A Reappraisal Using a Composite Indicator of Patent Quality∗

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Reappraisal Using a Composite Indicator of Patent Quality∗ Patterns of Innovation during the Industrial Revolution: a Reappraisal using a Composite Indicator of Patent Quality∗ Alessandro Nuvolari†a, Valentina Tartarib, and Matteo Trancheroc aScuola Superiore Sant'Anna, Pisa, Italy bCopenhagen Business School, Copenhagen, Denmark cHaas School of Business, UC Berkeley, USA August 5, 2019 Abstract We introduce a new bibliographic quality indicator for English patents granted in the period 1700-1850. The indicator is based on the visibility of each patent both in the contemporary legal and engineering literature and in modern authoritative works on the history of science and technology. The indicator permits to operationalize empirically the distinction between micro- and macroinventions. Our findings indicate that macroinventions did not exhibit any specific time clustering, while at the same time they were characterized by a labor-saving bias. These results suggest that Mokyr's and Allen's views of macroinventions, rather than conflicting, should be regarded as complementary. Keywords: Industrial Revolution; Patents; Macroinventions; Microinventions. JEL Code: N74, O31 ∗Acknowledgements: The authors want to thank Bart Verspagen, Tania Treibich, Abhishek Nagaraj, Sameer Srivas- tava, as well as participants to seminars at University C^oted'Azur, UNU-MERIT, Berkeley-Haas and to EMAEE 2019 at SPRU - University of Sussex for their helpful comments. We are indebted to Joel Mokyr, Ralf Meisenzahl, Morgane Louenan, Olivier Gergaud and Etienne Wasmer for sharing their data. The usual disclaimers apply. †Corresponding author: Alessandro Nuvolari, Scuola Superiore Sant'Anna, Pisa, Italy. Postal address: c/o Institute of Economics, Scuola Superiore Sant'Anna, Piazza Martiri 33, 56127, Pisa, Italy. E-mail: [email protected]. 1 1 Introduction Technical change has traditionally occupied a central place in the historiography of the Indus- trial Revolution. Not surprisingly, both contemporaries and historians have regarded technological progress as one of key-factors shaping the dramatic economic and social transformations taking place in England during XVIII and XIX centuries. This interest in technical change has resulted in a very rich qualitative literature which has provided detailed descriptions of technological advances both in a broad, comprehensive perspective (Landes 1969; Mokyr 1990; Trinder 2013) and at the level of spe- cific technologies, such as steam power (Hills, 1989), textiles (Hills, 1970) and iron production (Hyde, 1977). In this context, the distinction between microinventions and macroinventions originally proposed by Mokyr (1990) has established itself as a particularly useful notion for providing an insightful characterization of the patterns of technical change. In Mokyr's original formulation, microinventions are \[. ] small, incremental steps that improve, adapt and streamline existing techniques already in use, reducing costs, improving form and function, increasing durability, and reducing energy and raw material requirements", whereas macroinventions are \[. ] those inventions in which a radical new idea, without clear precedent, emerges more or less ab nihilo" (Mokyr 1990, p. 13). The distinction between micro- and macroinventions is intuitively appealing and is consistent with many qualitative accounts of the contours of technical change during the Industrial Revolution (Landes 1969; Mathias 1969). However, at closer inspection, the notions of microinventions and macroinventions appears of difficult empirical operationalization, especially if one is interested in reconstructions of broad patterns of technical change spanning more than one specific technology or industry. In this respect, an established tradition in economic history has resorted to patents to provide quantitative assessments of the rate and scope of technical change (Sullivan 1989, 1990; Khan and Sokoloff 1993). However, one of the well-known limitations of simple patent counts is that they do not take into account the different quality of the inventions in question (O'Brien et al., 1995), thus preventing a straightforward empirical identification of macroinventions. For modern patents, economists of innovation have addressed this issue by designing a number of indicators of patent quality based on the use of patent citations, geographical coverage (i.e., size of the patent family) and renewals (Van Zeebroeck, 2011). These indicators are not immediately applicable to the case of the English patent system during the Industrial Revolution. Remarkably, when writing The Lever of Riches in 1990, Mokyr pessimistically concluded that \[. ] patent statistics [in the Industrial 2 Revolution period] do not permit us to distinguish between radical and minor inventions" (Mokyr 1990, p. 82). In this paper, we introduce a new composite indicator of the quality of English patents for the period 1700-1850. Our indicator of patent quality is a substantial refinement of the bibliographic indicator proposed by Nuvolari and Tartari (2011) based on Bennet Woodcroft's Reference Index of Patents of Invention, 1617-1852. We construct our new composite indicator by complementing Woodcroft's Reference Index with information collected