new economic geography” literature following Krugman (1991a).
    [Show full text]
  • The Empirics of Agglomeration Economies: the Link with Productivity Marli Fernandes Sílvia Santos Ana Fontoura Gouveia
    GEE Papers Número 67 fevereiro de 2017 The empirics of agglomeration economies: the link with productivity Marli Fernandes Sílvia Santos Ana Fontoura Gouveia 1 The empirics of agglomeration economies: the link with productivity Marli Fernandes, Sílvia Santos e Ana Fontoura Gouveia Abstract There is a large branch of literature providing empirical evidence on the positive effects of agglomeration economies on productivity. However, for policy makers it is important to understand the role of agglomeration economies at a more micro level, disentangling the effects across industries, firm-level characteristics and time. The present survey reviews this literature, outlining the econometric approaches and methodological challenges. In general, results show that the magnitude of agglomeration economies differ substantially across industries and point to the presence of non-linear effects, also depending on the industry and product life cycles. The channels through which these effects operate may also differ – resulting from specialization externalities (within industries in the same region) and/or urbanisation externalities (across industries in the same region). Overall, the evidence reviewed in this survey highlights the need for policy makers to follow tailor-made approaches and to complement existing evidence with national level studies, maximizing potential productivity gains. JEL codes: R1, O3, L6, D24 Keywords: Agglomeration economies, Specialization externalities, Urbanization externalities, Productivity. * Marli Fernandes – Nova SBE; Sílvia Santos – GPEARI – Ministry of Finance; Ana Fontoura Gouveia (corresponding author [email protected]) – GPEARI/Ministry of Finance and Nova SBE. The opinions expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily of the institutions. Any errors or omissions are the authors’ responsibility.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Economics of the Restructuring of World Railways, with a Focus on Russia
    ECONOMIC ANALYSIS GROUP DISCUSSION PAPER On the Economics of the Restructuring of World Railways, with a Focus on ∗ Russia Russell Pittman † January 2021 EAG 21-1 EAG Discussion Papers are the primary vehicle used to disseminate research from economists in the Economic Analysis Group (EAG) of the Antitrust Division. These papers are intended to inform interested individuals and institutions of EAG’s research program and to stimulate comment and criticism on economic issues related to antitrust policy and regulation. The Antitrust Division encourages independent research by its economists. The views expressed herein are entirely those of the author and are not purported to reflect those of the United States Department of Justice. Information on the EAG research program and discussion paper series may be obtained from Russell Pittman, Director of Economic Research, Economic Analysis Group, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice, LSB 9004, Washington, DC 20530, or by e-mail at [email protected]. Comments on specific papers may be addressed directly to the authors at the same mailing address or at their e-mail address. Recent EAG Discussion Paper and EAG Competition Advocacy Paper titles are available from the Social Science Research Network at www.ssrn.com. To obtain a complete list of titles or to request single copies of individual papers, please write to Regina Robinson at [email protected] or call (202) 307 - 5794. In addition, recent papers are now available on the Department of Justice website at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/eag/discussion-papers.html. ∗ The views expressed herein are entirely those of the authors and should not be purported to reflect those of the US Department of Justice.
    [Show full text]
  • “Study About the Economics of Postal Services”
    ECONOMICS OF POSTAL SERVICES: Ref. Ares(2015)5322260 - 24/11/2015 FINAL REPORT A Report to the European Commission DG-MARKT Prepared by NERA July 2004 London The views and opinions expressed in this study are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the European Commission Project Team John Dodgson José Maria Rodriguez Jan Peter van der Veer Stephen Gibson Juan Hernandez Barbara Veronese 15 Stratford Place, London W1C 1BE, UK Pº de la Castellana 13, 28046 Madrid, Spain Tel: (+44) 20 7659 8500 Tel: (+34) 91 521 0020 Fax: (+44) 20 7659 8501 Fax: (+34) 91 521 7876 Web: http://www.nera.com An MMC Company ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS NERA wishes to thank all the postal operators and other organisations which assisted in this study by completing our questionnaires or responding to specific questions. We alone are responsible for the contents of this report. TABLE OF CONTENTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY i 1. INTRODUCTION 1 1.1. This Report 1 1.2. Our Terms of Reference 1 1.3. Coverage of the Study 3 1.4. Structure of the Rest of this Report 3 2. OUR APPROACH 5 2.1. Methodology 5 2.2. Information Sources 7 3. THE CHANGING NATURE OF POSTAL PROVISION 9 3.1. Introduction 9 3.2. Services Provided by Universal Service Providers 10 3.3. The Traditional Postal Value Chain 11 3.4. Parcels and Express Services 26 3.5. Conclusions 30 4. DEVELOPING POSTAL BUSINESS STRATEGIES 33 4.1. Introduction 33 4.2. The External Context that Operators Face 34 4.3.
    [Show full text]
  • The Industrial Revolution in Services *
    The Industrial Revolution in Services * Chang-Tai Hsieh Esteban Rossi-Hansberg University of Chicago and NBER Princeton University and NBER May 12, 2021 Abstract The U.S. has experienced an industrial revolution in services. Firms in service in- dustries, those where output has to be supplied locally, increasingly operate in more markets. Employment, sales, and spending on fixed costs such as R&D and man- agerial employment have increased rapidly in these industries. These changes have favored top firms the most and have led to increasing national concentration in ser- vice industries. Top firms in service industries have grown entirely by expanding into new local markets that are predominantly small and mid-sized U.S. cities. Market concentration at the local level has decreased in all U.S. cities but by significantly more in cities that were initially small. These facts are consistent with the availability of a new menu of fixed-cost-intensive technologies in service sectors that enable adopters to produce at lower marginal costs in any markets. The entry of top service firms into new local markets has led to substantial unmeasured productivity growth, particularly in small markets. *We thank Adarsh Kumar, Feng Lin, Harry Li, and Jihoon Sung for extraordinary research assistance. We also thank Rodrigo Adao, Dan Adelman, Audre Bagnall, Jill Golder, Bob Hall, Pete Klenow, Hugo Hopenhayn, Danial Lashkari, Raghuram Rajan, Richard Rogerson, and Chad Syverson for helpful discussions. The data from the US Census has been reviewed by the U.S. Census Bureau to ensure no confidential information is disclosed. 2 HSIEH AND ROSSI-HANSBERG 1.
