Request for Information ) Energy Cons

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Request for Information ) Energy Cons Before the U.S. Department of Energy Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy Re: Request for Information ) Energy Conservation Program: ) Energy Conservation Standards for ) EERE–2017–BT–STD–0003 Consumer Refrigerators, ) Refrigerator Freezers, and Freezers ) Comments of Consumer Federation of America Mark Cooper Mel Hall-Crawford Director of Research Director of Energy Programs FEBRUARY 13, 2020 TABLE OF CONTENTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 1. INTRODUCTION AND CONTEXT 1 A. Organizational Background of the Consumer Federation of America Relevant to the Above Captioned Proceeding B. A Pragmatic Consumer Approach to Setting Standards C. Outline 2. A LOOK AT THE REAL WORLD: THE TRACK RECORD OF APPLIANCE ENERGY 4 EFFICIENCY PERFORMANCE STANDARDS A. Simple Trends B. CFA’s Econometric Analysis of Appliances C. Prices D. The Benefits of Energy Efficiency Standard: Trump’s Two Trillion Dollar Mistake E. Low Income Consumers 1. Simple Mathematics of Income and Energy Consumption 2. Vulnerability to Market Imperfections 3. Exposure to Externalities 3. COMPREHENSIVE, MARKET FAILURE EXPLANATIONS OF THE EFFICIENCY GAP 17 A. The Efficiency Gap 1. The LBL Framework 2. The Resources for the Future Framework 3. The United Nations Industrial Development Organization B. Empirical Evidence of Market Barriers and Imperfections 1. Market Imperfections 2. Positive Externalities 3. Information and Behavior 4. Market Structure and Transaction Costs 4. STANDARDS AS A RESPONSE TO MARKET FAILURE 27 A. Rigorous Cost Benefit Analysis B. Standards as a Policy Response 1. Traditional Market Failures 2. Positive Externalities 3. Endemic Information and Behavior 4. Market Structure and Transaction Costs 5. COMMAND-BUT-NOT-CONTROL STANDARDS 31 A. Key Characteristics of Well-Crafted Performance Standards 1. Long-Term 2. Product Neutral 3. Technology-neutral 4. Responsive to industry needs 5. Responsive to consumer needs 6. Procompetitive B. Overestimation of Compliance Cost and the Tendency of Costs to Decline C. Non-Energy Benefits D. Macroeconomic Benefits of Standards 6. OTHER REASONS TO SUPPORT APPLIANCE EFFICIENCY STANDARDS 38 A. The Statutory Basis of “Command-But-Not-Control” Regulation 1. Executive Branch Guidance on Rulemaking B. Public Support for Appliance Efficiency Standards 1. Methodology 2. Attitudes toward Appliance Efficiency and Standards 3. Perception of Benefits and Support for Minimum Standards (2011) 4. Appliance Efficiency Standards Compared to Fuel Economy Standards EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Section 1: Introduction and Context These comments respond to the Request for Information regarding efficiency standards for refrigerators. They focus on the simple most important issue in the development of standards, market failures and imperfections, an issue that the DOE devoted little attention to and gave little guidance for in seeking comments. As a group that has represented consumer interests in virtually every regulatory proceeding in the past ten years involving efficiency standards for energy using durable, we take a unique approach that can be summarized in asking and answering four questions. Are there significant energy expenditures that appear to be wasteful in the sense that there are technologies available that cost less than the savings on energy use? Why is there an efficiency gap that imposes unnecessary costs on consumers? Is a standard an appropriate policy to address the market imperfections? How can the standard be best designed to achieve the goal of lowering consumer cost and protecting public health? To ass further support for these comments, we have attached and make direct reference to a report entitled Trump’s Two Trillion Dollar Mistake: The War on Energy Efficiency. This report has been filed with the all the agencies responsible for energy efficiency standards in response to earlier proceedings. Section 2 answers the first question: Are there significant energy expenditures that appear to be wasteful in the sense that there are technologies available that cost less than the savings on energy use? A Look at the Real World: The Track Record of Appliance Energy Efficiency Standards This section reviews empirical analysis of historical, contemporary and future benefits, for appliance standards in general