Traditionalists and Reformers in Eighteenth-Century Lombardy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Traditionalists and Reformers in Eighteenth-Century Lombardy Alternative Ideologies of Law: Traditionalists and Reformers in Eighteenth-Century Lombardy David B. Young* Cesare Beccaria's On Crimes and Punish- Dei delitti et delle pene (Des crimes et chia- ments, published in 1764, represented a new, timents) de Cesare Beccaria, publi6 en 1764, "bourgeois" outlook on criminal justice and pr~sente une vision nouvelle et bourgeoise de law in general. According to Beccaria, law la justice criminelle et du droit en g~n~ral. was impersonal, appealing to self-interest and Selon Beccaria, le droit est impersonnel. I1 establishing equality of opportunity through fait appel Al'int~r~t propre et 6tablit une 6ga- the direction of central government. In con- lit6 d'opportunit6 par la direction du gou- trast, one of Beccaria's most vocal critics, Fer- vernement central. Par contre, Ferdinando dinando Facchinei, expounded a more Facchinei, critique acharn6 de Beccaria, pro- traditional, feudal ideology. According to pose une ideologie fReodale plus tradition- Facchinei, law was divinely sanctioned, jus- nelle. Pour Facchinei, le droit est de sanction tifying the immobility among classes, and en- divine. lljustifie l'immobilisme des membres forced in a kindly but paternalistic manner. des classes. II est appliqu6 avec bont6 mais Modern scholars have dismissed Facchinei's d'une faqon paternaliste. Les intellectuels ideology, adopting Beccaria's as "virtually modernes ont rejet6 l'id6ologie de Facchinei self-evident". The author discusses both et adoptE, comme allant de soi, celle de Bee- these world views. He submits that, while the cara. I'auteur 6tudie ces deux visions du respective proponents of each view differed monde. II soutient que, bien que les deux in many respects, they were in fact speaking adversaires aient eu des vues divergentes sur within the same framework. They both ad- plusieurs sujets, ils 6voluaient dans un cadre dressed the landowning elite of eighteenth- de r6eference commun. Ils s'adressaient tous century Lombardy and tried to justify this deux A l'lite foncire de la Lombardie du group's power. Indeed, the two sides can be dix-huiti~me sicle et tentaient de justifier seen as representing "sub-ideologies" rather son pouvoir. On peut meme allerjusqu'A dire than diametrically opposed world views. que ces adversaires ne repr~sentaient que deux < sous-id6ologies)> plut6t que deux vi- sions du monde diam6tralement oppos~es. * * * *Associate: Husch. Eppenberger Donohue, Cornfeld & Jenkins. Kansas City. Missouri: J.D.. University of Missouri-Kansas City. 1988: Ph.D.. Columbia University. 1971: B. Phil.. Oxford University. 1970: M.A., Columbia University. 1971: B.A., Williams College. 1966. ©McGill Law Journal 1989 Revue de droit de McGill 1989] ALTERNATIVE IDEOLOGIES OF LAW Synopsis I. Introduction II. Background, Audience and Common Assumptions III. Society and Law IV. Economy, "Luxury" and Social Mobility V. Economies of Power: Education and Punishment V. Conclusion I. Introduction The publication of Cesare Beccaria's On Crimes and Punishments in 1764 has been taken as representing a drastic departure not merely in the manner of conceiving criminal justice, but of thinking about the nature and function of law itself.' Beccaria and his friends who gathered in the so-called "Academy of Fists" in Milan under the leadership of the indefatigable Pietro Verri2 have been seen as exponents of a "bourgeois" ideology, a way of seeing and evaluating the world quite different from the "feudal" ideology 'E Venturi, Utopia and Reform in the Enlightenment (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1971) at 106; see also, M. Weisser, Crime and Punishment in Early Modern Europe (Atlantic Highlands, N.J.: Humanities Press, 1979) at 133-36; and M. Foucault, Disciplineand Punish: The Birth of the Prison, trans. A. Sheridan (New York: Pantheon Books, 1977) at 11- 30, 74-101. 2The members of the Academy of Fists were young men drawn from the Milanese elite who were determined to bring Enlightenment ideas to the culture and government of Lombardy in particular and to Italy in general. See E Venturi, Settecento riformatore,vol. 1 (Turin: Giulio Einaudi, 1969) at 645-718. Pietro Verri was the moving spirit of the group. He wrote copiously on economic and administrative matters, vehemently rejecting traditional judicial governance in favor of active state intervention in economic improvement. See M.R. Manfra, Pietro Verri e i problemi economici del tempo suo (Milan: Albrighi, Segati, & C., 1932); Limoli, "Pietro Verri: A Lombard Reformer Under Enlightened Despotism" (1958) 18 J. Cent. Eur. Aft. 254. REVUE DE DROIT DE McGILL [Vol. 34 of an earlier day.3 To some modem scholars, the world view expounded by 4 the Academy of Fists seems virtually self-evident. In contrast, twentieth-century researchers have paid scant attention to Ferdinando Facchinei, Beccaria's earliest and in some respects most per- ceptive critic. A monk from Vallombroso in Venetian territory, Facchinei published his Notes and Observationson the Book Entitled, On Crimes and Punishmentsin 1765. 