Ballot Initiative Knowledge and Voter Turnout

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Ballot Initiative Knowledge and Voter Turnout Ballot Initiative Knowledge and Voter Turnout: Evidence from Field Experiments and National Surveys Jason Barabas1 Charles Barrilleaux2 Daniel Scheller3 DRAFT Abstract Policy issues play an important role in explanations of vote choice, but their effect on political participation is less clear. We employ randomized field experiments to determine whether reminding voters about the presence of issue amendments on the ballot influenced turnout in Florida during the 2006 general election. Contrary to findings in some observational studies, providing information regarding initiatives failed to stimulate turnout on all but the least publicly salient ballot amendments placed before voters in that election. In particular, a mail postcard message reminding citizens to vote on ballot measures that had largely escaped media scrutiny increased turnout by a few percentage points. Traditional get-out-the-vote civic duty messages proved to be ineffective as were attempts to remind citizens to vote on several more well-known initiatives. In an attempt to replicate the patterns nationally, we documented strong associations between knowledge of ballot initiatives and intended turnout in two cross-sectional surveys from 2006. Taken together, the empirical results suggest that increasing awareness of ballot initiatives can stimulate voter turnout, especially on relatively obscure issue amendments. 1 Associate Professor, Department of Political Science, Stony Brook University, jason.barabas @ stonybrook.edu. 2 LeRoy Collins Professor, Department of Political Science, Florida State University, cbarrilleaux @ fsu.edu. 3 Assistant Professor, College of Liberal Arts, University of Texas-El Paso, dsscheller @ utep.edu. Issues play an important role in elections, but scholars usually focus on the degree to which voters use policy preferences to select one candidate over another. Yet in many electoral settings citizens vote directly on issue initiatives in addition to selecting candidates. We have theories of issue voting (e.g., Carmines and Stimson 1980; Nie, Verba, and Petrocik 1979; Rabinowitz and Macdonald 1989), but surprisingly no comparable concept of “issue turnout” has emerged. The closest one comes to a theory of issue-based turnout is the rational choice explanation of voting (Downs 1957) in which an individual’s decision to vote depends on the probability of affecting the election times the utility gained from having the most preferred candidate win minus any costs. Smith (2001) adopts this perspective in his study of how salient ballot measures stimulate turnout. Information-based explanations of turnout also underlie work by Tolbert and her colleagues (Tolbert, Grummel, and Smith 2001; Tolbert, McNeal, and Smith 2003) as well as other studies that employ formal theoretical perspectives (Grosser and Schram 2006; Lassen 2005). The idea that issues, and ballot initiatives in particular, can help reverse years of declining voter turnout has great normative appeal (Teixeira 1992). Activists and progressive reformers claim that direct democracy can help create engaged citizens (Schmidt 1989; Zimmerman 1999). Scholars are also enamored with the notion of participatory democracy (Barber 1985; Pateman 1976). We take up the question of whether providing information about the presence of ballot initiatives affects voter participation. We examine this question using a methodology—the field experiment—which is the gold standard of get-out-the-vote evaluations (e.g., Gerber and Green 2000a; 2000b; 2001; 2002; Green, Gerber, and Nickerson 2003; Nickerson 2006). To date field experiments have not been used in a large scale study of the effects of get out the vote efforts on voting in elections with 2 ballot initiatives. Our results suggest that providing information on ballot amendments can stimulate turnout, but mostly in situations when the initiatives are relatively obscure. The Effects of Ballot Initiatives on Voter Turnout Ballot propositions have become a popular way for citizens to influence the laws and policies of their state. Twenty-four states in America practice some form of direct democracy and usage is on the rise. For instance, David Magleby (1994) found that from 1898 to 1992 over 1,700 initiatives were placed before U.S. voters. That number would have been higher had hundreds more qualified for inclusion on the ballots. However, Magleby notes that only 38% of initiatives passed (p. 231), which suggests that voters are fairly discerning. Furthermore, some states like Oregon and California offer voters many initiatives in elections while others like Illinois use it sparingly and only for the purpose of altering the legislative process (Tolbert, Lowenstein, and Donovan 1998). Past research has often concentrated