Dismantling Digital Deregulation: Toward a National Broadband Strategy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Dismantling Digital Deregulation: Toward a National Broadband Strategy DISMANTLING DIGITAL DEREGULATION: TOWARD A NATIONAL BROADBAND STRATEGY By S. Derek Turner DISMANTLING DIGITAL DEREGULATION: TOWARD A NATIONAL BROADBAND STRATEGY TABLE OF CONTENTS THE REVOLUTION WILL NOT BE STREAMED 5 Abandoning the Commitment to Competition 7 The FCC’s Premature Deregulation 9 Making Up for Lost Time: A National Broadband Plan 10 DEFINING AMERICA’S BROADBAND PROBLEM 14 The American Decline 15 The U.S. Duopoly Fails to Deliver 19 The Digital Divide Persists as Broadband Becomes an Essential Service 23 Why Some States Are Falling Behind in Broadband Adoption 25 America’s Broadband Failures Are the Result of Policy Failures 27 AMERICA’S BROADBAND PROBLEM: COMPETITION 28 The Computer Inquiries and Competition Policy 30 From Computer II to the 1996 Telecom Act 32 Implementing and Undermining the 1996 Telecom Act 33 The Rest of the World Takes a Different Path 37 Cable TV and the Beginning of the End of Broadband Competition 39 The FCC Kills the Commitment to Competition 42 Platform Competition: Always Right Around the Corner 47 The FCC’s Blindness to Abuses of Market Power 52 FCC Endorses Monopoly Power in the Middle-Mile and Special Access Markets 55 The FCC’s Premature Deregulation of the High-Capacity Broadband Market 59 AMERICA’S BROADBAND PROBLEM: OPENNESS 62 Nondiscrimination and Content Control 63 The FCC Abandons Openness 65 The Early Network Neutrality Debate 68 The Evolution of the Network Neutrality Debate 71 The Case Against Comcast 73 Net Neutrality and the Need for a Fifth Principle 75 Dealing with Managed Services 77 Getting Back to Basics: Preserving the Open Internet Should Be a Top Priority 79 www.freepress.net 2 DISMANTLING DIGITAL DEREGULATION: TOWARD A NATIONAL BROADBAND STRATEGY AMERICA’S BROADBAND PROBLEM: ACCESS 81 Universal Service Policy at a Crossroads 83 Defining Universal Service: History and Rationale 84 1934 to 1996: Monopolies and Cross-Subsidies 84 Universal Service and the Telecommunications Act of 1996 86 Competition and Universal Service: Congress Moves to Explicit Subsidies 87 Implementing the 1996 Act 88 Current Status of Universal Service and Impetus for Reform 90 Universal Service and Broadband 91 Leaping Forward: A New Approach to Universal Service 92 The High Cost Fund 93 The Current Distribution of High Cost Funds 95 Modernizing the High Cost Fund for Broadband 101 Distributing the Broadband Deployment High Cost Fund 103 The Role of Mobile Wireless Telephony 105 The FCC Must Not Place USF Contribution Burdens on Residential Broadband Connections 106 Lifeline/Link Up for Broadband: What Is the Likely Impact? 106 Ending the Stalemate at the Commission 109 TOWARD A NATIONAL BROADBAND POLICY: 111 SOLVING AMERICA’S BROADBAND PROBLEM 111 Policies For Success: Developing a National Broadband Plan 113 Getting the Act Back on Track: Protecting the Internet as an Open Platform for Innovation 11 4 Getting the Act Back on Track: Achieving Universal Service 11 6 Getting the Act Back on Track: Developing a Meaningful Competition Standard 11 7 Getting the Act Back on Track: Properly Classifying Broadband 11 8 Getting the Act Back on Track: Using Section 706 to Promote Competition 11 9 Getting the Act Back on Track: Promoting Platform Competition 120 Conclusion 122 www.freepress.net 3 DISMANTLING DIGITAL DEREGULATION: TOWARD A NATIONAL BROADBAND STRATEGY FIGURES Figure 1: The Decline in U.S. Broadband Penetration 16 Figure 2: Leaders in Absolute Growth in Broadband Penetration 17 Figure 3: Price, Speed and Value of Broadband Connections 18 Figure 4: Broadband Penetration vs. Price 19 Figure 5: Top U.S. Broadband Providers 20 Figure 6: U.S. Broadband Market Duopoly 21 Figure 7: U.S. Broadband Speeds 22 Figure 8: U.S. Residential Broadband Speeds 23 Figure 9: Economic Digital Divide 24 Figure 10: Racial/Ethnic Digital Divide 24 Figure 11: Geographic Digital Divide 25 Figure 12: Household Broadband Adoption vs. Median Income 25 Figure 13: Household Broadband Adoption vs. Poverty 26 Figure 14: Household Broadband Adoption vs. Percent of Rural Population 26 Figure 15: The Best and Worst U.S. States in Broadband Adoption 27 Figure 16: Broadband