from a wide array of modern sources on the history of technology. These different sources of information concerning the quality of each individual patent are aggregated using the approach introduced by Lanjouw and Schankerman (2004). The resulting Bigliographic Composite Index (BCI) that we propose provides a reliable selection of the most revolutionary technological breakthroughs of the period, and we validate its reliability through extensive robustness checks. The integration of multiple sources allows the construction of an index of patent quality that provides the opportunity for a large-scale empirical operationalization of the notions of micro- and macroinventions, at least for the subset of patented inventions. In turn, this will lead us to reappraise a number of interpretative conjectures on the sources and effects of macro- and microinventions and on their interconnections (Allen 2009; Mokyr 2010; Crafts 2011; Allen 2018). We find evidence that the distinction between macro- and microinventions is supported by the patent evidence, with the series of macroinventions showing characteristics remarkably close to the original theorizing of Mokyr (1990). In particular, the series of macroinventions shows statistical properties that are consistent with a significant role of serendipity in determining their occurrence. Vice versa, microinventions tend to come after the appearance of major breakthroughs, and to be correlated with the economic cycle. We also document that macroinventions were characterized by a labor-saving bias which is consistent with the High Wage Economy interpretation of the Industrial Revolution proposed by Allen (2009). However, unlike what has been suggested by Allen (2009), macroinventions were not the result of the activities of \outsiders", that is inventors working in different industrial sectors. A detailed study of patents in mechanical engineering further allows to test speculations of the historical literature on the role of machine users in innovation (MacLeod and Nuvolari, 2009), which we find were mostly responsible of minor improvements. Our work is connected also to the ongoing efforts on the construction of indices of historical technological progress. In this field, one traditional approach has been the estimation of indices of labour productivity or TFP (Crafts and Harley 1992; Crafts 2014), which however are indirect measures of technical change, often based on fragile data, and fraught with difficulties (Nelson, 1973). 3 Our efforts are closer in spirit to the recent attempts to construct direct proxies of technical change pioneered by Alexopoulos (2011), who proposed an indicator based on the number of new book titles in different fields of technology, and Kelly et al. (2018), who employed textual analysis of US patent documents to develop a new index of patent quality that can be used as a measure of technological change.1 2 Literature review The English patent system did not undergo major changes from the adoption of the Statute of Monopolies in 1624 to the reform of 1852. This relative uniformity, coupled with the precise recording of the date and details of the patents granted, makes patents an invaluable source to investigate the dynamics of innovation during the Industrial Revolution (Sullivan 1989, 1990). Still, historical patent data suffer from several pitfalls that can make their use problematic (MacLeod, 1988). The first major limitation is that obviously not all inventions were patented (Nuvolari 2004; Moser 2005). But as aptly noted by Schmookler (1966), this should stimulate research efforts on in- dicators of unpatented inventions that can usefully integrate the patent evidence, rather than leading to a dismissal of patents as an insightful source. A second important issue is the heterogeneity of patents in terms of their technological and eco- nomic significance, i.e. what we can refer to as their relative \quality". This, of course, applies to modern patents as well (Scherer and Harhoff, 2000). However, the patent system of the time had some features that exacerbated this problem. The English system was one of registration and not of examination and this means that patents were not subjected to any systematic check concerning their novelty or relevance. Sometimes patents lacked technological feasibility altogether, as the relatively high number of \perpetual
Recommended publications
  • BXAO Cat 1971.Pdf
    SOUTHWESTERN AT OXFORD Britain in the Renaissance A Course of Studies in the Arts, Literature, History, and Philosophy of Great Britain. July 4 through August 15, 1971, University College, Oxford University. OFFICERS AND TUTORS President John Henry Davis, A.B., University of Kentucky; B.A. and M.A., Oxford University; Ph.D., University of Chicago. Dean Yerger Hunt Clifton, B.A., Duke University; M.A., University of Virginia; Ph.D., Trinity College, Dublin. Tutors George Marshall Apperson, Jr., B.S., Davidson College; B.D., Th.M., Th.D., Union Theological Seminary, Virginia. Mary Ross Burkhart, B.A., University of Virginia; M.A., University of Ten­ nessee. James William Jobes, B.A., St. John's College, Annapolis; Ph.D., University of Virginia. James Edgar Roper, B.A., Southwestern At Memphis; B.A. and M.A., Oxford University; M.A., Yale University. UNIVERSITY COLLEGE, OXFORD UNIVERSITY Master Redcliffe-Maud of Bristol, The Right Honorourable John Primatt Redcliffe, Baron, M.A. Dean John Leslie Mackie, M.A. Librarian Peter Charles Bayley, M.A. Chaplain David John Burgess, M.A. Domestic Bursar Vice Admiral Sir Peter William Gretton, M.A. University College is officially a Royal Foundation, and the Sovereign is its Visitor. Its right to this dignity, based on medieval claims that it was founded by King Alfred the Great, has twice been asserted, by King Richard II in 1380 and by the Court of King's Bench in 1726. In fact, the college owes its origin to William of Durham who died in 1249 and bequeathed 310 marks, the income from which was to be employed to maintain 10 or more needy Masters of Arts studying divinity.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity Revisited
