Gian Rinaldo Carli (1720-1795): a Remarkable Early 'Money Doctor' [First Draft]

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Gian Rinaldo Carli (1720-1795): a Remarkable Early 'Money Doctor' [First Draft] Gian Rinaldo Carli (1720-1795): a remarkable early 'money doctor' [First draft] Gianfranco Tusset 1. Introduction “Some mathematicians maintained that money is like water, which flows and swirls around until it finds its equilibrium again: the matter is totally different, especially in Italy” (Carli 1751, 164-165). This quotation from one of Gian Rinaldo Carli’s main works, Dell’origine e del commercio delle monete e dei disordini che accadono nelle alterazioni di essa (Of the origin and trade of the coins and the disorders that occur in its alterations) (1751), clearly points to his focus on the conditions in which money circulates in order to guarantee the monetary equilibrium. Aim of this paper is to reconstruct the figure of Gian Rinaldo Carli, a monetarist economist who lived in the eighteenth-century, and whose work mirrored contradictions and strains that characterized the decades preceding the industrial burst. Belonging to a community of monetarist economists who enlivened a sort of golden age of the pre-classical studies on money, Carli stood out for is persistent focus on the need of guaranteeing monetary equilibrium, of intervening to assure conditions favorable to enlarge trade, at that time considered the main factor of growth. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 lingers over the eighteenth-century monetarist community as whole. Section 3 introduces some biographical notes on Gian Rinaldo Carli. Section 4 concerns the method Carli employed to deal with monetary topics. Section 5 presents the Carli's general view on monetary equilibrium. Section 6 reviews his researches on then increasing prices. Section 6 details threats to international monetary equilibrium and potential remedies. Section 7 concludes deepening the Carli’s proposal of money-doctor. 2. The reception of Galilean method Carli can be included among the Galilean economists, a label that require some explanation. Galileo occasionally wrote about economic topics, though they were certainly not particularly relevant, as demonstrated by the fact that economists quoted him for his methodology, not for his economic insights. The sole exception lies in the dilemma concerning the utility and value of diamonds and water, which Galileo considered long before Smith. Sagredo, one of the three known protagonists of Galileo’s Dialogue, blames vulgar people for considering silver and gold precious, and viewing land and mud as base elements, failing to realize that any prince would spend diamonds and rubies to buy land if it were in short supply. Galileo was aware that scarcity was the main cause behind value, and consequently behind prices too: “Abundance degrades things” (1632, p. 256). The problems of value, particularly of the metals used to make money, also attracted the attention of most of the Italian economists of that time: Geminiano Montanari (1633-1687), Gian Rinaldo Carli (1720-1795), Ferdinando Galiani (1728-1797), Cesare Beccaria (1738-1794), Pietro Verri (1728- 1797), and Giambattista Vasco (1733-1796); we can also add two economists who lived in Galileo’s time, Bernardo Davanzati (1509-1606) and Gasparo Scaruffi (1519-84). University of Padua. For correspondence: [email protected] 1 These economists tentatively termed here Galilean because they belonged to scientific circles and academies (the Accademia del Cimento, Accademia dei Pugni, among others) that explicitly followed the great physicist’s method and teachings. The fil rouge linking those circles was their rejection of the approach of Aristotle and the Scholastics, which was abstractly replaced by an experimental method never thoroughly defined when referred to human sciences. It is not easy to sketch the ideal type of Galilean economist, however. What exactly characterizes such an economist? Simply having rejected the Scholastic approach certainly was not enough. The idea of scientific rigor was important but needed to be contextualized. It took several decades for the traits of this ideal type of economist to become apparent.1 A careful reading of these economists’ contributions, which focused mainly on monetary topics, can provide some clarification. On the one hand, Galileo’s rigor was often invoked to justify the adoption of a geometrical method in dealing with practical problems. On the other, Galileo’s imprint was detectable when an economist tried to introduce some primitive form of algorithm to deal with monetary and more generally economic problems. The use of algorithms suggests some mechanism for solving economic problems that avoids the need for any type of moral or ethical, or simply individual, discretionary choice. Evidence of this trait could