on how initiatives are placed on the ballot, the role of special interests, and the effects on public policy outcomes or enfranchisement (e.g., Boehmke 2002; Bowler, Donovan, and Tolbert 1998; Gerber 1999; Smith 2004). However, two rationales are typically advanced for the use of ballot initiatives: (1) preventing the legislature from becoming unrepresentative, and (2) educating the voters on issues and civic skills like voting. While there is an active literature on the first question (e.g., Gerber 1996; Matsusaka 1995), it is “educative” effects of initiatives that are of concern here (Tolbert and Smith 2005). Most of the early studies that ask whether the presence of ballot initiatives increases turnout were not encouraging. In particular, work in the 1980s found no statistically significant relationship 3 between direct democracy and electoral participation (Everson 1981; Gilliam 1985; Magelby 1984). However, by the early-2000s evidence started to accumulate to suggest that ballot initiatives increase turnout, particularly in midterm elections (Smith 2001), but also in presidential contests. For example, using a pooled times of data for the 50 states over a 26-year period (from 1970 to 1996), Tolbert, Grummel, and Smith (2001) find that the presence and usage of citizen inspired initiatives boosts voter turnout from 3 to 4.5% in presidential races and from 7 to 9% in midterm elections. More recent work by Tolbert and Smith (2005) estimated the effects at nearly 1 to 2 percentage points for presidential and midterm elections respectively. They also document variation in effects within types of elections, observing a 4 point turnout effect in 1992 but a smaller 0.5 percentage point effect in 1996 (Smith and Tolbert 2004, 51). Methodological Advances and Limitations Three types of methodological improvements helped move the field from the null findings of years ago (Everson 1981) to the largely positive effects of today (Tolbert et al. 2001; 2003; 2005; Smith 2001). First, scholars like Tolbert, Grummel, and Smith (2001) obtained more precise statistical estimates by controlling for potentially confounding factors such as race, income, and the distinctiveness of the South. Also, they did so while using panel-corrected standard errors to acknowledge correlations across the repeated state-level observations. Finally, and most recently, they refined their analyses to consider distinctions between the voter-age versus voter-eligible populations (Tolbert and Smith 2005). However, these studies use aggregate-level data. A second methodological innovation has been to employ individual-level data. For example, “To avoid the ecological fallacies to which 4 aggregate-level analyses are prone…,” Tolbert, McNeal, and Smith (2003, 27) use individual level American National Election Studies (ANES) data collected during 1996, 1998, and 2000 to show that ballot initiatives increase turnout in midterm elections, but not necessarily during the presidential years. Lacey (2005) obtained similar results using a slightly different set of ANES surveys in 1990, 1992, 1994 and 1996. Finally, an important methodological advance with theoretical relevance concerns the salience of the initiative. Mark Smith (2001) finds that ballot initiatives increase turnout in midterm elections to the degree that they are salient. In other words, Smith argues turnout should be and indeed was found to be highest when a state’s largest newspaper devoted a lot of front page coverage to particular amendments on the day after the election (also see Lacey 2005). However, Tolbert and her colleagues (Tolbert, Grummel, and Smith. 2001) question the validity of Smith’s measure. They note that “A more direct and simple measure of saliency is the actual number of initiatives on the ballot each election…” (p. 632). That is, instead of a simple dichotomous measure of whether a state employs the initiative process, they use the number of initiatives on the ballot at any given moment as a way of capturing the amount of information available regarding ballot initiatives (also see Tolbert, McNeal, and Smith 2003; Tolbert and Smith 2005). Yet no matter what measure of salience one adopts—front-page media stories, initiative counts, or otherwise—room for improvements remains even with these advances. In particular, there is a tremendous amount of heterogeneity in ballot initiatives rules across the states. Some require the signatures of 10% of the total votes cast in the previous gubernatorial election (e.g., Utah) while for others the bar is 5% (Nebraska, Montana), 4% (Arkansas), or just one signature from voters residing in at least two-thirds of a state’s election districts (Alaska). The states also 5 use different time requirements—Idaho, Oregon, and Utah do not limit the amount of
Recommended publications
  • Voting for Parties Or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Di↵Erence?
    Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Di↵erence? Elena Llaudet⇤ Harvard University September 14, 2014 Abstract In this paper, I analyze the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems (CSES) data to put the U.S. case in a comparative context and explore the impact of electoral institutions on voting behavior. I find that the U.S. is not unique when it comes to party defection, defined as voting for a party other than ones own. Furthermore, when focusing on countries with mixed electoral systems, I find that electoral institutions have a substantial e↵ect on the degree to which the vote choice is party or candidate- centered, and thus, they might, in turn, have an impact on the level of incumbency advantage in the elections. ⇤Ph.D. from the Department of Government at Harvard University and current post-doctoral fellow in the Democracy Program at the Brennan Center for Justice at NYU Law School ([email protected]). Elections in the U.S. have long been considered unique, with its candidate-centered pol- itics and high levels of incumbency advantage. In this paper, I aim to put the U.S. case in a comparative context and explore the e↵ect that electoral institutions have on the voting behavior of the electorate. In particular, I study whether electoral systems a↵ect the likeli- hood of party defection in lower house elections, a phenomenon defined as voting for a party other than one’s own. In addition, to the extent possible, I try to distinguish whether voters are casting a ballot for a di↵erent party for strategic purposes – voting for a party that has higher chances of winning than their preferred one – or to support a particular candidate due to the candidate’s personal attributes, such as incumbency status.
    [Show full text]
  • VVSG Comments
    Before the U.S. ELECTION ASSISTANCE COMMISSION In the Matter of ) COMMENTS SUBMISSION ) VOLUNTARY VOTING SYSTEM ) Pursuant to 84 FR 6775, Doc. No.: 2019-03453 ) GUIDELINES VERSION 2.0 ) Wednesday, May 29th, 2019 ) DEVELOPMENT ) EAC Offices, Silver Spring, MD PUBLIC COMMENTS SUBMISSION OSET INSTITUTE COMMENTS LED BY GLOBAL DIRECTOR OF TECHNOLOGY EDWARD P. PEREZ REGARDING THE VOLUNTARY VOTING SYSTEM GUIDELINES VERSION 2.0 PRINCIPLES AND GUIDELINES Comment #1 Issue: Principles and Guidelines vs. Functional Requirements Reference: Overall VVSG 2.0 Structure The OSET Institute applauds the U.S. Election Assistance Commission (hereinafter, “EAC”) for making efforts to ensure that the future Voluntary Voting System Guidelines (VVSG) certification program is more flexible and agile than it has been in the past. With increasingly faster advances of technology matched by newly emerging cyber-security threats, it is essential for the VVSG to support regular adaptation and modification. Toward that end, VVSG 2.0's initial distinction between "Principles and Guidelines" versus "Functional Requirements" is well placed and laudable. In order to deliver on the promise of such a distinction, the OSET Institute believes that the following programmatic requirements must be adhered to: • “Principles and Guidelines" reflect policy statements, and any modifications to the Principles and Guidelines should require approval of EAC Commissioners. • Functional Requirements (and VSTL test assertions) do not represent policy statements, and their modification should not require approval of EAC Commissioners. Functional Requirements are simply the technical means to operationalize or implement the achievement of policy goals represented in the Principles and Guidelines. • Functional Requirements must support the policy goals represented in the Principles and Guidelines.
    [Show full text]
  • Testing Proximity Versus Directional Voting Using Experimentsq
    Electoral Studies 29 (2010) 460–471 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Electoral Studies journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Testing proximity versus directional voting using experimentsq Dean Lacy a,1, Philip Paolino b,* a Dartmouth College, 211A Silsby Hall, HB 6108, Hanover, NH 03755, United States b University of North Texas, 1155 Union Circle # 305340, Denton, TX 76203-5017, United States article info abstract Article history: A long-running debate about how voters use issues to evaluate candidates pits the prox- Received 3 July 2009 imity theory of voting against directional theory. Using surveys, both sides of the debate Received in revised form 18 February 2010 have found support for their preferred theory, but disagreement remains because of Accepted 6 April 2010 differing ways of analyzing the data. Lewis and King (2000) point out that these researchers make assumptions that bias results in favor of their theory. To avoid these Keywords: difficulties, our approach creates fictitious candidates with controlled positions, presents Issue voting these candidates to randomly-assigned subjects, and examines the relationship between Proximity ’ Directional subjects evaluations of these candidates and their ideological beliefs as a neutral test of Experiment proximity and directional theory. Our results provide reasonably strong support for proximity theory but little for directional theory. Ó 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction voting, voters and candidates have ideal points on a logical ordering of different policies, and voters choose the An important tenet of democracy is that elections allow candidate whose ideal point is nearest to their own (e.g., voters to influence public policy.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effect of Electoral Competitiveness on Voter Turnout
    Western Washington University Western CEDAR WWU Honors Program Senior Projects WWU Graduate and Undergraduate Scholarship Spring 2017 The Effect of Electoral Competitiveness on Voter Turnout Joel Jordan Western Washington University Follow this and additional works at: https://cedar.wwu.edu/wwu_honors Part of the Political Science Commons Recommended Citation Jordan, Joel, "The Effect of Electoral Competitiveness on Voter Turnout" (2017). WWU Honors Program Senior Projects. 43. https://cedar.wwu.edu/wwu_honors/43 This Project is brought to you for free and open access by the WWU Graduate and Undergraduate Scholarship at Western CEDAR. It has been accepted for inclusion in WWU Honors Program Senior Projects by an authorized administrator of Western CEDAR. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 1 The Effect of Electoral Competitiveness on Voter Turnout Joel Jordan Political Science Honors Thesis Western Washington University 2 Introduction In the most recent midterm congressional elections of 2014, over 83 million people entered the polls to vote for the 435 people who would pass legislation for the next two years (McDonald, 2016). These 83 million people, however, only account for 33% of our voting age population. Explaining the 33% voter turnout for legislative elections in the United States is of interest for three primary reasons. First, the United States has a substantially lower voter turnout than most other electoral democracies in the world. Figure 1 shows the voting age population turnout across 36 countries (IDEA, 2017). These countries contain more than one million people, are classified by the world bank as “High Income,” and are classified by Freedom House as “Free” (CIA, 2015)(World Bank, 2017)(Freedom House, 2017).