and refrigerator standards in particular. Efficiency standards for refrigerators have led to dramatic reductions in energy consumption at very low cost, resulting in substantial consumer savings. Section 2 also places the standards in a broader context not only for consumers and commercial business, but also for the economy, public health and safety. This adds depth to our conclusion that standards are in the consumer and national interest. We estimate that over $1 trillion of potential consumer pocketbook savings are being placed at risk by Trump’s $2 Trillion Mistake; The “War on Energy Efficiency.” Section 2 concludes with a discussion of th impact of standards on low income households. The opponents of standards invariably and inevitably claim that standards harm low 1 income consumers disproportionately. We cite three broad categories of factors that suggest low income consumers benefit disproportionately from standards. First is the simple math of income and energy consumption dictates that energy savings will be larger and lower in cost for this group in absolute. Net savings will be larger relative to their income, Second, market imperfections, that are addressed by standards are more likely to impact low income consumers. Third, low income households are also more likely to benefit from standards that lower energy consumption and reduce negative externalities or increase the capture of positive externalities. Section 3 answers the second question: Why is there an efficiency gap that imposes unnecessary costs on consumers? Comprehensive, Market Failure Explanations of the Efficiency Gap This section identifies the market failure and imperfections that result in the underinvestment in energy efficiency, This section examines the conceptual and empirical bases for concluding that the explanation for the success of standards lies in the failure of industry to invest in and deliver consumer appliances that dramatically reduce energy consumptions. The “efficiency” gap debate is the starting point, with a discussion of the frameworks offered by several major energy research institutions. Next the section examines another source of discussion of market failures – by almost two dozen Nobel Laureates in Economics. They define five avenues of analytic criticism through simplistic, neoclassical economic models that have grown into schools of thought about market failure Finally, empirical studies from the energy efficiency and climate change literatures that support about 50 specific market imperfections across the schools are though are identified. The attached study identifies over 200 individual studies and gives specific quotes that define the market imperfection. Section 4 answers the third question: Is a standard an appropriate policy to address the market imperfections? These questions go hand-in-hand. Why will a standard work and how should it be designed. The section first identifies numerous imperfections that standards address. It starts from the observation that rigorous cost benefit analysis is the key to selecting policies to address market failures. The literature and the agencies identify well over a dozen market imperfections. Section 5 answers the fourth question: How can the standard be best designed to achieve the goal of lowering consumer cost and protecting public health? Command-But-Not-Control Standards 2 Our analysis identifies six key characteristics of performance standards that make them attractive as a policy: Long-Term, Product Neutral, Technology-neutral, Responsive to industry needs, Responsive to consumer needs, Procompetitive. Striking a balance between these characteristics is an important step toward writing an effective standard. Beyond the conceptual arguments in favor of performance standards, we see an extremely important outcome of these standards in the marketplace that lends strong support to our conclusion – the very clear tendency for the cost of compliance to decline and be much lower than regulators of industry anticipate. Section 6 The Legal Terrain of Standards for Energy Efficiency and Environmental Protection This section offers two other reasons that market failures and imperfections should be the focal point of the DOE analysis of standards. First, we show that the legal context in which the Agency makes these decisions demands it. Standards are not optional; they are mandatory under the statute. The Administrative Procedure Act requires that the