Opportunity Cost Consideration

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Opportunity Cost Consideration Opportunity Cost Consideration STEPHEN A. SPILLER Normatively, consumers should incorporate opportunity costs into every decision they make, yet behavioral research suggests that consumers consider them rarely, if at all. This research addresses when consumers consider opportunity costs, who considers opportunity costs, which opportunity costs spontaneously spring to mind, and what the consequences of considering opportunity costs are. Perceived con- straints cue consumers to consider opportunity costs, and consumers high in pro- pensity to plan consider opportunity costs even when not cued by immediate con- straints. The specific alternatives retrieved and the likelihood of retrieval are functions of category structures in memory. For a given resource, some uses are more typical of the category of possible uses and so are more likely to be con- sidered as opportunity costs. Consumers who consider opportunity costs are less likely to buy focal options than those who do not when opportunity costs are appealing, but no less likely when opportunity costs are unappealing. onsumers have unlimited wants but limited resources, What are the consequences of considering versus neglecting C so satisfying one want means not satisfying another opportunity costs? (the opportunity cost). An opportunity cost is “the evaluation Five studies provide initial answers. Consumers consider placed on the most highly valued of the rejected alternatives opportunity costs when they perceive immediate resource or opportunities” (Buchanan 2008) or “the loss of other constraints and when they use limited-use resources (i.e., alternatives when one alternative is chosen” (Oxford English resources that may only be spent on particular products); Dictionary 2010). Opportunity costs are foundational to the planners chronically consider opportunity costs even when science of economics and, normatively, consumers should they do not face immediate constraints. Categories of re- account for opportunity costs in every decision. Though train- source uses influence which opportunity costs are considered ing can increase consideration (Larrick, Morgan, and Nisbett and the particular ones that are considered matter. Consum- 1990), a stream of behavioral research concludes that indi- ers who consider opportunity costs are more sensitive to viduals often neglect their opportunity costs (Becker, Ronen, their value than those who do not. and Sorter 1974; Frederick et al. 2009; Friedman and Neu- Opportunity cost consideration affects personal and societal mann 1980; Jones et al. 1998; Langholtz et al. 2003; Le- well-being. Individuals who consider opportunity costs are grenzi, Girotto, and Johnson-Laird 1993; Northcraft and more likely to obtain desirable life outcomes than those who Neale 1986). I define opportunity cost consideration as “con- neglect them (Larrick, Nisbett, and Morgan 1993). Personal sidering alternative uses for one’s resources when deciding bankruptcies are linked to credit card debt and spending on whether to spend resources on a focal option.” When do housing and automobiles that leave people with insufficient consumers consider opportunity costs? Who considers op- savings to withstand adverse events (Domowitz and Sartain portunity costs? Which opportunity costs do they consider? 1999; Zhu, forthcoming). Controlling for demographics, propensity to plan for the use of money (possibly reflecting Stephen A. Spiller ([email protected]) is a doctoral candidate differences in opportunity cost consideration) is associated in marketing at the Fuqua School of Business, Duke University. As of July with higher FICO credit scores (Lynch et al. 2010). 1, 2011, he will be assistant professor of marketing at the UCLA Anderson I begin by discussing research on focal and outside op- School of Management, 110 Westwood Plaza, Los Angeles, CA 90095. tions and propose how constraint and categorization may This article is based on the author’s dissertation. The author thanks the increase opportunity cost consideration. Five studies dem- editor, associate editor, three reviewers, and numerous seminar participants onstrate the effects of constraint, planning, and resource-use for constructive feedback. He is indebted to his dissertation committee, accessibility. Jim Bettman, Rick Larrick, Beth Marsh, and especially his cochairs, John Lynch and Dan Ariely, for invaluable guidance and mentorship. Ann McGill served as editor and Brian Ratchford served as associate editor FOCAL AND OUTSIDE OPTIONS for this article. Consumers consider opportunity costs when they pay at- Electronically published April 14, 2011 tention to outside options. Other constructs, such as pain of 595 ᭧ 2011 by JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH, Inc. ● Vol. 38 ● December 2011 All rights reserved. 