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity Revisited Volume Author/Editor: Josh Lerner and Scott Stern, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-47303-1; 978-0-226-47303-1 (cloth) Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/lern11-1 Conference Date: September 30 - October 2, 2010 Publication Date: March 2012 Chapter Title: The Rate and Direction of Invention in the British Industrial Revolution: Incentives and Institutions Chapter Authors: Ralf R. Meisenzahl, Joel Mokyr Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c12364 Chapter pages in book: (p. 443 - 479) 9 The Rate and Direction of Invention in the British Industrial Revolution Incentives and Institutions Ralf R. Meisenzahl and Joel Mokyr 9.1 Introduction The Industrial Revolution was the fi rst period in which technological progress and innovation became major factors in economic growth. There is by now general agreement that during the seventy years or so traditionally associated with the Industrial Revolution, there was little economic growth as traditionally measured in Britain, but that in large part this was to be expected.1 The sectors in which technological progress occurred grew at a rapid rate, but they were small in 1760, and thus their effect on growth was limited at fi rst (Mokyr 1998, 12– 14). Yet progress took place in a wide range of industries and activities, not just in cotton and steam. A full description of the range of activities in which innovation took place or was at least attempted cannot be provided here, but inventions in some pivotal industries such as iron and mechanical engineering had backward linkages in many more traditional industries.
    [Show full text]
  • Industrial Biography
    Industrial Biography Samuel Smiles Industrial Biography Table of Contents Industrial Biography.................................................................................................................................................1 Samuel Smiles................................................................................................................................................1 PREFACE......................................................................................................................................................1 CHAPTER I. IRON AND CIVILIZATION..................................................................................................2 CHAPTER II. EARLY ENGLISH IRON MANUFACTURE....................................................................16 CHAPTER III. IRON−SMELTING BY PIT−COAL−−DUD DUDLEY...................................................24 CHAPTER IV. ANDREW YARRANTON.................................................................................................33 CHAPTER V. COALBROOKDALE IRON WORKS−−THE DARBYS AND REYNOLDSES..............42 CHAPTER VI. INVENTION OF CAST STEEL−−BENJAMIN HUNTSMAN........................................53 CHAPTER VII. THE INVENTIONS OF HENRY CORT.........................................................................60 CHAPTER VIII. THE SCOTCH IRON MANUFACTURE − Dr. ROEBUCK DAVID MUSHET..........69 CHAPTER IX. INVENTION OF THE HOT BLAST−−JAMES BEAUMONT NEILSON......................76 CHAPTER X. MECHANICAL INVENTIONS AND INVENTORS........................................................82
    [Show full text]
  • The Growth of the Cotton Industry and Scottish Economic Development, 1780-1835
    THE GROWTH OF THE COTTON INDUSTRY AND SCOTTISH ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, 1780-1835 by ALEXANDER JAMES ROBERTSON M.A., University of Glasgow, 1963 A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF M.A. in the Department of History We accept this thesis as conforming to the required standard THE UNIVERSITY OF BRITISH COLUMBIA July, 1965. In presenting this thesis in partial fulfilment of .- the requirements for an advanced degree at the University of • British Columbia, I agree that the Library shall make it freely available for reference and study. I further agree that per• mission for extensive copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by the Head of my Department or by his representatives. It is understood that;copying or publi• cation of this thesis.for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission* Department of History The University of British Columbia, Vancouver 8, Canada Date 26th July, 1965. THE GROWTH OF THE COTTON INDUSTRY AND SCOTTISH ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, 1780-1835. ABSTRACT This study is intended, first of all, to be an examination of the growth of the cotton industry in Scotland from 176*0 to 1835. During this period, it became the largest and most important sector of the Scottish industrial economy, producing over 70% of the country's exports by value. There is, however, a subsidiary problem, that of placing the industry's growth within the general context of Scottish economic development in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. The choice of terminal dates was to some extent dictated by the availability of material.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rate and Direction of Invention in the British Industrial Revolution: Incentives and Institutions