decisions are made on the basis rigorous analysis applied to real world data. Both the law and the procedure strongly support our conclusions. Our analysis shows that while the OMB Guidance for regulatory decision making has been modified over the years, the basic structure has remained the same since the Reagan Administration. Second, we find strong support for energy efficiency standards in public opinion polls. Two-thirds of all respondents support standards. Among those who see benefits from standards, four-fifths support them. The support for appliance efficiency standards equals the high level of support expressed fuel economy standards, which are much more frequently studied. For both appliance and auto standards, almost three-quarters of respondents support the standards with a five-year payback. 3 1. INTRODUCTION AND
Recommended publications
  • A Task-Based Taxonomy of Cognitive Biases for Information Visualization
    A Task-based Taxonomy of Cognitive Biases for Information Visualization Evanthia Dimara, Steven Franconeri, Catherine Plaisant, Anastasia Bezerianos, and Pierre Dragicevic Three kinds of limitations The Computer The Display 2 Three kinds of limitations The Computer The Display The Human 3 Three kinds of limitations: humans • Human vision ️ has limitations • Human reasoning 易 has limitations The Human 4 ️Perceptual bias Magnitude estimation 5 ️Perceptual bias Magnitude estimation Color perception 6 易 Cognitive bias Behaviors when humans consistently behave irrationally Pohl’s criteria distilled: • Are predictable and consistent • People are unaware they’re doing them • Are not misunderstandings 7 Ambiguity effect, Anchoring or focalism, Anthropocentric thinking, Anthropomorphism or personification, Attentional bias, Attribute substitution, Automation bias, Availability heuristic, Availability cascade, Backfire effect, Bandwagon effect, Base rate fallacy or Base rate neglect, Belief bias, Ben Franklin effect, Berkson's paradox, Bias blind spot, Choice-supportive bias, Clustering illusion, Compassion fade, Confirmation bias, Congruence bias, Conjunction fallacy, Conservatism (belief revision), Continued influence effect, Contrast effect, Courtesy bias, Curse of knowledge, Declinism, Decoy effect, Default effect, Denomination effect, Disposition effect, Distinction bias, Dread aversion, Dunning–Kruger effect, Duration neglect, Empathy gap, End-of-history illusion, Endowment effect, Exaggerated expectation, Experimenter's or expectation bias,
    [Show full text]
  • Ilidigital Master Anton 2.Indd
    services are developed to be used by humans. Thus, understanding humans understanding Thus, humans. by used be to developed are services obvious than others but certainly not less complex. Most products bioengineering, and as shown in this magazine. Psychology mightbusiness world. beBe it more the comparison to relationships, game elements, or There are many non-business flieds which can betransfered to the COGNTIVE COGNTIVE is key to a succesfully develop a product orservice. is keytoasuccesfullydevelopproduct BIASES by ANTON KOGER The Power of Power The //PsychologistatILI.DIGITAL WE EDIT AND REINFORCE SOME WE DISCARD SPECIFICS TO WE REDUCE EVENTS AND LISTS WE STORE MEMORY DIFFERENTLY BASED WE NOTICE THINGS ALREADY PRIMED BIZARRE, FUNNY, OR VISUALLY WE NOTICE WHEN WE ARE DRAWN TO DETAILS THAT WE NOTICE FLAWS IN OTHERS WE FAVOR SIMPLE-LOOKING OPTIONS MEMORIES AFTER THE FACT FORM GENERALITIES TO THEIR KEY ELEMENTS ON HOW THEY WERE EXPERIENCED IN MEMORY OR REPEATED OFTEN STRIKING THINGS STICK OUT MORE SOMETHING HAS CHANGED CONFIRM OUR OWN EXISTING BELIEFS MORE EASILY THAN IN OURSELVES AND COMPLETE INFORMATION way we see situations but also the way we situationsbutalsotheway wesee way the biasesnotonlychange Furthermore, overload. cognitive avoid attention, ore situations, guide help todesign massively can This in. take people information of kind explainhowandwhat ofperception egory First,biasesinthecat andappraisal. ory, self,mem perception, into fourcategories: roughly bedivided Cognitive biasescan within thesesituations. forusers interaction andeasy in anatural situationswhichresults sible toimprove itpos and adaptingtothesebiasesmakes ingiven situations.Reacting ways certain act sively helpstounderstandwhypeople mas into consideration biases ing cognitive Tak humanbehavior. topredict likely less or andmore relevant illusionsare cognitive In each situation different every havior day.