Penetration and Open Access Policy 38 Figure 17: Broadband Price and Open Access Policy 38 Figure 18: Broadband Value and Open Access Policy 39 Figure 19: Earthlink on Time Warner Cable 45 Figure 20: The Decline of Earthlink and Covad 46 Figure 21: The Duopoly U.S. Broadband Market 48 Figure 22: No Indication of Mobile Broadband Supplanting Fixed Broadband 49 Figure 23: The Slow Performance of 3G Mobile Broadband 49 Figure 24: Percent of End-User Premises Without Broadband Deployment 49 Figure 25: Current Top U.S. States without Broadband Deployment 50 Figure 26: Top U.S. States without DSL Deployment in June 2005 50 Figure 27: DSL Adoption and Wholesale Access Policy 51 Figure 28: The Slow Death of CLECs 52 Figure 29: Special Access Runaway Rate of Returns 57 Figure 30: Top 10 Study Areas with Highest Special Access Rate of Returns 58 Figure 31: A Broken Regulatory System: Runaway Rate of Returns 58 Figure 32: Recoverable Interstate Investment and Returns 59 Figure 33: The Current USF Support Model 89 Figure 34: USF Disbursements by Program 90 Figure 35: Percentage of USF by Program 90 Figure 36: USF Contribution Base vs. Contribution Factor 91 Figure 37: High Cost Fund Disbursements 94 Figure 38: High-Cost Support: ILECs vs. CLECs 95 Figure 39: High Cost Fund Support by Program and Study Area Type 96 Figure 40: Per Line Monthly High Cost Fund Support by Program 97 Figure 41: Per Line Monthly High Cost Fund Support By Program and Study Area Type 97 Figure 42: Per Line Monthly High Cost Fund Support by Cost - All Carriers 99 Figure 43: Per Line Monthly High Cost Fund Support By Cost and Study Area Type 100 Figure 44: Current Participation in the Lifeline Program 107 Figure 45: Adoption of Internet by Low-Income Households 107 Figure 46: Potential Cost and Impact of a Broadband Lifeline Program 109 www.freepress.net 4 DISMANTLING DIGITAL DEREGULATION: TOWARD A NATIONAL BROADBAND STRATEGY CHAPTER 1 THE REVOLUTION WILL NOT BE STREAMED www.freepress.net 5 DISMANTLING DIGITAL DEREGULATION: TOWARD A NATIONAL BROADBAND STRATEGY INTRODUCTION: THE PROMISE OF THE INTERNET On a cold February morning 13 years ago, President Bill Clinton made history by signing the Telecommunications Act of 1996 into law. It was the first signing at the Library of Congress and the first to be streamed live over the Internet.1 This symbolism was intended to capture the legislation’s promise of bringing the information revolution to the doorstep of every American. As President Clinton signed a bill he described as “truly revolutionary” and that would “protect consumers against monopolies,” he spoke of the future the law would bring. “Soon, working parents will be able to check up on their children in class via computer,” he said. “On a rainy Saturday night, you’ll be able to order up every movie ever produced or every symphony ever created in a minute’s time.”2 Americans are still waiting on the promise of this digital revolution. The story of how this digital promise was broken is a tale of typical Washington politics. Before the ink was even dry on the 1996 Act, the powerful media and telecommunications giants and their army of overpaid lobbyists went straight to work obstructing and undermining the competition the new law was intended to create. By the dawn of the 21st century, what they could not get overturned in the courts was gladly undone by a new FCC staffed and led by the same lobbyists. Instead of “protection against monopolies,” consumers have been left with high prices, few choices and a duopoly of cable and phone companies. Instead of “every American child” being connected, today we have more than 20 million school-age kids without home Internet connections. And instead of every American being able to order up a movie in “a minute’s time,” today less than 5 percent of Americans have a home Internet connection capable of downloading a movie in less than 30 minutes.3 Worst of all, the promise of the Internet as a democracy-enhancing, free-flowing communications conduit is now in serious jeopardy.4 But this story actually begins long before the 1996 Act came into being. It begins nearly half a century ago, during a time when the network computing industry was in its infancy and the nation’s communications market was still a government-sanctioned monopoly. In the 1960s, the Federal Communications Commission began to craft a regulatory structure that would allow the Internet to grow and thrive as an open and competitive communications platform. The FCC established a bold series of safeguards through the so-called Computer Inquiries that would protect competition on the Internet from the monopoly whims of the phone companies that owned and controlled the Internet’s infrastructure. This regulatory structure was remarkably 1 See Mike Mills, “Ushering in a New Age in Communications; Clinton Signs ‘Revolutionary’ Bill into Law at a Ceremony Packed with Symbolism,” Washington Post, Feb. 9, 1996. 