    [Show full text]
  • Referendum Campaigns: Changing What People Think Or Changing What They Think About?1 Michael Marsh
    02305_17838_06_cha04.qxp 6/20/2007 2:01 AM Page 63 4 Referendum Campaigns: Changing What People Think or Changing What They Think About?1 Michael Marsh Cohen (1963: 13) made the well-known observation that the media do not so much tell people what to think as tell them what to think about. The same argument is often made with respect to parties in election campaigns as they try to ensure that the focus of the campaign will be on issues that are positive ones for them, or which they own (Schattschneider, 1960; Riker, 1986; Petrocik, 1996; Budge et al., 2001). Less common is to suggest that the same should be true of referendums. This argument can be found in Magelby (1989) and Darcy and Laver (1990) while de Vreese and Semetko (2004) provide an intensive empirical study of the Danish vote on the euro to show how far this happens. The pro-referendum side will try to persuade the public that the referendum is about something the public feels positive about while the anti-referendum side will explain the referendum in terms they think will provoke negative feel- ings. A successful redefinition of the issue may well provoke consider- able volatility in the campaign, and this is much more likely to happen in a referendum (LeDuc, 2002a, 2002b). Of course, the extent to which either side can do this will depend in part on the strength of the respec- tive campaigns. Overall, a weak campaign may leave the electorate sim- ply confused; a strong one should bring more clarity, and an unbalanced one should see voters’ perceptions reflecting the weight of the stronger campaign.
    [Show full text]
  • Efficiency, Equity, and Timing in Voting Mechanisms
    Efficiency, Equity, and Timing in Voting Mechanisms by Marco Battaglini, Princeton University Rebecca Morton, New York University Thomas Palfrey, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 121 September 2005 We thank Anna Bassi, Shivani Nayyar, Valeria Palanza, and Stephanie Wang for their research assistance. We also benefited from the comments of Sandy Gordon, Scott DeMarchi, and participants at the Interactions Workshop at GREQAM, Marseille, the Conference on Constitutional and Scientific Quandries at ICER, Torino, the Conference in Tribute to Jean- Jacques Laffont in Toulouse, the 2005 American Political Science Association Annual Meetings, and seminar participants at the Princeton Center for the Study of Democratic Politics. Thomas Palfrey acknowledges support from NSF grants SES-0079301 and SES-0094800, as well as from Princeton University’s Center for Economic Policy Studies. Abstract We compare the behavior of voters, depending on whether they operate under sequential and simultaneous voting rules, when voting is costly and information is incomplete. In many real political institutions, ranging from small committees to mass elections, voting is sequential, which allows some voters to know the choices of earlier voters. For a styl- ized model, we characterize the equilibria for this rule, and compare it to simultaneous voting, and show how these equilibria vary for di¤erent voting costs. This generates a variety of predictions about the relative e¢ ciency and equity of these two systems, which we test using controlled laboratory experiments. Most of the qualitative predictions are supported by the data, but there are signi…cant departures from the predicted equilib- rium strategies, in both the sequential and sumultanous voting games.