be seen in the objectivity of Galilean economists’ analyses, and their exclusion of any moral or political considerations. The above idea of an early algorithm emerges more clearly when referred to monetary topics. Quantitative ratios between coins and money represented a first step. It was not true arithmetic applied to monetary relationships, but Carli, Montanari, Scaruffi, Beccaria and Galiani clearly developed their analyses with data and quantitative ratios. Their proofs were built on quantitative demonstrations. Numbers inserted in the literary discourse enabled these economists to make their analyses quantitative and objective, helping them to evade any strictly moral assessments. Was this a legacy of Galileo’s increasingly well-known approach? Not exactly. Certainly, the changing scientific climate drove these authors to make more and more use of data, but this practice seems to have made its appearance even before Galileo’s time. Davanzati’s monetary analysis is proof of this: he may not have employed data in the same was as Carli did later on, but Davanzati undeniably used a quantitative approach. Gasparo Scaruffi also produced a numerical representation of monetary exchanges. Galileo’s message probably accelerated the use of data in monetary analysis, but it would have happened anyway. Galileo’s insistence on the need for scientific rigor and applied mathematics actually favored the encounter between the monetary approach based on pure mathematics and geometry on the one hand, and the commercial use of calculation and numbering on the other. After Galileo, it no longer made sense to distinguish between pure and applied mathematics when referring to monetary studies. The above monetarist economists sought mathematical rigor by taking a concrete, practical approach. Galilean economics grew from the combination of pure mathematics and geometry with calculations applied to technical and practical issues. In this scientific environment, the approach to monetary issues took a political dimension, it was clearly recognized that the management of money was object of princes and governments, of policy, we would say nowadays. 1 For a more detailed analysis of this label, Galilean economists, see Tusset 2018. 2 A visual representation of monetarist economists Figure 1 shows the words characterizing the main works of six monetarist economists who can be considered as “Galilean” in the sense described above. Beside Carli, we can find: Bernardo Davanzati, Geminiano Montanari, Ferdinando Galiani, Cesare Beccaria, and Giambattista Vasco. The figure was obtained using correspondence analysis to emphasize the words relatively most often used in the main works of the above-mentioned economists.2 The linguistic variance was not very high (see values of inertia on the horizontal and vertical axes), meaning that these economists all discussed similar (monetary) issues, and used similar concepts in their analyses. On the other, both the horizontal (25.02%) and the vertical (22.58%) variances suffice to highlight some differences between these economists, though they followed much the same trend. Considering their lexicon, the figure can be divided into four parts, with Ferdinando Galiani placed in the first quadrant, where the markers of his work on money are nonetheless clearly visible: the terms “moral”, “justice”, “rich”, “unfair”, “virtuous”, “virtue”, “usury”, and “usurers” emphasize his ethical conception of value. Moving counterclockwise, Montanari and Davanzati, in the quadrant II, speak about money too, but they stand apart for their use of words referring to the condition of individuals: “useful”, “wishes”, “families”, “equilibrate”, and “happy”, among others. Montanari cannot move too far away from Davanzati, his acknowledged theoretical reference point. Montanari’s studies and works have frequently led him to be associated with Galileo, but in dealing with monetary topics, he went his own way, emphasizing a subjective approach to monetary analysis that makes his texts distinctive from those of other authors. The distance that separates him from Aristotle is also shorter than in the case of other economists. Continuing, we find Carli in the quadrant III. Words such as “seigniorage,” “equilibrium,” “balancing,” “disorder,” “manipulation,” “governments,” “pestilence,” and “eroded” show his interest in the depreciation characterizing the money in circulation. The aggregate phenomenon is represented here by the declared value of coins, which did not correspond to their real value. Political distortions lie behind this phenomenon, which cannot be brought down to a specific cause. 2 The vocabulary represented in a scatterplot that “can be regarded as a map, because the position of each [economist] can be regarded as a two-dimensional position, almost like a geographical location in a region defined by latitude and longitude.