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE RATE AND DIRECTION OF INVENTION IN THE BRITISH INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION: INCENTIVES AND INSTITUTIONS Ralf Meisenzahl Joel Mokyr Working Paper 16993 http://www.nber.org/papers/w16993 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 April 2011 Prepared for the 50th anniversary conference in honor of The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, ed. Scott Stern and Joshua Lerner. The authors acknowledge financial support from the Kauffman Foundation and the superb research assistance of Alexandru Rus. The opinions expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2011 by Ralf Meisenzahl and Joel Mokyr. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Rate and Direction of Invention in the British Industrial Revolution: Incentives and Institutions Ralf Meisenzahl and Joel Mokyr NBER Working Paper No. 16993 April 2011 JEL No. N13,N73,O31,O34,O43 ABSTRACT During the Industrial Revolution technological progress and innovation became the main drivers of economic growth. But why was Britain the technological leader? We argue that one hitherto little recognized British advantage was the supply of highly skilled, mechanically able craftsmen who were able to adapt, implement, improve, and tweak new technologies and who provided the micro inventions necessary to make macro inventions highly productive and remunerative.
    [Show full text]
  • Wealth, Waste, and Alienation: Growth and Decline in the Connellsville Coke Industry
    1 The Foundations of the Industry The Nature, Use, and Early Development of Coke in the United States Coke is the residue produced when great heat is applied to coal kept out of direct contact with air. The process is conducted either by cov- ering the coal with a more or less impermeable layer or, more effec- tively, by enclosing it in an oven. Volatiles are driven off, leaving a product that is largely carbon. There are various types of coke. That made as a byproduct of gas production is derived from coals fairly high in volatiles and is rapidly processed in retorts at relatively low temperatures. The resulting coke is dull, spongy, and burns readily. In contrast, low-volatile coals produce insufficient gas to complete the coking process. Between these extremes are the so-called caking coals. “Burned” at higher temperature and with a long continued heat, the best caking coals—which should also have only a low ash and sulfur content—produce a coke much harder and denser than gas coke, a coke that is strong, fibrous, and silver-gray in color and has a semi- metallic luster. Its hardness means it is resistant to abrasion and therefore free from fine particles. This kind of coke is porous, its structure vesicular—that is, having minute holes formed by the release of the gases that it once contained. Because it is admirably suited for use as a fuel in furnaces provided with a strong draught, this product of a limited, special group of coals with these highly distinc- tive properties and striking appearance is known as metallurgical coke.
    [Show full text]
  • Blast Furnace
    Blast furnace From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia Jump to: navigation, search Blast furnace in Sestao, Spain. The actual furnace itself is inside the centre girderwork. A blast furnace is a type of metallurgical furnace used for smelting to produce metals, generally iron. In a blast furnace, fuel and ore are continuously supplied through the top of the furnace, while air (sometimes with oxygen enrichment) is blown into the bottom of the chamber, so that the chemical reactions take place throughout the furnace as the material moves downward. The end products are usually molten metal and slag phases tapped from the bottom, and flue gases exiting from the top of the furnace. Blast furnaces are to be contrasted with air furnaces (such as reverberatory furnaces), which were naturally aspirated, usually by the convection of hot gases in a chimney flue. According to this broad definition, bloomeries for iron, blowing houses for tin, and smelt mills for lead, would be classified as blast furnaces. However, the term has usually been limited to those used for smelting iron ore to produce pig iron, an intermediate material used in the production of commercial iron and steel. Contents [hide] • 1 History o 1.1 China o 1.2 Ancient World elsewhere o 1.3 Medieval Europe o 1.4 Early modern blast furnaces: origin and spread o 1.5 Coke blast furnaces o 1.6 Modern furnaces • 2 Modern process • 3 Chemistry • 4 See also • 5 References o 5.1 Notes o 5.2 Bibliography • 6 External links [edit] History Blast furnaces existed in China from about the 5th century BC, and in the West from the High Middle Ages.