5 The members of the Academy of Fists angrily replied to his work, 6 which purported to indict Beccaria's book on no fewer than six charges of sedition and twenty-three of impiety. Beccaria himself affected an Olympian disdain for Facchinei, at least in print.7 Modern scholars, for their part, have either found Facchinei's writing turgid and his principles incomprehensible, or else they have dismissed him as an exponent of a vanishing world view.8 Prevailing interpretation certainly confirms that there has been a par- adigm change between Facchinei and twentieth-century readers. A clear sign of a drastic divergence in world view is incomprehension. 9 Cultural his- torians have noted that when two groups hold to vastly differing ideologies, 3 D. Humphries & D.E Greenberg, "The Dialectics of Crime Control" in D.E Greenberg, ed., Crime and Capitalism (Palo Alto, Cal.: Mayfield, 1981) at 223-24; see also P Jenkins, "Varieties of Enlightenment Criminology" (1984) 24 Brit. J. Criminology 112. 4P Gay, The Enlightenment: An Interpretation,vol. 1 (New York: Knopf, 1969) at 439-47; M. Maestro, CesareBeccaria and the OriginsofPenal Reform (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1973) at 3-45, 125-43. 5 E Facchinei, Note ed osservazioni sul libro intitolato Dei delitti e delle pene (Venice: no publisher indicated, 1765); see D. Young, "Property and Punishment in the Eighteenth Century: Beccaria and His Critics" (1986) 31 Am. J. Juris. 121 at 130-32. 6p Verri & A. Verri, "Risposta ad uno scritto che s'intitola Note ed osservazioni sul libro Dei delitti e delle pene" [1765], in C. Beccaria, Dei delitti e delle pene: Con una raccolta di lettere e documenti relativi alla nascita dell'operae alla suafortuna nell'Europadel Settecento, ed. by E Venturi (Turin: Giulio Einaudi, 1965) at 178 [hereinafter, Delitti (Venturi ed.)]. 7 C. Beccaria, On Crimes and Punishments, trans. D. Young (Indianapolis: Hacket, 1986) at 6: "I have given public testimony of my religion and of my obedience to my sovereign in my reply to [Facchinei's] Notes and Observations;it would be superfluous to answer other writings of this sort." 8Maestro, supra, note 4 at 35-38; Venturi, supra, note 1 at 102-05; see Torcellan, "Cesare Beccaria a Venezia" (1964) 76 Rivista storica italiana 720 at 721-23. 9T. Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, 2d ed. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1970) at 111-59. In the context of changing scientific paradigms, Kuhn points out that, as a new paradigm becomes entrenched, older assumptions and world views appear silly, affected, or altogether incoherent. Changes in conceiving the nature of the world alter what is accepted as a legitimate question or as a legitimate answer. Thus, incomprehension becomes inevitable. 1989] ALTERNATIVE IDEOLOGIES OF LAW world views, or ways of making sense of the world,' 0 neither side can un- derstand the other."l Often one side can make sense of the other only by forcing it onto the Procrustean bed of its own ideology. Thus, elite groups have "made sense" of folk beliefs and practices by treating them as heresy or witchcraft, thereby distorting the significance of these beliefs beyond the recognition of their adherents. 12 Such ideological misunderstandings can operate between periods as well as between groups. The basic assumption and values of the investigator are so remote from those of the investigated that incomprehension, distortion, or cavalier dismissal are inevitable.' 3 If there is a drastic ideological paradigm shift between modem aca- demicians and Facchinei, however, it does not follow that there was such a gulf between Facchinei and the Academy of Fists. Literary and art his- torians have emphasized that the ideology of a work is best found in the outlook of its intended audience rather than in the unique individuality of the writer, composer, painter, or sculptor.14 Generally, works addressed to the same audience share a common set of underlying attitudes and concerns, no matter how much the works may differ in specific proposals or in the 5 courses of conduct they recommend.' '0As used here, "ideology" refers to assumptions about facts and values that enable one to make sense of the world. Without such assumptions, it would be impossible to comprehend either the physical or the social universe. A person without an ideology would be, like Tristram Shandy's mother, incapable of understanding or evaluating anything. In this essay, "ideology" does not refer to false consciousness, for consciousness can be judged false only in light of the evaluator's own ideology. J.M. Balkin, "Ideology and Counter-Ideology from Lochner to Gar- cia" (1986) 54 U.M.K.C. L. Rev. 175 at 176-77. Anthropologists have long been concerned with ways of making sense of the world. As used here, a "way of making sense of the world" is synonymous with an "ideology". Historians have applied this anthropological concern, show- ing how social groups made different assumptions about how the world does work and how it should work, thus arriving at very different understandings.