Recommended publications
  • Money, Finance and Crisis. Marx Within the Monetary Circuit
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Money, finance and crisis. Marx within the monetary circuit Veronese Passarella, Marco LUBS, University of Leeds 2013 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/68507/ MPRA Paper No. 68507, posted 23 Dec 2015 20:39 UTC Moneta, finanza e crisi. Marx nel circuito monetario Marco Veronese Passarella* Versione 5.0 - Ultima modifica 30 Luglio 2014 1. Introduzione: l’altro Marx Fin dalla pubblicazione postuma del Terzo Libro de Il Capitale, il dibattito “economi- co” attorno alla grande opera incompiuta di Karl Marx si è concentrato prevalentemente sul cosiddetto problema della trasformazione (dei valori-lavoro in prezzi di produzione), nonché sulla legge della caduta tendenziale del saggio del profitto. In altri termini, è so- prattutto sulla possibile frizione tra Primo Libro e (prima e terza sezione del) Terzo Li- bro che si è storicamente focalizzata l’attenzione dei più, dentro e fuori le mura acca- demiche. Per contro, ad eccezione dei capitoli finali dedicati agli schemi di riproduzio- ne,1 il Secondo Libro de Il Capitale è stato a lungo trascurato. Peggior sorte è toccata alla quinta sezione del Terzo Libro, dedicata al credito, al capitale fittizio ed al sistema bancario. In effetti, se l’analisi delle due forme – mercantile e capitalistica – della circo- lazione è stata solitamente sminuita a sorta di breve introduzione al problema dell’individuazione dell’origine del plusvalore (problema affrontato compiutamente da Marx nel Primo Libro), il ruolo della moneta, del credito e della finanza nell’ambito del- la teoria marxiana, laddove contemplato, è stato quasi sempre ridotto a quello di ampli- ficatori del ciclo economico.2 Lungi dall’essere considerati elementi costitutivi del mo- do di produzione capitalistico, e dunque di ogni modello analitico che aspiri ad indagar- * Ricercatore presso la Leeds University Business School, Economics Division.
    [Show full text]
  • New Working Papers Series, Entitled “Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics”
    Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 74 the other canon foundation, Norway Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn Ragnar Nurkse Department of Innovation and Governance CONTACT: Rainer Kattel, [email protected]; Wolfgang Drechsler, [email protected]; Erik S. Reinert, [email protected] 80 Economic Bestsellers before 1850: A Fresh Look at the History of Economic Thought Erik S. Reinert, Kenneth Carpenter, Fernanda A. Reinert, Sophus A. Reinert* MAY 2017 * E. Reinert, Tallinn University of Technology & The Other Canon Foundation, Norway; K. Car- penter, former librarian, Harvard University; F. Reinert, The Other Canon Foundation, Norway; S. Reinert, Harvard Business School. The authors are grateful to Dr. Debra Wallace, Managing Director, Baker Library Services and, Laura Linard, Director of Baker Library Special Collections, at Harvard Business School, where the Historical Collection now houses what was once the Kress Library, for their cooperation in this venture. Above all our thanks go to Olga Mikheeva at Tallinn University of Technology for her very efficient research assistance. Antiquarian book dealers often have more information on economics books than do academics, and our thanks go to Wilhelm Hohmann in Stuttgart, Robert H. Rubin in Brookline MA, Elvira Tasbach in Berlin, and, above all, to Ian Smith in London. We are also grateful for advice from Richard van den Berg, Francesco Boldizzoni, Patrick O’Brien, Alexandre Mendes Cunha, Bertram Schefold and Arild Sæther. Corresponding author [email protected] The core and backbone of this publication consists of the meticulous work of Kenneth Carpenter, librarian of the Kress Library at Harvard Busi- ness School starting in 1968 and later Assistant Director for Research Resources in the Harvard University Library and the Harvard College 1 Library.