2 See “Remarks by the President in Signing Ceremony for the Telecommunications Act Conference Report,” The White House Of- fice of the Press Secretary, Feb. 8, 1996. 3 See infra Figure 8, explaining that only 4 percent of U.S. households subscribe to broadband connections with advertised speeds above 10 megabits per second. 4 At the 1996 Act’s signing ceremony, President Clinton said: “It is fitting that we mark this moment here in the Library of Con- gress. It is Thomas Jefferson’s building. ... He understood that democracy depends upon the free flow of information. … Today, the information revolution is spreading light, the light Jefferson spoke about, all across our land and all across the world.
Recommended publications
  • The US Experiment with Government Ownership of the Telephone
    University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law 4-1-2013 The Wires Go to War: The U.S. Experiment with Government Ownership of the Telephone System During World War I Michael A. Janson Federal Communications Commission Christopher S. Yoo University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Communications Law Commons, Economic History Commons, Legal History Commons, Other Business Commons, Policy History, Theory, and Methods Commons, Science and Technology Law Commons, and the United States History Commons Repository Citation Janson, Michael A. and Yoo, Christopher S., "The Wires Go to War: The U.S. Experiment with Government Ownership of the Telephone System During World War I" (2013). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law. 467. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/467 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Articles The Wires Go to War: The U.S. Experiment with Government Ownership of the Telephone System During World War I Michael A. Janson* & Christopher S. Yoo** One of the most distinctive characteristics of the U.S. telephone system is that it has always been privately owned, in stark contrast to the pattern of government ownership followed by virtually every other nation. What is not widely known is how close the United States came to falling in line with the rest of the world.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Telecom Meltdown for a Listing of Recent Titles in the Artech House Telecommunications Library, Turn to the Back of This Book
    The Great Telecom Meltdown For a listing of recent titles in the Artech House Telecommunications Library, turn to the back of this book. The Great Telecom Meltdown Fred R. Goldstein a r techhouse. com Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data A catalog record for this book is available from the U.S. Library of Congress. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data Goldstein, Fred R. The great telecom meltdown.—(Artech House telecommunications Library) 1. Telecommunication—History 2. Telecommunciation—Technological innovations— History 3. Telecommunication—Finance—History I. Title 384’.09 ISBN 1-58053-939-4 Cover design by Leslie Genser © 2005 ARTECH HOUSE, INC. 685 Canton Street Norwood, MA 02062 All rights reserved. Printed and bound in the United States of America. No part of this book may be reproduced or utilized in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, recording, or by any information storage and retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher. All terms mentioned in this book that are known to be trademarks or service marks have been appropriately capitalized. Artech House cannot attest to the accuracy of this information. Use of a term in this book should not be regarded as affecting the validity of any trademark or service mark. International Standard Book Number: 1-58053-939-4 10987654321 Contents ix Hybrid Fiber-Coax (HFC) Gave Cable Providers an Advantage on “Triple Play” 122 RBOCs Took the Threat Seriously 123 Hybrid Fiber-Coax Is Developed 123 Cable Modems