    [Show full text]
  • Infographic I.10
    The Digital Health Revolution: Leaving No One Behind The global AI in healthcare market is growing fast, with an expected increase from $4.9 billion in 2020 to $45.2 billion by 2026. There are new solutions introduced every day that address all areas: from clinical care and diagnosis, to remote patient monitoring to EHR support, and beyond. But, AI is still relatively new to the industry, and it can be difficult to determine which solutions can actually make a difference in care delivery and business operations. 59 Jan 2021 % of Americans believe returning Jan-June 2019 to pre-coronavirus life poses a risk to health and well being. 11 41 % % ...expect it will take at least 6 The pandemic has greatly increased the 65 months before things get number of US adults reporting depression % back to normal (updated April and/or anxiety.5 2021).4 Up to of consumers now interested in telehealth going forward. $250B 76 57% of providers view telehealth more of current US healthcare spend % favorably than they did before COVID-19.7 could potentially be virtualized.6 The dramatic increase in of Medicare primary care visits the conducted through 90% $3.5T telehealth has shown longevity, with rates in annual U.S. health expenditures are for people with chronic and mental health conditions. since April 2020 0.1 43.5 leveling off % % Most of these can be prevented by simple around 30%.8 lifestyle changes and regular health screenings9 Feb. 2020 Apr. 2020 OCCAM’S RAZOR • CONJUNCTION FALLACY • DELMORE EFFECT • LAW OF TRIVIALITY • COGNITIVE FLUENCY • BELIEF BIAS • INFORMATION BIAS Digital health ecosystems are transforming• AMBIGUITY BIAS • STATUS medicineQUO BIAS • SOCIAL COMPARISONfrom BIASa rea• DECOYctive EFFECT • REACTANCEdiscipline, • REVERSE PSYCHOLOGY • SYSTEM JUSTIFICATION • BACKFIRE EFFECT • ENDOWMENT EFFECT • PROCESSING DIFFICULTY EFFECT • PSEUDOCERTAINTY EFFECT • DISPOSITION becoming precise, preventive,EFFECT • ZERO-RISK personalized, BIAS • UNIT BIAS • IKEA EFFECT and • LOSS AVERSION participatory.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects of Mentioning Information, Shared Information Bias, Ownership Bias, Reiteration, and Confirmation Bias Lyn M
    Perceived Importance of Information: The Effects of Mentioning Information, Shared Information Bias, Ownership Bias, Reiteration, and Confirmation Bias Lyn M. van Swol To cite this version: Lyn M. van Swol. Perceived Importance of Information: The Effects of Mentioning Information, Shared Information Bias, Ownership Bias, Reiteration, and Confirmation Bias. Group Processes and Intergroup Relations, SAGE Publications, 2007, 10 (2), pp.239-256. 10.1177/1368430207074730. hal-00571647 HAL Id: hal-00571647 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-00571647 Submitted on 1 Mar 2011 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Group Processes & Intergroup Relations 2007 Vol 10(2) 239–256 Perceived Importance of Information: The Effects of Mentioning Information, Shared Information Bias, Ownership Bias, Reiteration, and Confi rmation Bias Lyn M. Van Swol Northwestern University Participants were given information for and against the decriminalization of marijuana and discussed the issue in groups. Factors affecting rated importance of information after the group discussion were examined. Participants did not rate information that was mentioned during the discussion as more important than information not mentioned, and participants did not rate shared information they mentioned as more important than unshared information.