    [Show full text]
  • Le Pour Et Le Contre. Galiani, La Diplomatie Et Le Commerce Des Blés
    Le pour et le contre. Galiani, la diplomatie et le commerce des blés « Il y a quelque subalterne à Naples qui méritent d’être observé, entre autres l’abbé Galiani, qui aspire à jouer un rôle et croit se faire un mérite en s’opposant de tout son petit pouvoir à ce qui intéresse la France. »1 La plupart des études sur l’abbé Galiani, et particulièrement sur ses Dialogues sur le commerce des blés et sa période parisienne, oscillent entre trois grands pôles : l’histoire littéraire2, l’histoire de la pensée économique3; et l’histoire culturelle des Lumières et des sociabilités4. Ces études fondamentales ont ainsi éclairé les liens intellectuels de Galiani avec les écrivains et philosophes (en particulier Diderot et Grimm), le contenu théorique de sa pensée économique, et son inscription dans les cercles mondains de la capitale française. Cependant, une dimension d’importance semble négligée : l’activité diplomatique de l’abbé, qui ne peut être traitée séparément du reste. En effet, non seulement la « république des lettres » était encastrée dans le jeu du pouvoir, mais Ferdinando Galiani avait pour propriété sociale éminente d’être le chargé d’affaire du Royaume des Deux-Siciles, chargé d’informer le gouvernement de son royaume sur le cours des négociations du Pacte de Famille. Sa présence assidue dans les salons parisiens ne témoigne pas seulement de son goût pour la bonne compagnie et la conversation mondaine, mais de son professionnalisme : hors Versailles, nul espace plus propice, en effet, à la fréquentation des grands5. Si le terme diplomate apparaît tardivement, sous la Révolution semble-t-il, pour désigner le métier de représentant d’une puissance étrangère, la réalité professionnelle lui est antérieure6.
    [Show full text]
  • Downloaded from Elgar Online at 09/30/2021 01:19:40PM Via Free Access I I
    i i i i Bibliography Adrian, T. and Shin, H. S. (2010), ‘The changing nature of financial intermedi- ation and the financial crisis of 2007–2009,’ Annual Review of Economics, 2010 (2), 603–618. Adrian, T. and Shin, H. S. (2011), ‘Financial intermediaries and monetary economics,’ in B. M. Friedman and M. Woodford (eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, Amsterdam: North Holland, vol. 3A, pp. 601–650. Akerlof, G. A. (2002), ‘Behavioral macroeconomics and macroeconomic behavior,’ American Economic Review, 92 (3), 411–433. Akerlof, G. A. and Shiller, R. J. (2015), Phishing for Fools, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Arrow, K. J. (1967), ‘Samuelson Collected,’ Journal of Political Economy, 75 (5), 730–737. Arrow, K. J. (1974), ‘Limited knowledge and economic analysis,’ American Economic Review, 64 (1), 1–10. Arrow, K. J. (2009), ‘Some developments in economic theory since 1940: An eyewitness account,’ Review of Economics, 1 (1), 1–16. Arrow, K. J. and Hahn, F. H. (1971), General Competitive Analysis,San Francisco: Holden-Day Inc. Backhouse, R. E. and Boianovsky, M. (2013), Transforming Modern Macro- economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Baranzini, M. (2005), Léon Walras e la moneta senza velo, Torino: UTET. Barro, R. J. and Grossman, H. I. (1971), ‘A general disequilibrium model of income and employment,’ American Economic Review, 61 (1), 82–93. Benhabib, J. and Spiegel, M. (2000), ‘The role of financial development in growth and investment,’ Journal of Economic Growth, 5 (4), 341–360. Bernanke, B. S. (1983), ‘Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the Great Depression,’ American Economic Review, 73 (3), 257–276.