    [Show full text]
  • A Comment on Competition and Controversy in Local Telecommunications Howard A
    Hastings Law Journal Volume 50 | Issue 6 Article 7 1-1999 A Comment on Competition and Controversy in Local Telecommunications Howard A. Shelanski Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Howard A. Shelanski, A Comment on Competition and Controversy in Local Telecommunications, 50 Hastings L.J. 1617 (1999). Available at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal/vol50/iss6/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Hastings Law Journal by an authorized editor of UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. A Comment on Competition and Controversy in Local Telecommunications by HOWARD A. SHELANSKI* The principal goal of the Telecommunications Act of 1996 is to open the market for local telephone service to competition. So far, however, the statute has attracted headlines more for generating legal controversy than for creating economic competition. The disputes that have commanded such attention and colored public discussion of the Act involve, at their core, the Federal Communications Commission's interpretation of provisions requiring incumbent local carriers to make parts of their proprietary networks available for use by new entrants. While some observers blame litigation and non- compliance with these "network unbundling" provisions for delaying implementation of a generally sound piece of legislation,' others contend either that the FCC's implementation of the unbundling requirements is impermissible and onerous or that regulators have not gone far enough to help new competitors.2 Given the resources devoted to disputes over the Act, it would be easy to suppose, as a variety of commentators have,3 that the success of the 1996 Act depends on how courts and regulators resolve * Acting Professor of Law, University of California at Berkeley (on leave 1999-2000) and Chief Economist, Federal Communications Commission.
    [Show full text]
  • Federal Register/Vol. 86, No. 5/Friday, January 8, 2021/Rules
    1636 Federal Register / Vol. 86, No. 5 / Friday, January 8, 2021 / Rules and Regulations FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS at: https://docs.fcc.gov/public/ and resale requirements where they COMMISSION attachments/FCC-20-152A1.pdf. stifle technology transitions and broadband deployment, but preserve I. Introduction 47 CFR Part 51 unbundling requirements where they 1. The Telecommunications Act of are still necessary to realize the 1996 [WC Docket No. 19–308; FCC 20–152; FRS 1996 (the 1996 Act) changed the focus Act’s goal of robust intermodal 17221] of telecommunications law and policy competition benefiting all Americans. from the regulation of monopolies to the Modernizing Unbundling and Resale encouragement of robust intermodal II. Background Requirements in an Era of Next- competition. Few of its effects were as 4. The 1996 Act and implementing Generation Networks and Services consequential as ending the local Commission regulations imposed a exchange monopolies held by number of obligations on incumbent AGENCY: Federal Communications incumbent local exchange carriers LECs to promote competitive entry into Commission. (LECs) and opening local markets to the telecommunications marketplace, ACTION: Final rule. competition. To facilitate new entry into including obligations to unbundle the local exchange market, the 1996 Act network elements to other carriers on a SUMMARY: In this document, the imposed special obligations on rate-regulated basis and to offer Commission eliminates unbundling incumbent LECs, including telecommunications services for resale requirements, subject to reasonable requirements to offer these new on a rate-regulated basis. In the 24 years transition periods, for enterprise-grade competitive carriers unbundled network since the passage of the 1996 Act, the DS1 and DS3 loops here there is elements and retail telecommunications Commission has continually reviewed evidence of actual and potential services for resale, both on a rate- and, when warranted, reduced competition, for broadband-capable DS0 regulated basis.