    [Show full text]
  • The Psychology of Competition: a Social Comparison Perspective
    Notre Dame Law School NDLScholarship Journal Articles Publications 11-2013 The Psychology of Competition: A Social Comparison Perspective Stephen M. Garcia Avishalom Tor Notre Dame Law School, [email protected] Tyrone M. Schiff Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.nd.edu/law_faculty_scholarship Part of the Behavior and Behavior Mechanisms Commons, and the Law and Society Commons Recommended Citation Stephen M. Garcia, Avishalom Tor & Tyrone M. Schiff, The Psychology of Competition: A Social Comparison Perspective, 8 Persp on Psych Sci 634 (2013). Available at: https://scholarship.law.nd.edu/law_faculty_scholarship/941 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Publications at NDLScholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal Articles by an authorized administrator of NDLScholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. PPSXXX10.1177/1745691613504114Garcia et al.Psychology of Competition 504114research-article2013 Perspectives on Psychological Science XX(X) 1 –17 The Psychology of Competition: © The Author(s) 2013 Reprints and permissions: sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav A Social Comparison Perspective DOI: 10.1177/1745691613504114 pps.sagepub.com Stephen M. Garcia1, Avishalom Tor2, and Tyrone M. Schiff1 1University of Michigan and 2University of Notre Dame Abstract Social comparison—the tendency to self-evaluate by comparing ourselves to others—is an important source of competitive behavior. We propose a new model that distinguishes between individual and situational factors that increase social comparison and thus lead to a range of competitive attitudes and behavior. Individual factors are those that vary from person to person: the relevance of the performance dimension, the similarity of rivals, and their relationship closeness to the individual, as well as the various individual differences variables relating to social comparison more generally.
    [Show full text]
  • John Collins, President, Forensic Foundations Group
    On Bias in Forensic Science National Commission on Forensic Science – May 12, 2014 56-year-old Vatsala Thakkar was a doctor in India but took a job as a convenience store cashier to help pay family expenses. She was stabbed to death outside her store trying to thwart a theft in November 2008. Bloody Footwear Impression Bloody Tire Impression What was the threat? 1. We failed to ask ourselves if this was a footwear impression. 2. The appearance of the impression combined with the investigator’s interpretation created prejudice. The accuracy of our analysis became threatened by our prejudice. Types of Cognitive Bias Available at: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_cognitive_biases | Accessed on April 14, 2014 Anchoring or focalism Hindsight bias Pseudocertainty effect Illusory superiority Levels-of-processing effect Attentional bias Hostile media effect Reactance Ingroup bias List-length effect Availability heuristic Hot-hand fallacy Reactive devaluation Just-world phenomenon Misinformation effect Availability cascade Hyperbolic discounting Recency illusion Moral luck Modality effect Backfire effect Identifiable victim effect Restraint bias Naive cynicism Mood-congruent memory bias Bandwagon effect Illusion of control Rhyme as reason effect Naïve realism Next-in-line effect Base rate fallacy or base rate neglect Illusion of validity Risk compensation / Peltzman effect Outgroup homogeneity bias Part-list cueing effect Belief bias Illusory correlation Selective perception Projection bias Peak-end rule Bias blind spot Impact bias Semmelweis
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects of Group Status on Intragroup Behavior
    The Effects of Group Status on Intragroup Behavior: Implications for Group Process and Outcome Jin Wook Chang Organizational Behavior and Theory Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Dissertation Committee: Rosalind M. Chow (Co-Chair) Anita W. Woolley (Co-Chair) Linda Argote John M. Levine The Effects of Group Status on Intragroup Behavior: Implications for Group Process and Outcome ABSTRACT How does the status of a group influence the behavior of individuals within the group? This dissertation aims to answer this question by investigating the psychological and behavioral implications of membership in high- versus low-status groups, with a primary focus on the impact of membership in a high-status group. I propose that in high-status groups, personal interests, including material and relational, are more salient, therefore guiding member behavior within the groups. This emphasis on personal gain leads to behavior that best suits their interests regardless of the impact on group outcomes. In six studies, using both experimental and correlational methods, I test this main idea and examine boundary conditions. The first set of studies examines members’ group-oriented behavior, and finds that membership in a high-status group (a) decreases the resources allocated for the group as members attempt to ensure personal gain; (b) lowers the preference for a competent newcomer who may enhance group outcome but who may jeopardize personal gains; and (c) reduces the amount of voluntary information sharing during group negotiations, hindering group outcomes. The findings also reveal that reducing the conflict between group and personal interests via cooperative incentives encourages group- oriented behavior in high-status groups.