    [Show full text]
  • David Hume on Public Credit Maria Pia Paganelli Trinity University, [email protected]
    Trinity University Digital Commons @ Trinity Economics Faculty Research Economics Department 2012 David Hume on Public Credit Maria Pia Paganelli Trinity University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.trinity.edu/econ_faculty Part of the Economics Commons Repository Citation Paganelli, M.P. (2012). David Hume on public credit. History of Economic Ideas, 20(1), 31-43. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics Department at Digital Commons @ Trinity. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Faculty Research by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ Trinity. For more information, please contact [email protected]. electronic issnelectronic 17 issn X · OF ECONOMICS IDEAS HISTORY 1122-8792 HISTORY OF 24-2169 ECONOMIC IDEAS X/2012/1 HEI offprint XX/2012/1 Fabrizio Serra editore Pisa · Roma Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2142520 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC IDEAS History of Economic Ideas Online www.historyofeconomicideas.com Editors: Riccardo Faucci (University of Pisa) Roberto Marchionatti (University of Turin) Book Review Editor: Nicola Giocoli (University of Pisa) Editorial Board: Richard Arena (University of Nice), Duccio Cavalieri (University of Florence), Marco Dardi(University of Florence), Peter D. Groenewegen (University of Sydney), Hansjörg Klausinger (University of Vienna), Christian Seidl (University of Kiel) Advisory Board: M. M. Augello (University of Pisa),G. Becattini (University of Florence), A. A. Brewer (University of Bristol), B. J. Caldwell (Duke University), A. L. Cot (University of Paris i), R. W. Dimand (Brock University), S. Fiori (University of Turin), G. C. Harcourt (University of Cambridge, uk), A. Karayiannis† (University of Piraeus), B.
    [Show full text]
  • The Neapolitan Banks in the Context of Early Modern Public Banks;
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Velde, François R. Working Paper The Neapolitan banks in the context of early modern public banks Working Paper, No. 2018-05 Provided in Cooperation with: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Suggested Citation: Velde, François R. (2018) : The Neapolitan banks in the context of early modern public banks, Working Paper, No. 2018-05, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago, IL, http://dx.doi.org/10.21033/wp-2018-05 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/200575 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The Neapolitan Banks in the Context of Early Modern Public Banks François R. Velde March 11, 2018 WP 2018-05 ral Reserve Bank of Chicago Reserve ral https://doi.org/10.21033/wp-2018-05 *Working papers are not edited, and all opinions and errors are the responsibility of the author(s).
    [Show full text]
  • Vanity and the Daedalian Wings of Paper Money in Adam Smith
    Trinity University Digital Commons @ Trinity Economics Faculty Research Economics Department 2006 Vanity and the Daedalian Wings of Paper Money in Adam Smith Maria Pia Paganelli Trinity University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.trinity.edu/econ_faculty Part of the Economics Commons Repository Citation Paganelli, M.P. (2006). Vanity and the Daedalian wings of paper money in Adam Smith. In L. Montes & E. Schliesser (Eds.), New voices on Adam Smith (pp. 271-289). Routledge. This Contribution to Book is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics Department at Digital Commons @ Trinity. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Faculty Research by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ Trinity. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 12_Adam Smith518 15/12/05 1:56 pm Page 271 12_Adam Smith518.pdf 12 Vanity and the Daedalian wings of paper money in Adam Smith Maria Pia Paganelli George Stigler (1971) claimed that: ‘it is uncomfortable to explain Smith’s failure by the failure of everyone else, for he is a better man than everyone else’ (214). Diverging from Stigler, the problem presented in this chapter is: how can we explain Smith’s failure when others did not fail, for Smith is a better man than everyone else? The failure by Smith diagnosed in this chapter is his lack of vision for the potential uses and/or misuses as policy instruments of paper money in general and of public credit in particular – vision that Smith’s contempor- aries did not lack. Paper money could be used not only as a cheaper sub- stitute of metallic money, as Smith well realized, but also as a relatively cheaper policy tool to create more money and try to gain control over the economy.