Recommended publications
  • NO PAIN, NO GAIN the Understanding of Cruelty in Western Philosophy 1 and Some Reflections on Personhood
    FILOZOFIA POHĽAD ZA HRANICE ___________________________________________________________________________Roč. 65, 2010, č. 2 NO PAIN, NO GAIN The Understanding of Cruelty in Western Philosophy 1 and Some Reflections on Personhood GIORGIO BARUCHELLO, Faculty of Law and Social Sciences, University of Akureyri, Iceland BARUCHELLO, G.: No Pain, No Gain. The Understanding of Cruelty in Western Philosophy and Some Reflections on Personhood FILOZOFIA 65, 2010, No 2, p. 170 Almost daily, we read and hear of car bombings, violent riots and escalating criminal activities. Such actions are typically condemned as “cruel” and their “cruelty” is ta- ken as the most blameworthy trait, to which institutions are obliged, it is implied, to respond by analogously “cruel but necessary" measures. Almost daily, we read and hear of tragic cases of suicide, usually involving male citizens of various age, race, and class, whose farewell notes, if any, are regularly variations on an old, well- known adagio: “Goodbye cruel world.” Additionally, many grave cruelties are nei- ther reported nor even seen by the media: people are cheated, betrayed, belittled and affronted in many ways, which are as humiliating as they are ordinary. Yet, what is cruel? What meaning unites the plethora of phenomena that are reported “cruel”? How is it possible for cruelty to be so extreme and, at the same time, so common? This essay wishes to offer a survey of the main conceptions of cruelty in the history of Western thought, their distinctive constants of meaning being considered in view of a better understanding of cruelty’s role in shaping each person’s selfhood. Keywords: Cruelty – Evil – Liberalism (of fear) – Pain – Person(hood) Richard Rorty claimed famously that ‘liberals are the people who think that cruelty is the worst thing we do.’2 With this statement, he intended to set himself squarely amongst the pro- ponents of that ‘liberalism of fear’ which Judith Shklar had been establishing as a recognised liberal strand since the early 1980s.
    [Show full text]
  • Europe (In Theory)
    EUROPE (IN THEORY) ∫ 2007 Duke University Press All rights reserved Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper $ Designed by C. H. Westmoreland Typeset in Minion with Univers display by Keystone Typesetting, Inc. Library of Congress Cataloging-in- Publication Data appear on the last printed page of this book. There is a damaging and self-defeating assumption that theory is necessarily the elite language of the socially and culturally privileged. It is said that the place of the academic critic is inevitably within the Eurocentric archives of an imperialist or neo-colonial West. —HOMI K. BHABHA, The Location of Culture Contents Acknowledgments ix Introduction: A pigs Eye View of Europe 1 1 The Discovery of Europe: Some Critical Points 11 2 Montesquieu’s North and South: History as a Theory of Europe 52 3 Republics of Letters: What Is European Literature? 87 4 Mme de Staël to Hegel: The End of French Europe 134 5 Orientalism, Mediterranean Style: The Limits of History at the Margins of Europe 172 Notes 219 Works Cited 239 Index 267 Acknowledgments I want to thank for their suggestions, time, and support all the people who have heard, read, and commented on parts of this book: Albert Ascoli, David Bell, Joe Buttigieg, miriam cooke, Sergio Ferrarese, Ro- berto Ferrera, Mia Fuller, Edna Goldstaub, Margaret Greer, Michele Longino, Walter Mignolo, Marc Scachter, Helen Solterer, Barbara Spack- man, Philip Stewart, Carlotta Surini, Eric Zakim, and Robert Zimmer- man. Also invaluable has been the help o√ered by the Ethical Cosmopol- itanism group and the Franklin Humanities Seminar at Duke University; by the Program in Comparative Literature at Notre Dame; by the Khan Institute Colloquium at Smith College; by the Mediterranean Studies groups of both Duke and New York University; and by European studies and the Italian studies program at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.