    [Show full text]
  • Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C
    Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554 In the Matter of ) ) AT&T Petition to Launch a Proceeding ) GN Docket No. 12-353 Concerning the TDM-to-IP Transition, ) Petition of the National Telecommunications ) Cooperative Association for a Rulemaking ) to Promote and Sustain the Ongoing TDM-to-IP ) Evolution ) ) Policies and Rules ) Governing Retirement of Copper Loops ) RM-11358 By Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers ) ) Petition of XO Communications, LLC, ) Covad Communications Group, Inc., NuVox ) Communications and Eschelon Telecom, Inc. ) For a Rulemaking to Amend Certain Part 51 ) Rules Applicable to Incumbent LEC ) Retirements of Copper Loops and Copper ) Subloops ) __________________________________________) REPLY COMMENTS OF MPOWER COMMUNICATIONS CORP., U.S. TELEPACIFIC CORP., ACN COMMUNICATIONS SERVICES, INC., LEVEL 3 COMMUNICATIONS, LLC, TDS METROCOM, LLC, BLUE ROOSTER TELECOM, INC., IMPULSE TELECOM, LLC., RURAL BROADBAND NOW!, SONIC TELECOM, LLC, ALPHEUS COMMUNICATIONS, LLC, AND MEGAPATH CORPORATION Tamar E. Finn Joshua M. Bobeck Philip J. Macres Bingham McCutchen, LLP 2020 K St., NW Washington, DC 20006 (202) 373-6000 (tel) (202) 373-6001 (fax) [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Counsel for Mpower Communications Corp., U.S. TelePacific Corp., ACN Communications Services, Inc., Level 3 Communications, LLC, TDS Metrocom, LLC, Alpheus Communications, LLC, and MegaPath Corporation A/75459565 Jeff Buckingham, President Dave Clark, President Blue Rooster Telecom, Inc. Impulse Telecom, LLC P.O. Box 4959 5383 Hollister Avenue, Suite 240, San Luis Obispo, CA 93403 Santa Barbara, CA 93111 (805) 545-5100 (805) 456-5800 [email protected] [email protected] Michael Ireton, President Dane Jasper, Founder & CEO Rural Broadband Now! Sonic Telecom, LLC 111 S Main St.
    [Show full text]
  • Attachment A
    ATTACHMENT A Network Neutrality Rules in Comparative Perspective: A Relatively Limited Intervention in the Market January 2010 Prepared for : CCIA By: Kip Meek & Robert Kenny Ingenious Consulting Network 1 Contents 1. Executive Summary .......................................................................................................3 2. Regulatory objectives.....................................................................................................4 Promote universal service/ access ............................................................................4 Foster competitive markets ......................................................................................5 Promote public confidence and protect consumer rights ..........................................6 Encourage investment and innovation......................................................................7 Optimise use of scarce resources..............................................................................8 Minimise the burden and costs of regulation............................................................8 Ensure security of supply ..........................................................................................9 Non-US regulatory objectives .................................................................................10 Conclusion..............................................................................................................10 3. Regulatory approaches to bottlenecks .........................................................................11
    [Show full text]
  • Access and Interconnection Issues in the Move Towards the Full Liberalization of European Telecommunications Leonard W.H
    NORTH CAROLINA JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL LAW AND COMMERCIAL REGULATION Volume 23 | Number 1 Article 1 Fall 1997 Access and Interconnection Issues in the Move towards the Full Liberalization of European Telecommunications Leonard W.H. Ng Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.unc.edu/ncilj Recommended Citation Leonard W. Ng, Access and Interconnection Issues in the Move towards the Full Liberalization of European Telecommunications, 23 N.C. J. Int'l L. & Com. Reg. 1 (1997). Available at: http://scholarship.law.unc.edu/ncilj/vol23/iss1/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Carolina Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in North Carolina Journal of International Law and Commercial Regulation by an authorized editor of Carolina Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Access and Interconnection Issues in the Move towards the Full Liberalization of European Telecommunications Cover Page Footnote International Law; Commercial Law; Law This article is available in North Carolina Journal of International Law and Commercial Regulation: http://scholarship.law.unc.edu/ ncilj/vol23/iss1/1 Access and Interconnection Issues in the Move Towards the Full Liberalization of European Telecommunications Leonard W.H. Ngt I. Introduction ............................................................................ 2 II. The Meaning and Nature of Interconnection in the European Union ................................................................... 4 III. An Introduction to the Regulation of Access and Interconnection ................................................................... 7 IV. Competition Aspects of Access and Interconnection ...... 11 A. Analysis Under Article 86 ............................................. 11 1. Dominance of Telecommunications Organizations ...... 12 (a) The Relevant Product or Services Market ...... 13 (b) The Relevant Geographic Market .................... 15 (c) Determination of Dominance ..........................