    [Show full text]
  • The In/Visible Woman: Mariangela Ardinghelli and the Circulation Of
    The In/visible Woman: Mariangela Ardinghelli and the Circulation of Knowledge between Paris and Naples in the Eighteenth Century Author(s): Paola Bertucci Source: Isis, Vol. 104, No. 2 (June 2013), pp. 226-249 Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of The History of Science Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/670946 . Accessed: 29/06/2013 11:12 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press and The History of Science Society are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Isis. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 130.132.173.211 on Sat, 29 Jun 2013 11:12:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions The In/visible Woman Mariangela Ardinghelli and the Circulation of Knowledge between Paris and Naples in the Eighteenth Century By Paola Bertucci* ABSTRACT Mariangela Ardinghelli (1730–1825) is remembered as the Italian translator of two texts by the Newtonian physiologist Stephen Hales, Haemastaticks and Vegetable Staticks. This essay shows that her role in the Republic of Letters was by no means limited to such work.
    [Show full text]
  • Capodistria, Ieri E Oggi
    CAPODISTRIA, IERI E OGGI Autrice Martina Seražin Mohorčič Discipline di riferimento Lingua e letteratura italiana (italiano L1), storia Target group Scuola elementare con lingua d’insegnamento italiana in Slovenia - 8 e 9 classe EDUKA2 PER UNA GOVERNANCE TRANSFRONTALIERA DELL’ISTRUZIONE ČEZMEJNO UPRAVLJANJE IZOBRAŽEVANJA EDUKA2 Per una governance transfrontaliera dell’istruzione / Čezmejno upravljanje izobraževanja Progetto finanziato nell’ambito del Programma di Cooperazione Interreg V-A Italia- Slovenia 2014-2020 con il Fondo europeo di sviluppo regionale / Projekt financira Program sodelovanja Interreg V-A Italija-Slovenija s sredstvi Evropskega sklada za regionalni razvoj Work package / Delovni sklop 3.1.3 Condivisione e realizzazione di materiali didattici e azioni pilota di supporto all’insegnamento delle lingue minoritarie e regionali / Skupno načrtovanje in realizacija didaktičnega gradiva in pilotnih aktivnosti za podporo pri poučevanju manjšinskih in regionalnih jezikov Unità didattiche per l’insegnamento dell’italiano nelle scuole con lingua d’insegnamento italiana in Slovenia / Učne enote za potrebe poučevanja italijanščine na šolah z italijanskim učnim jezikom v Sloveniji TITOLO CAPODISTRIA, IERI E OGGI AUTRICE Martina Seražin Mohorčič A CURA DI Sergio Crasnich, Sonja Starc PROJECT MANAGER Zaira Vidau EDITO DA Facoltà di Studi Educativi dell’Università del Litorale GRAFICA E IMPAGINAZIONE Ilaria Comello, Grafica Goriziana– Gorizia Il contenuto della presente pubblicazione non rispecchia necessariamente le posizioni ufficiali
    [Show full text]
  • Marsili's Oceanographic Cruise
    APRIL 2018 P I N A R D I E T A L . 845 Measuring the Sea: Marsili’s Oceanographic Cruise (1679–80) and the Roots of Oceanography a b b c d NADIA PINARDI, EMIN ÖZSOY, MOHAMMED ABDUL LATIF, FRANCA MORONI, ALESSANDRO GRANDI, e e f GIUSEPPE MANZELLA, FEDERICO DE STROBEL, AND VLADYSLAV LYUBARTSEV a Department of Physics and Astronomy, University of Bologna, Bologna, Italy b Institute of Marine Sciences, Erdemli, Mersin, Turkey c Emilia Romagna Regional Agency, Bologna, Italy d Istituto Nazionale di Geofisica e Vulcanologia, Bologna, Italy e Historical Oceanography Society, La Spezia, Italy f Centro Euro-Mediterraneo per i Cambiamenti Climatici, Bologna, Italy (Manuscript received 25 August 2017, in final form 3 February 2018) ABSTRACT The first in situ measurements of seawater density that referred to a geographical position at sea and time of the year were carried out by Count Luigi Ferdinando Marsili between 1679 and 1680 in the Adriatic Sea, Aegean Sea, Marmara Sea, and the Bosporus. Not only was this the first investigation with documented oceanographic mea- surements carried out at stations, but the measurements were described in such an accurate way that the authors were able to reconstruct the observations in modern units. These first measurements concern the ‘‘specific gravity’’ of seawaters (i.e., the ratio between fluid densities). The data reported in the historical oceanographic treatise Osservazioni intorno al Bosforo Tracio (Marsili) allowed the reconstruction of the seawater density at different geographic locations between 1679 and 1680. Marsili’s experimental methodology included the collection of surface and deep water samples, the analysis of the samples with a hydrostatic ampoule, and the use of a reference water to standardize the measurements.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Happiness As the Wealth of Nations: the Rise of Political Economy in Naples in a Comparative Perspective