    [Show full text]
  • Warwick.Ac.Uk/Lib-Publications the BRITISH LIBRARY BRITISH THESIS SERVICE
    A Thesis Submitted for the Degree of PhD at the University of Warwick Permanent WRAP URL: http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk/130193 Copyright and reuse: This thesis is made available online and is protected by original copyright. Please scroll down to view the document itself. Please refer to the repository record for this item for information to help you to cite it. Our policy information is available from the repository home page. For more information, please contact the WRAP Team at: [email protected] warwick.ac.uk/lib-publications THE BRITISH LIBRARY BRITISH THESIS SERVICE SHAKESPEARE'S RECEPTION IN 18TH CENTURY TITLE ITALY: THE CASE OF HAMLET AUTHOR Gabriella PETRONE FRESCO DEGREE PhD AWARDING Warwick University BODY DATE 1991 THESIS DX177597 NUMBER THIS THESIS HAS BEEN MICROFILMED EXACTLY AS RECEIVED The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the original thesis submitted for microfilming. Every effort has been made to ensure the highest quality of reproduction. Some pages may have indistinct print, especially if the original papers were poorly produced or if awarding body sent an inferior copy. If pages are missing, please contact the awarding body which granted the degree. Previously copyrighted materials (journals articles, published texts etc.) are not filmed. This copy of the thesis has been supplied on condition that anyone who consults it is understood to recognise that it's copyright rests with its author and that no information derived from it may be published without the author's prior written consent. Reproduction of this thesis, other than as permitted under the United Kingdom Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under specific agreement with the copyright holder, is prohibited.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction
    INTRODUCTION L’homme est la mesure des choses. […] La biographie est le fondement même de l’histoire. Franco Venturi, dans Dal trono al- l’al bero della libertà, I, Rome, 1991, p. 24. « L’homme est un animal capable de toutes les contradictions ». Cette phrase tirée du Petit commentaire d’un galant homme de mauvaise humeur1 résonne comme un défi lancé à l’optimisme progressiste du siècle des Lumières. C’est aussi une promesse de difficulté pour qui tente de saisir la logique d’une pensée au cœur de laquelle s’inscrit le relativisme. Né à Milan en 1741, Alessandro Verri avait fourbi ses premières armes dans Le Café. Dirigé par son frère Pietro, ce périodique nourri de culture française entendait soutenir et stimuler la politique réformatrice modérée mise en œu- vre en Lombardie par de hauts fonctionnaires de l’administration des Habsbourg, qui s’était attelée à un programme de « fondation ou refondation de l’État moderne »2. Il mourut à Rome, à soixante- quinze ans, romancier reconnu, apôtre de la Restauration monar- chique et fervent défenseur de l’Église. Ce raccourci biographique souligne l’apparente contradiction du parcours intellectuel d’Ales- sandro Verri : d’un côté, sa production milanaise développe une réflexion sur la modernisation des institutions juridiques, une cri- tique des académies littéraires et une satire des mœurs ; de l’autre, ses écrits romains témoignent d’une adhésion aux canons du clas- sicisme et aux thèses du conservatisme catholique. Cet intrigant paradoxe de l’esprit verrien possède quelque chose d’inattendu et de séduisant : le jeune homme des Lumières, devenu l’homme de la nuit et des sépulcres, un conservateur, si ce n’est un réactionnaire, aurait-il embrassé les deux âmes de son siècle, les Lumières et les anti-Lumières, l’encyclopédisme et la contre-révolution ? 1 Comentariolo di un galantuomo di mal umore, che ha ragione, sulla definizione : l’uomo è un animale ragionevole, in cui si vedrà di che si tratta, dans Il Caffè, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Before the Tragedy of the Commons: Early Modern Economic Considerations of the Public Use of Natural Resources