    [Show full text]
  • A Non-Linear Threshold Estimation of Density Effects
    sustainability Article Population Dynamics and Agglomeration Factors: A Non-Linear Threshold Estimation of Density Effects Mariateresa Ciommi 1, Gianluca Egidi 2, Rosanna Salvia 3 , Sirio Cividino 4, Kostas Rontos 5 and Luca Salvati 6,7,* 1 Department of Economic and Social Science, Polytechnic University of Marche, Piazza Martelli 8, I-60121 Ancona, Italy; [email protected] 2 Department of Agricultural and Forestry Sciences (DAFNE), Tuscia University, Via San Camillo de Lellis, I-01100 Viterbo, Italy; [email protected] 3 Department of Mathematics, Computer Science and Economics, University of Basilicata, Viale dell’Ateneo Lucano, I-85100 Potenza, Italy; [email protected] 4 Department of Agriculture, University of Udine, Via del Cotonificio 114, I-33100 Udine, Italy; [email protected] 5 Department of Sociology, School of Social Sciences, University of the Aegean, EL-81100 Mytilene, Greece; [email protected] 6 Department of Economics and Law, University of Macerata, Via Armaroli 43, I-62100 Macerata, Italy 7 Global Change Research Institute of the Czech Academy of Sciences, Lipová 9, CZ-37005 Ceskˇ é Budˇejovice, Czech Republic * Correspondence: [email protected] or [email protected] Received: 14 February 2020; Accepted: 11 March 2020; Published: 13 March 2020 Abstract: Although Southern Europe is relatively homogeneous in terms of settlement characteristics and urban dynamics, spatial heterogeneity in its population distribution is still high, and differences across regions outline specific demographic patterns that require in-depth investigation. In such contexts, density-dependent mechanisms of population growth are a key factor regulating socio-demographic dynamics at various spatial levels. Results of a spatio-temporal analysis of the distribution of the resident population in Greece contributes to identifying latent (density-dependent) processes of metropolitan growth over a sufficiently long time interval (1961-2011).
    [Show full text]
  • Global Typology of Urban Energy Use and Potentials for An
    Global typology of urban energy use and potentials for SPECIAL FEATURE an urbanization mitigation wedge Felix Creutziga,b,1, Giovanni Baiocchic, Robert Bierkandtd, Peter-Paul Pichlerd, and Karen C. Setoe aMercator Research Institute on Global Commons and Climate Change, 10829 Berlin, Germany; bTechnische Universtität Berlin, 10623 Berlin, Germany; cDepartment of Geographical Sciences, University of Maryland, College Park, MD 20742; dPotsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research, 14473 Potsdam, Germany; and eYale School of Forestry & Environmental Studies, New Haven, CT 06511 Edited by Sangwon Suh, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA, and accepted by the Editorial Board December 4, 2014 (received for review August 17, 2013) The aggregate potential for urban mitigation of global climate (9, 10), and also with GHG emissions from the residential change is insufficiently understood. Our analysis, using a dataset sector (11). The recent IPCC report identifies urban form of 274 cities representing all city sizes and regions worldwide, as a driver of urban emissions but does not provide guidance on demonstrates that economic activity, transport costs, geographic its relative importance vis-à-vis other factors. In comparative factors, and urban form explain 37% of urban direct energy use studies, cities are often sampled from similar geographies (5, 12, and 88% of urban transport energy use. If current trends in urban 13) or population sizes (8). In these studies, causality is difficult expansion continue, urban energy use will increase more than to establish, and self-selection (14) as well as topological prop- threefold, from 240 EJ in 2005 to 730 EJ in 2050. Our model shows erties and specific urban form characteristics (15) partially ex- that urban planning and transport policies can limit the future plain the relationship between urban population density and increase in urban energy use to 540 EJ in 2050 and contribute to transport energy consumption.
    [Show full text]
  • Handout: Ecological Footprints from Around the World
    Ecological Footprints From Around the World Handout Map Your Eco-Footprint lesson plan support material Green Star! Newsletter May/June 2006 Handout: Ecological Footprints From Around the World (Adapted from: “How big is your footprint,” Energy for a Sustainable Future — Education Project, www.esfep.org/ ) Ecological Footprints From Around the World: Where Do You Fit In? How Much Land Do You Need to Live? If you had to provide everything you use from your own land — how much land area would you need? This land would have to provide you with all of your food, water, energy and everything else that you use. The amount of land you would need to support your lifestyle is called your Ecological Footprint. The ecological footprint is one way of measuring the impact a person has on the environment. Is the World Big Enough for All of Our BIG Feet? The size of a person’s Ecological Footprint will depend on many factors. Do you grow your own food? Do you walk or drive? Do you use renewable or non-renewable energy sources? Everyone has an ecological footprint because we all need to use the earth’s resources to survive. But we must make sure we don’t take more resources than the earth can provide. Different people in the same country will have different sized ecological footprints. Different countries also have different ecological footprints. For example, a person with the average Canadian lifestyle has an ecological footprint of 8.56 hectares. A person living in Ethiopia, Africa, has an average ecological footprint of 0.67 hectares.
    [Show full text]