    Public Happiness as the Wealth of Nations: The Rise of Political Economy in Naples in a Comparative Perspective Filippo Sabetti The professed object of Dr. Adam Smith’ inquiry is the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. There is another inquiry, however, perhaps still more interesting, which he occasionally mixes with it, I mean an inquiry into the causes which affect the happiness of nations. (Malthus 1798: 303, quoted in Bruni and Porta 2005, 1) The rise of political economy in eighteenth-century Naples was as much a response to the economic conditions of the realm as it was an effort to absorb, modify, and give a hand to the scientific and human progress agitating Transalpine currents of thought. The emerging political economy in Naples stands out in part because its calls for reform and for the creation of a commercial and manufacturing society were not a radical break or rupture with the past. The recognition of the capacity of a commercial society to create wealth was accompanied by the equally important recognition that market transactions between individuals could be perceived both as mutually beneficial exchanges and as genuine social interactions that carried moral value by virtue of the social content. Whereas the Scottish Enlightenment sought to isolate market relationships from other relationships and to separate the concept of a well-governed state from the ideal of the virtuous citizen, the Neapolitan Enlightenment continued to embed the economy in social relations, arguing that good institutions could not function in the absence of good men. Individual happiness was derived from making others happy and not from the accumulation of things.
    [Show full text]
  • Experiment and Speculation in Seventeenth-Century Italy : the Case of Geminiano Montanari
    Original citation: Vanzo, Alberto. (2016) Experiment and speculation in seventeenth-century Italy : the case of Geminiano Montanari. Studies In History and Philosophy of Science Part A, 56 . pp. 52-61. Permanent WRAP url: http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk/75572 Copyright and reuse: The Warwick Research Archive Portal (WRAP) makes this work of researchers of the University of Warwick available open access under the following conditions. This article is made available under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International license (CC BY 4.0) and may be reused according to the conditions of the license. For more details see: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ A note on versions: The version presented in WRAP is the published version, or, version of record, and may be cited as it appears here. For more information, please contact the WRAP Team at: [email protected] http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk Studies in History and Philosophy of Science 56 (2016) 52e61 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Studies in History and Philosophy of Science journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/shpsa Experiment and speculation in seventeenth-century Italy: The case of Geminiano Montanari Alberto Vanzo Department of Philosophy, Social Sciences Building, University of Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL, United Kingdom article info abstract Article history: This paper reconstructs the natural philosophical method of Geminiano Montanari, one of the most Received 29 July 2015 prominent Italian natural philosophers of the late seventeenth century. Montanari’s views are used as a Received in revised form case study to assess recent claims concerning early modern experimental philosophy. Having presented 24 October 2015 the distinctive tenets of seventeenth-century experimental philosophers, I argue that Montanari adheres Available online xxx to them explicitly, thoroughly, and consistently.
    [Show full text]