0093-5301/2011/3804-0001$10.00. DOI: 10.1086/660045 596 JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH paying (Prelec and Loewenstein 1998; Rick, Cryder, and H1: Resource constraints increase opportunity cost Loewenstein 2008) or the value of the marginal dollar consideration. (Chandukala et al. 2007), may curb consumption too but are not the focus of the present work. This usage of op- In support of this hypothesis, tight mental budgets can portunity cost consideration is consistent with previous re- reduce consumption (Heath and Soll 1996; Krishnamurthy search (e.g., Jones et al. 1998; Legrenzi et al. 1993). Because and Prokopec 2010; Shefrin and Thaler 1988; Stilley, Inman, the way consumers value money may be divorced from its and Wakefield 2010), and merely making smaller, more con- possible uses (Hsee et al. 2003; van Osselaer, Alba, and strained accounts more accessible leads to a lower likelihood Manchanda 2004), and therefore from opportunity costs, it of purchase (Morewedge, Holtzman, and Epley 2007). Rus- is important to understand when they incorporate alternative sell et al. (1999) speculate that consumers with tight budget resource uses, not just the value of money, into their de- constraints are more likely to construct cross-category con- cisions. sideration sets. Consumers tend not to consider alternatives Previous research has largely ignored the drivers of op- that are not explicitly available (Legrenzi et al. 1993), but portunity cost consideration, although some has focused on they are more likely to consider alternatives when they are the consequences of opportunity cost consideration versus more relevant, even if they are not focal (Cherubini et al. neglect. Although framing one option as focal may not 2003; Del Missier et al. 2007). Thought protocols show that change the decision structure, and thus should not affect the people construe resource allocation tasks one decision at a decision, it can have important effects on choice (Jones et time, effectively ignoring opportunity costs, until they have al. 1998). Appealing focal options are more likely to be few resources remaining (Ball et al. 1998). When they ap- chosen than appealing outside options (Posavac et al. 2004, proach constraints, other expenditure opportunities are more 2005), more information is gathered about focal than outside diagnostic, and they construe the current decision as an al- options (Cherubini, Mazzocco, and Rumiati 2003; Del Mis- location across multiple expenditure opportunities. sier, Ferrante, and Constantini 2007; Legrenzi et al. 1993), Constraint is dynamic and varies over time; opportunity and sometimes purchase decisions are made as if outside cost consideration should vary accordingly. Consumers us- options do not exist (Frederick et al. 2009). Research on ing monthly budgets for any given purchase feel less con- hypothesis testing similarly finds that more evidence is gath- straint than consumers using weekly budgets (Morewedge ered about focal hypotheses than alternative hypotheses et al. 2007), expenses are more salient at the end of bud- (Klayman and Ha 1987; Sanbonmatsu et al. 1998), culmi- getary periods than at the beginning (Soster 2010), and food nating in overconfidence regarding a focal hypothesis (Mc- consumption declines over the month for individuals re- Kenzie 1997, 1998). Although focal options take on a priv- ceiving monthly food stamps (Shapiro 2005). Collectively, ileged status, consumers sometimes spontaneously recruit these findings suggest that shorter budgeting periods may outside options into focal decisions (Jones et al. 1998; Po- increase opportunity cost consideration. savac, Sanbonmatsu, and Fazio 1997). The purpose of the present work is to determine what drives such spontaneous The Effects of Category Structures on the recruitment of outside options. I propose two critical drivers Accessibility of Opportunity Costs in Memory are perceived constraint and the accessibility of alternate resource uses. The second proposed driver of opportunity cost consid- eration is the accessibility of alternate resource uses. Infor- mation in memory often is available without being acces- The Effect of Perceived Constraint on sible (Lynch and Srull 1982; Tulving and Pearlstone 1966), Opportunity Cost Consideration so increasing the accessibility of an alternative can increase its consideration (Mitra and Lynch 1995; Nedungadi 1990; The first proposed driver of opportunity cost consideration Posavac et al. 1997; Priester et al. 2004). Accessibility is a is perceived constraint. When consumers recruit inputs to function of both self-generated and externally present re- evaluate a single alternative, they rely on a metacognitive trieval cues (Lynch and Srull 1982). The present work ex- sense of sufficiency to terminate
Recommended publications
  • Money, Interest and Inflation Chapter 28 C H a P T E R C H E C K L I S T When You Have Completed Your Study of This Chapter, You Will Be Able To
    Money, Interest and Inflation Chapter 28 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain what determines the demand for money and how the demand for money and the supply of money determine the nominal interest rate. 2 Explain how in the long run, the quantity of money determines the price level and money growth brings inflation. 3 Identify the costs of inflation and the benefits of a stable value of money. WHERE WE ARE; WHERE WE’RE HEADING < The Real Economy Real factors that are independent of the price level determine real GDP, the natural unemployment rate. Investment and saving determine the real interest rate and, along with population growth and technological change, determine the growth rate of real GDP. <The Money Economy Money is created by banks and its quantity is controlled by the Fed. WHERE WE ARE; WHERE WE’RE HEADING <The Money Economy The effects of money can be best understood in three steps: • The effects of the Fed’s actions on the short-term nominal interest rate • The long-run effects of the Fed’s actions on the price level and the inflation rate • The details between the short-run and long-run effects 28.1 MONEY AND THE INTEREST RATE < The Demand for Money Quantity of money demanded The inventory of money that households and firms choose to hold. Benefit of Holding Money The benefit of holding money is the ability to make payments.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Evaluation Glossary of Terms