    [Show full text]
  • Internet 3.0: Identifying Problems and Solutions to the Network Neutrality Debate
    International Journal of Communication 1 (2007), 461-492 1932-8036/20070461 Internet 3.0: Identifying Problems and Solutions to the Network Neutrality Debate ROB FRIEDEN Penn State University What Internet Service Providers (ISPs) can and cannot do to diversify and differentiate services lies at the core of the debate over neutrality in network operation. In prior generations ISPs had little incentive or technological capability to deviate from plain vanilla best efforts routing for content providers and from a single standard bit rate offered on “all you can eat” terms for consumer access to the World Wide Web. The next generation Internet has the technological capability and ISPs have the commercial motivation to offer “better than best efforts” routing and premium services for both content providers and consumers seeking higher quality of service and more reliable traffic delivery. However the potential exists for carriers, operating the major networks used to switch and route bitstreams, to go beyond satisfying diverse requirements of content provider and end users. Network neutrality advocates worry that major ISPs have both the wherewithal and incentive to bifurcate the Internet into one medium increasingly prone to congestion and declining reliability and one offering superior performance and potential competitive advantages to users able and willing to pay, or affiliated with an ISP operating a major bitstream transmission network such as AT&T, Verizon and Comcast. Opponents refuse to see a current or prospective problem and worry that network neutrality requirements legitimize common carrier regulation of the Internet, a regulatory regime heretofore limited to telecommunications services operating in a less than fully competitive environment.
    [Show full text]
  • Developments in Local Loop Unbundling”, OECD Digital Economy Papers, No
    Please cite this paper as: OECD (2003-06-02), “Developments in Local Loop Unbundling”, OECD Digital Economy Papers, No. 74, OECD Publishing, Paris. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/233065827862 OECD Digital Economy Papers No. 74 Developments in Local Loop Unbundling OECD Unclassified DSTI/ICCP/TISP(2002)5/FINAL Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 10-Sep-2003 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR SCIENCE, TECHNOLOGY AND INDUSTRY COMMITTEE FOR INFORMATION, COMPUTER AND COMMUNICATIONS POLICY Unclassified DSTI/ICCP/TISP(2002)5/FINAL Cancels & replaces the same document of 07 August 2003 Working Party on Telecommunication and Information Services Policies DEVELOPMENTS IN LOCAL LOOP UNBUNDLING English - Or. English JT00148819 Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format DSTI/ICCP/TISP(2002)5/FINAL FOREWORD This report was presented to the Working Party on Telecommunications and Information Services Policy (TISP) in June 2002 and was declassified by the Committee for Information, Computer and Communications Policy in March 2003. The report was prepared by Mr. Atsushi Umino of the OECD's Directorate for Science, Technology and Industry. It is published on the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. Copyright OECD, 2003 Applications for permission to reproduce or translate all or part of this material should be made to: Head of Publications Service, OECD, 2 rue André-Pascal, 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France. 2 DSTI/ICCP/TISP(2002)5/FINAL TABLE OF CONTENTS FOREWORD 2 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 4 I. LOCAL LOOP UNBUNDLING IN OECD COUNTRIES 6 1.1.