    [Show full text]
  • Kevin Masters 1 VITA Kevin S. Masters Office: Department Of
    Kevin Masters 1 VITA Kevin S. Masters Office: Department of Psychology University of Colorado Denver Denver, CO 80217-3364 Telephone: Office: (303) 315-7062 Fax: (303) 556-3520 E-mail: [email protected] Major Position Professor; Program Director in Clinical Health Psychology Department of Psychology University of Colorado Denver Denver, CO Secondary Position Director of Behavioral Research Anschutz Health and Wellness Center University of Colorado Denver Denver, CO Education Ph.D. Clinical Psychology. Brigham Young University, Provo, Utah, 1989. APA accredited program. Predoctoral Clinical Internship. Duke University Medical Center, Durham, North Carolina, 1988-89. APA accredited internship. M.A. Clinical Psychology. University of Dayton, Dayton, Ohio, 1982. B.A. (Summa Cum Laude), Psychology, Cedarville College, Cedarville, Ohio, 1980. Teaching Experience (Courses Taught) Physiological Processes and Health Psychology (Graduate course) Cardiovascular Health Psychology (Graduate course) Health Psychology (Graduate course) Readings in Health Psychology (Graduate course) Ethical and Professional Issues in Clinical Psychology (Graduate course) Introduction to Psychotherapy (Graduate course) Kevin Masters 2 Existential and Spiritual Approaches to Psychotherapy (Graduate course) Existential and Spiritual Issues in Health Psychology (Graduate course) Intellectual Assessment (Graduate course) Advanced Personality Assessment (Graduate course) Empirically Validated Treatments (Graduate course) Practicum in Psychotherapy (Graduate course)
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Embrace Your Cognitive Bias
    1 Embrace Your Cognitive Bias http://blog.beaufortes.com/2007/06/embrace-your-co.html Cognitive Biases are distortions in the way humans see things in comparison to the purely logical way that mathematics, economics, and yes even project management would have us look at things. The problem is not that we have them… most of them are wired deep into our brains following millions of years of evolution. The problem is that we don’t know about them, and consequently don’t take them into account when we have to make important decisions. (This area is so important that Daniel Kahneman won a Nobel Prize in 2002 for work tying non-rational decision making, and cognitive bias, to mainstream economics) People don’t behave rationally, they have emotions, they can be inspired, they have cognitive bias! Tying that into how we run projects (project leadership as a compliment to project management) can produce results you wouldn’t believe. You have to know about them to guard against them, or use them (but that’s another article)... So let’s get more specific. After the jump, let me show you a great list of cognitive biases. I’ll bet that there are at least a few that you haven’t heard of before! Decision making and behavioral biases Bandwagon effect — the tendency to do (or believe) things because many other people do (or believe) the same. Related to groupthink, herd behaviour, and manias. Bias blind spot — the tendency not to compensate for one’s own cognitive biases. Choice-supportive bias — the tendency to remember one’s choices as better than they actually were.