    [Show full text]
  • Energy Management of Stove in Pig-Iron Plant
    IOSR Journal of Mechanical and Civil Engineering (IOSR-JMCE) ISSN: 2278-1684, PP: 48-51 www.iosrjournals.org Energy Management of Stove in Pig-Iron Plant 1, 1 Pankaj R.Pardeshi Prof .Dr.B.S.Kothavale 1,2 Department of Mechanical Engineering, MIT College Of Engineering,Kothrud Pune-411038,India. ABSTRACT: A study was conducted in one of the pig iron plant to prime objective explore potential for energy saving. A detailed technical study on the site measurement were conducted the detailed energy & material balance of entire pig-iron production process presented in the paper. This paper describes the model- based control and estimation techniques for energy management of stove and blower house in pig- iron plant. This estimated parameter is then used by the model based controller to determine the minimum fuel required for subsequent regenerative cycle. The stove is regenerative type recuperater and uses the gas from blast furnace to stove to generate heated gas. In case of blower house the plant use the blower house building which energy consumption is very high as compare to out-put of blowing air to stove. This paper gives the energy management about the blower house and also reduces the losses in pig-iron plant. That energy management improves the production capacity. Keywords - 3- Phase power meter, Single phase power meter, Anemometer, Ultrasonic Non- Contact flow meter, Data control system (SCADA) I. INTRODUCTION A blast furnace is used to produce molten iron oxides, coke and flux. One of the major sources of energy for this process is the sensible heat coming from the preheated air, referred to as blast air that is injected into the furnace.
    [Show full text]
  • Scottish Industrial History Vol 5.2 1982
    SCOTTISH INDUSTRIAL OF DOCKS. l L K A - - J-" , ~ ; . :! / ln~·h - $Vr1 Fr tr ~ . ~-"""' .~rr f e ¥ 'nl .Jijf' «fJ JW ~--- ____!!IV l'rrt . ] n ~h - /6" .l•~ r• t-. 2{' =!' _ ________!!' Florl. • Volume 5.2 1982 S C 0 T T I S B I N D U S T R I A L B I S T 0 R Y Volmne 5.2 1982 Scottish Industri£1 History is published twice annually by the Scot­ tish Society for Industrial History, the Scottish Society for the Preserv­ ation of Historical Machinery and the Business Archives Council of Scotland. The editors are: Mrs S. Clack, Paisley; Dr C.W. Munn, University of Glasgow; and Mr A.T. Wilson, University of Glasgow. The typescript was prepared by Mr D. MacLauchlan, University of Glasgow and proof-read by Mr M. Livingstone, Business Archives Council of Scotland. The cover illustration shows a plan of Methil Dock (from Minutes ..Qt Proceedings ..Qt ~ Institute ..Qt ~ Engineers, vol. CXCI, 1912-13, part one). 1 S C 0 T T I S H I N D U S T R I A L H I S T 0 R Y Volume 5.2 1982 Contents Scottish salt making in the 18th century: a regional survey Christopher A. Whatley 2 The Iron industry of the Monklands: an introduction George Thomson 27 Randolph Wemyss and the development of Methil as a coal port ran Russell 42 Society News 52 Summary of lists of archive surveys and deposits 55 Book rwi~s 74 2 SCOTTISH SALT MAKING IN THE 18TH CENTORY: A REGIONAL SURVEYl by Christopher A.