    409 Before the Tragedy of the Commons: Early Modern Economic Considerations of the Public Use of Natural Resources Nathaniel Wolloch* This article distinguishes between the precise legal and economic approach to the commons used by Hardin and many other modern commentators, and the broader post-Hardinian concept utilized in environmentally-oriented discussions and aiming to limit the use of the commons for the sake of preservation. Particularly in the latter case, it is claimed, any notion of the tragedy of the commons is distinctly a modern twentieth-century one, and was foreign to the early modern and even nineteenth-century outlooks. This was true of the early modern mercantilists, and also of classical political economists such as Adam Smith and even, surprisingly, Malthus, as well as of Jevons and his neoclassical discussion aimed at maximizing the long-term use of Britain’s coal reserves. One intellectual who did recognize the problematic possibility of leaving some tracts of land in their pristine condition to answer humanity’s need for a spiritual connection with nature was J. S. Mill, but even he regarded this as in essence almost a utopian ideal. The notion of the tragedy of the commons in its broader sense is therefore a distinctly modern one. Was there a concept of the tragedy of the commons before William Forster Lloyd in 1833, the precedent noted by Garrett Hardin himself?1 If we mean by this an exact concept akin to the modern recognition that population pressure leads to the irrevocable depletion and even destruction of irreplaceable natural resources, then the answer by and large is negative.
    [Show full text]
  • Johann Heinrich Gottlob Von Justi – the Life and Times of an Economist
    Johann Heinrich Gottlob von Justi (1717-1771): The Life and Times of an Economist Adventurer. Erik S. Reinert The Other Canon Foundation Table of Contents: Johann Heinrich Gottlob von Justi (1717-1771): The Life and Times of an Economist Adventurer. ................................................................................................................................. 1 Table of Contents: .................................................................................................................. 1 Introduction: ‘State Adventurers’ in English and German Economic History. ..................... 2 1. Justi’s Life. ......................................................................................................................... 4 2. Justi’s Influence in Denmark-Norway. ............................................................................ 11 3. Systematizing Justi’s Writings. ........................................................................................ 15 4. Justi as the Continuity of the Continental Renaissance Filiation of Economics. ............. 18 5. Economics at the Time of Justi: ‘Laissez-faire with the Nonsense Left out’................... 21 6. What Justi knew, but Adam Smith and David Ricardo later left out of Economics. ....... 25 7. Conclusion: Lost Relevance that Could be Regained. ..................................................... 31 Bibliography: ........................................................................................................................ 34 Introduction: ‘State
    [Show full text]
  • Cesare Beccaria: Utilitarianism, Contractualism and Rights
    Cesare Beccaria: Utilitarianism, Contractualism and Rights Mario Ricciardi and Filippo Santoni de Sio If you are visiting Milan, you will discover that ‘Cesare Beccaria’ is a Mila- nese household name. Walking through the streets downtown – in an area fa- miliar to shoppers – is Cesare Beccaria Square, and everyone has heard of the high school, or of the juvenile prison, named after this illustrious citizen of the past. While walking through the square, somebody might even direct your attention to a bronze, a replica of an original Nineteenth century marble by Giuseppe Grandi, which shows a man no longer young, stout; from his clothing and hairstyle he is easily recognisable as a nobleman of the Eighteenth century. He is absorbed in his thoughts – some books are at his feet – suggesting that he must be a scholar, maybe a philosopher. Those asking for further information about the thoughtful man on the pedestal will easily satisfy their curiosity. Even in these forgetful times anybody will tell them that he is Cesare Beccaria, the author of On Crimes and Punishments. This answer exemplifies the phenom- enon of a literary work that almost overwhelms the memory of its author. Ac- cording to Luigi Settembrini, On Crimes and Punishments is more than a book, it is “a fact of history, because it marks the time when torture and atrocities were abolished in criminal trials, and people began to wonder whether it is really necessary to wage death on those guilty of a crime” (1878: 67). For the Neapoli- tan scholar, who wrote in the Nineteenth century, roughly one hundred years after the publication of Beccaria’s book, the phenomenon we have mentioned above is already a fait accompli, inspiring ambiguous praise.