    [Show full text]
  • Implicit Bias and Moral Analysis: Continuing to Traverse the Moral Terrain of Community Development
    Implicit Bias and Moral Analysis: Continuing to Traverse the Moral Terrain of Community Development Peter A. DePergola II, Ph.D., M.T.S. Director of Clinical Ethics, Baystate Health Assistant Professor of Medicine, University of Massachusetts Medical School Assistant Professor of Bioethics and Medical Humanities, Elms College Director, Center for Ethics, Religion, and Culture, Elms College Adjunct Assistant Professor of Medicine, Tufts University School of Medicine Research Scientist in Neuroethics, American Academy of Neurology Research Scholar in Bioethics, TEDMED Objectives • Identify the relevant questions of moral analysis and moral reasoning in the context of community development. • Examine sources of implicit bias in the context of distributing limited goods. • Discuss methods by which to identify and remedy implicit bias in the context of serving others. • Distinguish between caring for a person with needs and caring for the needs a person has. Relevant Questions of Moral Analysis • “What?” (Veracity) • “Why?” and “How?” (Beneficence, Nonmaleficence) • “Who?” (Dignity, Autonomy) • “When?” and “Where?” (Justice, Privacy, Confidentiality) • “What if…?” (Prudence) • “What else?” (Fidelity, Courage) Relevant Questions of Moral Reasoning 1. What are we attempting to do? (Is our plan for serving persons in need ethically, legally, and practically reasonable?) 2. Why are we attempting to do it? (Is our plan for serving persons in need focused on the overall well-being of those in need?) 3. How are we attempting to do it? (Is the method of serving persons in need proportionate to the goals we had for serving them in the first place?) 4. What do we intend in attempting to do it? (Is our plan for serving persons in need emerging from a place of benevolence?) 5.
    [Show full text]
  • Cognitive Biases Cognitive Biases and Heuristics Are Mental Shortcuts That Aid in Processing of Information, but Can Lead to Suboptimal Decisions
    Cognitive Biases Cognitive biases and heuristics are mental shortcuts that aid in processing of information, but can lead to suboptimal decisions. List of Biases and Heuristics Bias/Effect Description Business Problem Category Advice Ambiguity bias Preference for known Need to We favor options that appear simple risks over unknown risks Act Fast or that have more complete information over more complex, ambiguous options. Anchoring Overreliance on initial Think of each Too Much We notice when something has information piece of Information changed. information as independently as possible, then review them collectively Anecdotal fallacy Overvaluing personal Not We find stories and patterns even in experience when Enough sparse data. compared to data Meaning Anthropomorphism Mistakenly imbuing things Not We find stories and patterns even in with human traits Enough sparse data. Meaning Appeal to novelty Belief that something new Need to In order to stay focused, we favor the is inherently superior to Act Fast immediate, relatable thing in front of status quo us over the delayed and distant. Appeal to probability Mistaking probability for Even the best Not We simplify probabilities and fallacy certainty laid plans can Enough numbers to make them easier to think fail, even when Meaning about. they are more likely than not to succeed Argument from Mistaken belief that a Some Not We fill in characteristics from fallacy fallacious argument arguments are Enough stereotypes, generalities, and prior implies that the better than Meaning histories
    [Show full text]
  • Toward a Meta-Methodology for Real-World Problem Solving
    Toward a meta-methodology for real-world problem solving by Ryan Reed Dissertation presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Industrial Engineering in the Faculty of Engineering at Stellenbosch University Promoter: Prof JH van Vuuren March 2020 Stellenbosch University https://scholar.sun.ac.za Stellenbosch University https://scholar.sun.ac.za Declaration By submitting this dissertation electronically, I declare that the entirety of the work contained therein is my own, original work, that I am the sole author thereof (save to the extent explicitly otherwise stated), that reproduction and publication thereof by Stellenbosch University will not infringe any third party rights and that I have not previously in its entirety or in part submitted it for obtaining any qualification. Date: March 2020 Copyright © 2020 Stellenbosch University All rights reserved i Stellenbosch University https://scholar.sun.ac.za ii Stellenbosch University https://scholar.sun.ac.za Abstract There are complexities inherent to the subjective experience of life that render real-world prob- lem solving exceedingly subtle and difficult. Yet, all too often, it is not the complex nature of problems that result in their persistence, but rather the ineffective fashion in which practitioners dedicated to their resolution respond thereto. The process of real-world problem solving comprises three parts: The development of a formal formulation of a problem considered, the identification of an adequate response thereto, often by means of analytical modelling, and finally, the practical implementation of that response. In the history of real-world problem solving, the first of these phases has often been neglected and, as a result, solution methodologies dedicated to the formulation of problems, complicated by the dynamics of human nature, have failed to address several phenomena relevant to the success of problem resolution.
    [Show full text]