    Economic Evaluation Glossary of Terms A Attributable fraction: indirect health expenditures associated with a given diagnosis through other diseases or conditions (Prevented fraction: indicates the proportion of an outcome averted by the presence of an exposure that decreases the likelihood of the outcome; indicates the number or proportion of an outcome prevented by the “exposure”) Average cost: total resource cost, including all support and overhead costs, divided by the total units of output B Benefit-cost analysis (BCA): (or cost-benefit analysis) a type of economic analysis in which all costs and benefits are converted into monetary (dollar) values and results are expressed as either the net present value or the dollars of benefits per dollars expended Benefit-cost ratio: a mathematical comparison of the benefits divided by the costs of a project or intervention. When the benefit-cost ratio is greater than 1, benefits exceed costs C Comorbidity: presence of one or more serious conditions in addition to the primary disease or disorder Cost analysis: the process of estimating the cost of prevention activities; also called cost identification, programmatic cost analysis, cost outcome analysis, cost minimization analysis, or cost consequence analysis Cost effectiveness analysis (CEA): an economic analysis in which all costs are related to a single, common effect. Results are usually stated as additional cost expended per additional health outcome achieved. Results can be categorized as average cost-effectiveness, marginal cost-effectiveness,
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Microeconomics LESSON 2 ACTIVITY 2 Key Scarcity, Opportunity Cost and Production Possibilities Curves
    UNIT Answer I 1 Microeconomics LESSON 2 ACTIVITY 2 Key Scarcity, Opportunity Cost and Production Possibilities Curves Scarcity necessitates choice. Consuming or producing more of one thing means consuming or pro- ducing less of something else. The opportunity cost of using scarce resources for one thing instead of something else is often represented in graphical form as a production possibilities curve. Part A Use Figures 2.1 and 2.2 to answer these questions. Write the correct answer on the answer blanks, or underline the correct answer in parentheses. Figure 2.1 Production Possibilities Curve 1 12 10 8 6 GOOD B 4 2 031 2 456 GOOD A 1. If the economy represented by Figure 2.1 is presently producing 12 units of Good B and zero units of Good A: (A) The opportunity cost of increasing production of Good A from zero units to one unit is the loss of two unit(s) of Good B. (B) The opportunity cost of increasing production of Good A from one unit to two units is the loss of two unit(s) of Good B. (C) The opportunity cost of increasing production of Good A from two units to three units is the loss of two unit(s) of Good B. (D) This is an example of (constant / increasing / decreasing / zero) opportunity cost per unit for Good A. Advanced Placement Economics Teacher Resource Manual © National Council on Economic Education, New York, N.Y. 17 UNIT Answer I 1 Microeconomics LESSON 2 ACTIVITY 2 Key Part B Use the axes in Figures 2.3, 2.4 and 2.5 to draw the type of curve that illustrates the label above each axis.
    [Show full text]
  • Oecd Development Centre
    OECD DEVELOPMENT CENTRE Working Paper No. 16 (Formerly Technical Paper No. 16) COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: THEORY AND APPLICATION TO DEVELOPING COUNTRY AGRICULTURE by Ian Goldin Research programme on: Changing Comparative Advantage in Food and Agriculture June 1990 TABLE OF CONTENTS SUMMARY . 9 PREFACE . 11 INTRODUCTION . 13 PART ONE . 14 COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: THE THEORY . 14 The Theory of Comparative Advantage . 14 Testing the theory . 15 The Theory and Agriculture . 16 PART TWO . 19 COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE: THE PRACTICE . 19 Costs and Prices . 19 Land, Labour and Capital . 20 Joint Products . 22 Cost Studies . 22 Engineering Cost Studies . 23 Revealed Comparative Advantage . 25 Trade Liberalisation Simulations . 26 Domestic Resource Cost Analysis . 29 PART THREE . 32 COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE AND DEVELOPING COUNTRY AGRICULTURE . 32 Comparative Advantage and Economic Growth . 32 Conclusion . 33 NOTES . 35 BIBLIOGRAPHICAL REFERENCES . 36 7 SUMMARY This paper investigates the application of the principle of comparative advantage to policy analysis and policy formulation. It is concerned with both the theory and the measurement of comparative advantage. Despite its central role in economics, the theory is found to be at an impasse, with its usefulness confined mainly to the illustration of economic principles which in practice are not borne out by the evidence. The considerable methodological problems associated with the measurement of comparative advantage are highlighted in the paper. Attempts to derive indicators of comparative advantage, such as those associated with "revealed comparative advantage", "direct resource cost", "production cost" and "trade liberalisation" studies are reviewed. These methods are enlightening, but are unable to provide general perspectives which allow an analysis of dynamic comparative advantage.