    [Show full text]
  • Polls, the Press, and Political Participation: the Effects of Anticipated Election Closeness on Voter Turnout
    Polls, the Press, and Political Participation: The Effects of Anticipated Election Closeness on Voter Turnout Leonardo Bursztyn Davide Cantoni Patricia Funk Noam Yuchtman* July 2018 Abstract Models of voting, including the canonical rational voter model, predict that voters are more likely to turn out when they anticipate a closer election. Yet, evidence of a causal effect of antic- ipated election closeness on voter turnout is limited. We exploit naturally occurring variation in the existence, closeness, and dissemination of pre-election polls to identify a causal effect of anticipated election closeness on voter turnout in Swiss referenda. Closer elections are as- sociated with greater turnout only when polls exist. Examining within-election variation in newspaper reporting on polls across cantons, we find that close polls increase turnout signifi- cantly more where newspapers report on them most. This holds examining only “incidental” exposure to coverage by periodicals whose largest audience is elsewhere. The introduction of polls had larger effects in politically unrepresentative municipalities, where locally available information differs most from national polls. Keywords: Voter turnout, media, polls JEL Classification: D72, P16 *Bursztyn: University of Chicago and NBER. Email: [email protected]. Cantoni: University of Munich, CEPR, and CESifo. Email: [email protected]. Funk: Universita` della Svizzera Italiana. Email: [email protected]. Yuchtman: UC Berkeley, Haas School of Business, NBER, and CESifo. Email: [email protected]. We would like to thank Ernesto Dal Bo,´ Devesh Rustagi and numerous seminar participants for very helpful comments. We thank Tillmann von Carnap, Raymond Han, Peter Hong, Vasily Korovkin, Aakaash Rao, Ann-Christin Schwegmann, and in particular Francesca Crotta, Felix Schoenenberger, and Christoph Wellig, for extraordinary research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Rational Behavior and Information in Strategic Voting
    RATIONALITY AND INFORMATION IN STRATEGIC VOTING DISSERTATION Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate School of Ohio State University By Andrew R. Tomlinson, M.A. * * * * * The Ohio State University 2001 Dissertation Committee: Approved by Professor Herbert F. Weisberg, Adviser Professor Paul Allen Beck __________________________________ Adviser Professor Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier Political Science Graduate Program ABSTRACT In recent years, third parties and independent candidacies have become an important part of the American political system. Yet few of these parties or candidates have been able to win office. Strategic voting by supporters of third party and independent candidates often siphons off potential votes for those candidates, and leads to their loss. Much of the work that has been done on strategic voting leaves out some crucial elements of the voting process. In this dissertation I fill some of the gaps in the extant literature. Using data from the 1998 Gubernatorial election in Minnesota and the 1994 U.S. Senate election in Virginia, I show how the amount of strategic voting was drastically different in the two elections. I then use the Virginia data to model the vote choice of supporters of the third- place candidate with the correct, theoretically-based model. Next, I content analyze newspaper coverage of the two elections, in order to examine the role of the media in shaping the decision to vote strategically or sincerely. I find that there was more coverage of candidate negativity and more coverage of the horserace aspect of the campaign in Virginia than in Minnesota.
    [Show full text]
  • Taking Ballots Seriously: Heterogeneous Ballot Compositions and Vote Choice
    Taking Ballots Seriously: Heterogeneous Ballot Compositions and Vote Choice Ingrid Mauerer University of Barcelona School of Economics Institutions and Political Economy Research Group Address: John M. Keynes, 1-11, 08034 Barcelona, Spain Phone: +34 93 403 72 32 Email: [email protected] Annemarie Walter University of Nottingham School of Politics and International Relations Address: University Park, Nottingham, NG7 2RD, United Kingdom Email: [email protected] Acknowledgements: We wish to thank Cees van der Eijk, Paul Thurner, Bill Greene, Ruth Dassonneville, and Jonathan Mellon for their helpful comments. We are also grateful to Hannah Reitz and Daniel Krähmer for superb research assistance. Taking Ballots Seriously: Heterogeneous Ballot Compositions and Vote Choice Ingrid Mauerer and Annemarie Walter In partially-contested multiparty elections, voters are confronted with different party choices, depending on their constituency. We present a computationally straightforward modeling approach that systematically integrates heterogeneous ballot compositions, which classical models neglect, into the voter utility functions. We illustrate the benefits of the approach in studying British spatial voting behavior, where previous studies tend to simplify the actual choice situation by modeling a single ballot composition, thereby ignoring a substantial part of the electorate. Using 2015 British Election Study data, we simultaneously consider up to seven parties, spread across eight unique ballots, and provide a fully-specified vote model. The results show that both spatial and tactical considerations depend on which party voters evaluate. Whereas spatial proximity substantially impacts voting for the large parties, we uncover the reversed pattern for tactical considerations. These party-specific effects are not found when neglecting ballot composition heterogeneity.