    [Show full text]
  • I 100 MEMBRI DEL PANTHEON DEL PENSIERO LIBERALE 1. Pericle 2
    I 100 MEMBRI DEL PANTHEON DEL PENSIERO LIBERALE 1. Pericle 2. Protagora 3. Platone 4. Aristotile 5. Marco Tullio Cicerone, Marcus Tullius Cicero 6. Marco Aurelio, Marcus Aurelius Antoninus Augustus 7. Thomas More 8. Francis Bacon, 1st Viscount St. Alban 9. Galileo Galilei 10. Tommaso Campanella, al secolo Giovan Domenico Campanella, pseudonimo Squilla 11. Antonio Serra 12. Huig Van Groot, italianizzato Ugo Grozio 13. Thomas Hobbe of Malmesbury 14. René Descartes, italianizzato Renato Cartesio 15. John Locke 16. Baruch Spinoza 17. Isaac Newton 18. Gottfried Wilhelm von Leibniz 19. Bernard de Mandeville 20. Richard Cantillon 21. Thomas Jefferson 22. Jeremy Bentham 23· Charle~-Louis de Secondat, Barone de La Brède e de Montesquieu, 24· David Hume 25· Jean-Jacques Rousseau 26. Denis Diderot 27. Antonio Genovesi 28. Jean Baptiste Le Rond d'Alembert 29· Adam Smith 30. Immanuel Kant 31. Ferdinando Galiani 32. Pietro Verri, dei Conti Verri 33· Edmund Burke 34· Cesare Bonesana-Beccaria, marchese di Gualdrasco e di Villareggio 35· John Jay 36. James Madison 37. Giovanni Maria Angioy 38. Gaetano Filangieri senior, dei Principi di Arianello 39· Alexander Hamilton 40. Thomas Robert Malthus 41. Friedrich Wilhelm Christian Carl Ferdinand Freiherr von Humboldt 42. Henri-Benjamin Constant de Rebecque 43. Georg Wilhelm Friedrich Hegel 44. David Ricardo 45. François Pierre Guillaume Guizot 46. Antonio Francesco Davide Ambrogio Rosmini Serbati 47. Thomas Babington Macaulay, 1st Baron Macaulay 48. Giuseppe Mazzini 49. Alexis Henri Charles de Clérei de Tocqueville 50. John Stuart Mill 51. Abraham Lincoln 52. William Ewart Gladstone 53. Camillo Benso, Conte di Cavour, di Cellarengo e di Isolabella 54.
    [Show full text]
  • Cesare Beccaria's Forgotten Influence on American Law John Bessler University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected]
    University of Baltimore Law ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 2017 The tI alian Enlightenment and the American Revolution: Cesare Beccaria's Forgotten Influence on American Law John Bessler University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.law.ubalt.edu/all_fac Part of the European Law Commons, Law and Politics Commons, and the Legal History Commons Recommended Citation John Bessler, The Italian Enlightenment and the American Revolution: Cesare Beccaria's Forgotten Influence on American Law, 37 Mitchell Hamline Law Journal of Public Policy and Practice 1 (2017). Available at: http://scholarworks.law.ubalt.edu/all_fac/972 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE ITALIAN ENLIGHTENMENT AND THE AMERICAN REVOLUTION: CESARE BECCARIA’S FORGOTTEN INFLUENCE ON AMERICAN LAW John D. Bessler‡ Abstract The influence of the Italian Enlightenment—the Illuminismo—on the American Revolution has long been neglected. While historians regularly acknowledge the influence of European thinkers such as William Blackstone, John Locke and Montesquieu, Cesare Beccaria’s contributions to the origins and development of American law have largely been forgotten by twenty-first century Americans. In fact, Beccaria’s book, Dei delitti e delle pene (1764), translated into English as On Crimes and Punishments (1767), significantly shaped the views of American revolutionaries and lawmakers.