    [Show full text]
  • Leyland Historical Society
    LEYLAND HISTORICAL SOCIETY (Founded 1968) Registered Charity No. 1024919 PRESIDENT Mr. W. E. Waring CHAIR VICE-CHAIR Mr. P. Houghton (Joint) Mr E. Almond and Mr. M. J. Park HONORARY SECRETARY HONORARY TREASURER Mr. M. J. Park Mr. E. Almond Tel: 01772 337258 AIMS To promote an interest in history generally and that of the Leyland area in particular MEETINGS Held on the first Monday of each month (September to July inclusive) at 7.30 pm in The Shield Room, Banqueting Suite, Civic Centre, West Paddock, Leyland SUBSCRIPTIONS Vice Presidents: £12.00 per annum Members: £12.00 per annum School Members: £1.00 per annum Casual Visitors: £3.00 per meeting A MEMBER OF THE LANCASHIRE LOCAL HISTORY FEDERATION THE HISTORIC SOCIETY OF LANCASHIRE AND CHESHIRE and THE BRITISH ASSOCIATION FOR LOCAL HISTORY Visit the Leyland Historical Society's Web Site at: http//www.leylandhistoricalsociety.co.uk Editorial Welcome to the fifty-eighth edition of the Lailand Chronicle. The year 2012 has been a year of celebration in our capital city, our neighbouring city of Preston and our town of Leyland. It was a year in which we celebrated our monarch’s Diamond Jubilee during an CONTENTS extended week-end in June; then came the the London 2012 Olympic and Paraplegic Games taking place in July and August. The Guild Editorial 3 celebrations in Preston were held at the end of August and our own revamped Leyland Festival took place in September having been Society Affairs 4 rescheduled from July because of wet weather Peter Houghton conditions. The wet weather itself is making headlines as this year is being recorded as the Historical Fact, Fiction and 7 wettest in the last one hundred years.
    [Show full text]
  • HISTORY of REVOLUTIONS and ERA of COLONIALISM (2014 Admission Onwards)
    UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION III SEMESTER B.A HISTORY: COMPLEMENTARY SOCIAL AND CULTURAL HISTORY OF BRITAIN: HIS3C03 HISTORY OF REVOLUTIONS AND ERA OF COLONIALISM (2014 Admission onwards) Multiple-Choice Questions and Answers Prepared by Dr.N.PADMANABHAN Associate Professor&Head P.G.Department of History C.A.S.College, Madayi P.O.Payangadi-RS-670358 Dt.Kannur-Kerala 0 1. The Glorious Revolution is the name given to a series of events that took place in the late 17th century in................... a) England b) France c) America d) Holland 2. Through the Restoration, ………………became the king of England. a) Charles II b) Robert Owen c)James I d)James II 3……………….., an avowed Catholic and believer of the Devine Right, like previous Stuart kings, came into throne in 1685. a) James II b) Robert Owen c) John Russell d) ) Charles II 4. In………………., a revolution without bloodshed took place against James II’s activities. a) 1688 b)1693 c)1694 d)1697 5.The main cause behind the Glorious revolution was ………………attempt to revive Catholicism in England. a) James II’s b) Robert Owens c) John Russell’s d) Charles II’s 6.In 1686, …………….founded the “Court of Ecclesiastical Commission” like previous ‘High Commission Court’ (cancelled in 1641) in order to punish the people, opposite to his religious doctrine. a) James II b)Sir Isaac Newton c) Elias Howe d) Thomas Edison 7.In 1687, …………….issued the first ‘Declaration of Indulgence’ suspending the penal laws against both Catholics and Dissenters. a) James II b)G.M.
    [Show full text]
  • Chemical Glasgow and Its Chemical Entrepreneurs, 1760–1860
    MAX-PLANCK-INSTITUT FÜR WISSENSCHAFTSGESCHICHTE Max Planck Institute for the History of Science 2015 PREPRINT 472 John R. R. Christie Chemistry through the ‘Two Revolutions’: Chemical Glasgow and its Chemical Entrepreneurs, 1760–1860 Chemistry through the ‘Two Revolutions’: Chemical Glasgow and its Chemical Entrepreneurs, 1760-1860* John R. R. Christie University of Oxford Introduction The principal focus of this essay, the town of Glasgow and the chemical works of St. Rollox, is local, but has a general resonance, for St. Rollox has at times been regarded as a paradigmatic case of industrialized chemical production within the encompassing orbit of the Industrial Revolution. Here, inarguably it seems, are to be found the kinds of research-based, knowledge-induced technical innovation, entrepreneurship, growth rates, scale transformations, employment and wage patterns, which allow assimilation to some or other historiographical normativity of industrialization, at least in British terms. One may note in passing here, that although St. Rollox’ development is known well enough in outline, and with some quantified information, this is not known directly from archives of company records, or from any detailed history of the company, for few such records, if they still exist, are currently available to the historian.1 Information is derived rather from sources such as the New Statistical Account of Scotland, and other contemporary observers.2 Some informal local or parish histories, and biographical and family- history treatments of the two principal figures of the early history of St. Rollox, Charles Tennant and Charles Macintosh are also useful. The most recent and conceptually sophisticated, albeit relatively brief treatment of St.
    [Show full text]