    [Show full text]
  • Candidate Information Packet Student Government Association University of Colorado Denver
    Candidate Information Packet Student Government Association University of Colorado Denver Spring 2021 Election Dear Candidate, Thank you for your interest in the University of Colorado Denver’s Student Government Association. This application packet contains the necessary forms for verification of candidacy. All other supporting documents (Spring 2021) Election Code, CU Denver SGA Constitution, AHEC Posting Policies, Student Code of Conduct, etc.) can be found at the CU Denver SGA website: http://www.ucdenver.edu/sga Please address all correspondence and election questions to: [email protected] The candidate eligibility form (found on MyLynx) is due electronically on Wednesday, March 10th by Midnight. In addition, we are requesting a small candidate bio (no more than 300 words) with your candidate eligibility form. Candidates must personally attend one of two available election information sessions held on March 11th at 5pm or March 12th at 11am. The purpose of this meeting is to address candidate questions and review election guidelines. You, and your campaign team, are expected to know all campaign rules, regulations, and consequences for rule violations. While all this information is included in this packet in the Election Code, here are some reminders: Positions for candidacy include the Executive ticket (President and Vice President), six (6) finance and funding and six (6) legislation and outreach Senators., one (1) Chair of Events and Planning, one (1) Chair of Student Fee Review Committee, two (2) SACAB Representatives and eight (8) members of College Council. College Council candidates must be a declared major in the school/college they are running for. The General Election will begin on Monday, April 5th, 2021 and will end on April 9th, 2021.
    [Show full text]
  • Voting Preferences and the Environment in the American
    Societyand Natural Resources, 14:455–469, 2001 Copyright Ó 2001 Taylor& Francis 0894-1920/2001 $12 .00 1 .00 Voting Preferences and theEnvironment in the American Electorate DEBORAHL YNNGUBER Department ofPolitical Science University of Vermont Burlington, Vermont, USA Despite evidence of agrowing environmental consensus in the United States, students of electoral politics have long debated the political signicance of environmentalism by noting the near absence of this issue from national political campaigns. Unfortu- nately, with only limited survey data available in the past, the few studies to address environmental voting did moreto report adeciency than to explain whyit should be the case. In this study Iuse 1996 National Election Study (NES) data to examine the impact of environmental concern onattitudes toward American political parties and their candidates. Data results on issue positions and proximities conrm that while environmental issues represent astrength of the Democratic ticket, those issues seldom shape individual vote preferences for three reasons: (1) low issue salience; (2) small perceived differences between candidates on matters of environmental policy; and (3) the tendency of environmental concern to cut across traditional (and morepowerful) cleavages, including partisan identication. Keywords environmental attitudes, issue salience, partisan identication, political parties, U.S. elections, voting In democracies, the “bottom line”for judging the strength of public opinion isthe impact of that opinion on the electoral
    [Show full text]
  • CRT Draft 20050914 Section 1 Preface
    CRT Draft 20050914 Section 1 Preface This document contains "zeroth draft" text from Core Requirements and Testing (CRT) for the following parts of the next iteration of the VVSG: • Introductory text, including introduction to new standards architecture (Section 2.1.1) • Requirements on casting (Section 4.4.2) counting and reporting (Section 4.4.3) • General software integrity (not security -- Section 4.3.1.1.1) and workmanship requirements (Section 4.3.4) • Process model (Section 4.5.1) • Logic model (Section 4.5.2) • Logic verification (Section 6.3.1) • Beginnings of test protocols (not including security or usability testing -- Section 6.4) • Miscellaneous minor sections assigned to CRT • CRT contributions to sections assigned to other subcommittees that have not yet been transferred • Rationale for changes (Section 2.1) Text for hardware and software performance requirements and hardware workmanship requirements is distributed in a separate document. "Zeroth draft" text is neither complete nor reviewed, and informative text is missing. The goal of this draft is just to show the directions that CRT is taking and provide the opportunity for early feedback. Notes on work that is yet to be done and problems that need to be fixed are shown highlighted like this. These notes are for our own use and will not appear in the final draft. Similarly, the Impact field of requirements is for our own use and will not appear in the final draft. Notes applying to the entirety of the document follow. General: go through [1] and [3], ensure that all useful requirements and informative text are retained somewhere.
    [Show full text]