    [Show full text]
  • Did Mandatory Unbundling Achieve Its Purpose? Empirical Evidence from Five Countries
    MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02618 3696 * / N * UBKARES Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/didmandatoryunbuOOhaus y hb3i \msmy jy[415 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Did Mandatory Unbundling Achieve Its Purpose? Empirical Evidence from Five Countries Jerry Hausman Gregory Sidak Working Paper 04-40 Nov 1 , 2004 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://ssrn.com/abstract=623221 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY FEB 1 2005 LIBRARIES 1 Hausman Sidak Oxford vS 3:00 PM Eastern 11/08/04 Did Mandatory Unbundling Achieve Its Purpose? Empirical Evidence from Five Countries Jerry A. Hausmanf J. Gregory Sidakf t In this article, we examine the rationales offered by telecommunications regulators worldwide for pursuing mandatory unbundling. We begin by defining mandatory unbundling, with brief descriptions of different wholesale forms and different retail products. Next, we examine four major rationales for regulatory intervention of this kind: (I) competition in the form of lower prices and greater innovation in retail markets is desirable, (2) competition in retail markets cannot be achieved with mandatory unbundling, (3) mandatory unbundling enables future facilities-based investment ('stepping-stone' or 'ladder of investment' hypothesis), and (4) competition in wholesale access markets is desirable. We proceed by testing empirically the major rationales in the United States, the United Kingdom, New Zealand, Canada, and Germany. For each case study, we review the mandator}' unbundling experience with respect to retail pricing, investment, entry barriers, and wholesale competition.
    [Show full text]
  • Notice of Proposed Rulemaking – WC Docket No
    October 29, 2019 FACT SHEET* Modernizing Unbundling and Resale Rules in an Era of Next-Generation Networks and Services Notice of Proposed Rulemaking – WC Docket No. 19-308 Background: Before 1996, local telephone companies (known as incumbent local exchange carriers or LECs) held a monopoly on local telephone service. Congress passed the Telecommunications Act of 1996 to open these local markets to competition, requiring incumbent LECs to (1) unbundle and open their networks to competitors at cost-based rates, and (2) offer for resale at wholesale rates telecommunications services that the incumbent LEC offers at retail. At the same time, Congress also left it to the FCC to determine which network elements should be subject to unbundling and gave the FCC the authority to forbear from these obligations if they became no longer necessary in light of changes in the industry. Over the last 23 years, the communications marketplace has transformed, with robust intermodal voice and broadband competition in many areas of the country. This Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (Notice) would propose to update the FCC’s unbundling and resale rules to reflect these marketplace realities and to remove unnecessary regulatory burdens that can inhibit the deployment of, and transition to, next- generation networks. At the same time, recognizing that unbundling requirements may have continued benefits in providing broadband access to consumers where facilities-based competition is less likely to occur, the Notice would propose to maintain rules regarding mass
    [Show full text]
  • PHOENIX CENTER POLICY BULLETIN NO. 17 Page 1 of 18
    PHOENIX CENTER POLICY BULLETIN NO. 17 Page 1 of 18 PHOENIX CENTER POLICY BULLETIN NO. 17 George S. Ford, Ph.D. Thomas M. Koutsky, J.D. Lawrence J. Spiwak, J.D. April 2007 WIRELESS NET NEUTRALITY: FROM Carterfone TO CABLE BOXES Abstract: Over the past few months there have been calls to impose “wireless net neutrality” rules on the burgeoning United States wireless industry. These critics assert that certain practices by the wireless industry—such as handset “locking” practices, data bandwidth limitations, and control over features included on handsets—unduly hamper the ability of consumers to access and use advanced data communications services and, therefore, require severe regulatory intervention to protect consumers. To correct this perceived market defect, wireless network neutrality advocates essentially seek to turn highly sophisticated wireless telecommunications networks into commodity-based networks. In support of this proposal, wireless network neutrality advocates point to the Federal Communications Commission’s 1968 Carterfone decision and the more recent Cable Navigation Devices rules as examples in which the Commission has taken what they allege to be a similar regulatory approach for both the landline telephone and video programming distribution market. In this BULLETIN we show that neither the mandates of, nor conditions relevant to, Carterfone and the Cable Navigation Devices decisions appear to support the regulatory intervention sought by the wireless network neutrality advocates. Indeed, the Carterfone and Cable Navigation Devices decisions appear to decidedly call for a rejection of the recent proposals for wireless network neutrality. We also discuss the substantial risks that Carterfone-type regulation would commoditize wireless network services in a way that could substantially harm the prospects for entry and competition in the industry.
    [Show full text]