    [Show full text]
  • The Market for Ideas and the Origins of Economic Growth in Eighteenth Century Europe
    The Market for Ideas and the Origins of Economic Growth in Eighteenth Century Europe Joel Mokyr Depts. of Economics and History Northwestern University Berglas School of Economics Tel Aviv University revised: Sept. 2006 I am grateful to Marianne Hinds and Michael Silver for loyal and competent research assistance. The comments of Avner Greif on an earlier version are much appreciated. 1 Two statements summarize much of the conventional wisdom about the historical experience of growth in the West: (1) Modern economic growth was ignited by the Industrial Revolution in the eighteenth century, and (2) the Industrial Revolution was, as everybody had always suspected, primarily about technology. Both statements must be qualified and nuanced: growth proper did not start until the second third of nineteenth century, and technology (to say nothing of “industry”) was not all there was to it. Yet when all is said and done, the place of technology in the economic miracle that occurred in Europe in the nineteenth century remains central. Technology, in its widest sense, is about new ideas and the growth of useful knowledge.1 Yet the economic impact of new technology, no matter how ingenious, can be realized only if the institutional environment is conducive and allows for the exploitation of inventions in an effective manner. In a simple economic model, it is hard to know whether conducive institutions “cause” technological change or the other way around. It is arguable that neither are truly exogenous, and instead both depend on the formation process of ideologies and beliefs that follows its own rules. Do ideas affect the outcomes of economic history? In a famous paragraph, John Maynard Keynes wrote that "the power of vested interests is vastly exaggerated compared with the gradual encroachment of ideas ...
    [Show full text]
  • Privilege and Property: the Political Foundations of Failed Class Formation in Eighteenth-Century Austrian Lombardy
    Privilege and Property: The Political Foundations of Failed Class Formation in Eighteenth-Century Austrian Lombardy DYLAN RILEY Department of Sociology, UCLA introduction The distinction between state and civil society is deeply rooted in both sociol- ogy and political theory (Barkey and Parikh 1991:525; Bobbio 1999:115; Habermas 1989:19). Even thinkers who argue that civil society and the state ‘interact’ often retain the basic conceptual opposition between the terms. Barkey and Parikh go so far as to characterize recent work on the state as “the state-society literature” (1991:524). Within sociology, however, there is less theoretical discussion of what connects state and society—political society— or the way that interests in civil society are constituted as claims on the state. But as the Sardinian Marxist Antonio Gramsci pointed out in his Prison Note- books, and the German sociologist Max Weber is his essay on class, status and parties, political society is reducible neither to interests in civil society, nor to the state (Gramsci 1971:138–40; Weber 1946:194; see also Poulantzas 1976: 95; Przeworski 1985:67; Stepan-Norris and Zeitlin 1991:1153; Wright 1978: 103, 222). Following in this Gramscian and Weberian tradition, the central theoretical point of this paper is to show how the structure of political society matters for group formation. More specifically, this paper addresses the question: what is the autonomous effect of political society on class formation, understood as the degree to which a group with a common relationship to the means of produc- tion organizes itself politically on the basis of that relationship? My main the- oretical argument is that a political society, in which actors make claims on the state in terms of privileges attached to residence, rather than property owner- ship, inhibits class formation even when other factors, such as the relations of production, state pressure, and culture, promote it.
    [Show full text]
  • Artes Liberales Lectures Artes Liberales Lectures Artes Liberales
    Artes Liberales Lectures No. 2 Ira Katznelson LIBERAL ARTS AND RISKS FOR FREEDOM In the Artes Liberales Lectures series we publish texts by eminent scholars who have visited the Collegium Artes Liberales and have given important lectures there. In this series thus far was published: • Donald W. Harward, Liberal Education and We, Wydział „Artes Liberales”, Warszawa 2018. The Artes Liberales Lectures series is a continuation of the OBTA Lectures series in which two books were published: • Thomas Molnar, Unity of Knowledge, OBTA, Warszawa 2004. • Roman Szporluk, Zachodni wymiar kształtowania się współczesnej Ukrainy, OBTA, DiG, Warszawa 2004. Ira Katznelson LIBERAL ARTS AND RISKS FOR FREEDOM Wydział „Artes Liberales” Warszawa 2018 Series Editor Jerzy Axer Text Adjustment Elżbieta Olechowska Composition & Typesetting Michał Kucharski Copyright 2018 by Wydział „Artes Liberales”, Uniwersytet Warszawski Copyright 2018 by Ira Katznelson All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, translated, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without prior written permission from the publisher. ISBN 978-83-63636-75-3 Wydział „Artes Liberales”, Uniwersytet Warszawski ul. Nowy Świat 69, Warszawa www.al.uw.edu.pl This book was published with the financial support of the “Artes Liberales Institute” Foundation (www.ial.org.pl). Printed in Poland in 150 copies. Paper: Olin Regular Natural White (120 & 250 gsm). Fonts: Adobe Garamod Pro & Museo Sans Cond. Liberal Arts and Risks for Freedom* It is wonderful to attend an event that in considering risks of free- dom is dedicated to understand liberal arts education as a form of democratic reason.
    [Show full text]