    [Show full text]
  • Opportunity Cost and Explain Why Accounting Profits and Economic Profits Are Not the Same.”
    Microeconomics Topic 1: “Explain the concept of opportunity cost and explain why accounting profits and economic profits are not the same.” Reference: Gregory Mankiw’s Principles of Microeconomics, 2nd edition, Chapter 1 (p. 3-6) and Chapter 13 (p. 270-2). Scarcity Economics is the study of how people make choices under scarcity. What is scarcity? Scarcity means that resources are limited. There are not enough resources available to satisfy everyone’s wants. This is clearly true for individuals. Your income is limited. You cannot buy everything you want, so you must choose between different alternatives. Your time is also limited. You cannot do everything you want to, so you are forced to choose between different alternatives. If you choose to spend the day at the beach, you give up going to class or working. Opportunity Cost This concept of scarcity leads to the idea of opportunity cost. The opportunity cost of an action is what you must give up when you make that choice. Another way to say this is: it is the value of the next best opportunity. Opportunity cost is a direct implication of scarcity. People have to choose between different alternatives when deciding how to spend their money and their time. Milton Friedman, who won the Nobel Prize for Economics, is fond of saying "there is no such thing as a free lunch." What that means is that in a world of scarcity, everything has an opportunity cost. There is always a trade-off involved in any decision you make. The concept of opportunity cost is one of the most important ideas in economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Opportunity Costs and the Economist’S View: a Response to “The Economist’S Fallacy”
    http://www.jmde.com/ Commentary Understanding Opportunity Costs and the Economist’s View: A Response to “The Economist’s Fallacy” Brad R. Watts Western Michigan University f course, the concept of opportunity costs wheat bread as being the $2.50 they hand over O has generally remained in the domain of to the cashier at the grocery store. Instead, economists and its understanding and economists are concerned with efficient use of acceptance are not universal in other fields, resources, which means that cost should be including evaluation. Indeed, in the last issue of considered in light of what could have the Journal of Multidisciplinary Evaluation (JMDE), otherwise been obtained with the same resource Michael Scriven spoke out against the use of expenditure—in this case perhaps the oatmeal opportunity costs in evaluation. Unfortunately, bread, or tortillas, or other product that you what may appear to Scriven to be flaws of logic could have put your limited resources toward if and utility in the economists’ concept of cost you had not decided on getting the whole wheat are the result of some common bread. misunderstandings about what a “cost” is—at On the surface this may seem trivial since, least in terms of how economists use the term. after all, we obviously prefer the wheat bread However, I believe that the points raised by and many of us could easily afford to purchase Scriven can be either corrected or clarified in a both the loaf of wheat bread and the tortillas. way that will illustrate why opportunity costs are However, as the situation grows more a useful and important concept for evaluators.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice
    Chapter 2 The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano © 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice 2 Chapter Outline Scarcity, Choice, and Opportunity Cost Scarcity and Choice in a One-Person Economy Scarcity and Choice in an Economy of Two or More Scarcity and Choice and Scarcity The Production Possibility Frontier Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade The Economic Problem Economic Systems Command Economies Laissez-Faire Economies: The Free Market Mixed Systems, Markets, CHAPTER 2: The Economic Problem: Economic The 2: CHAPTER and Governments Looking Ahead © 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair 2 of 34 THE ECONOMIC PROBLEM: SCARCITY AND CHOICE FIGURE 2.1 The Three Basic Questions Scarcity and Choice and Scarcity Three basic questions must be answered in order to understand an economic system: • What gets produced? CHAPTER 2: The Economic Problem: Economic The 2: CHAPTER • How is it produced? • Who gets what is produced? © 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair 3 of 34 THE ECONOMIC PROBLEM: SCARCITY AND CHOICE capital Things that are themselves produced and that are then used in the production of other goods and services. factors of production (or factors) The inputs into the process of production. Scarcity and Choice and Scarcity Another word for resources. CHAPTER 2: The Economic Problem: Economic The 2: CHAPTER © 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair 4 of 34 THE ECONOMIC PROBLEM: SCARCITY AND CHOICE production The process that transforms scarce resources into useful goods and services.
    [Show full text]
  • Using Evolutionary Economics to Explain Pradator-Prey Anomalies In
    Using evolutionary economics to explain pradator-prey anomalies in the fisheries or explaining micky mouse's ears James R, Wilson, Professor Department d'économie et de gestion Universite du Quebec, Rimouski 300, allée des Ursulines Rimouski, Quebec CANADA G5L7B5 Abstract The development of several sub-fields of general economics, including those of bounded rationality, institutional economics and the evolutionary economics, has expanded the scope and intensity of the dialogue both within economics, as well as between economists and other scientists. One of the more important preoccupations of early evolutionary economics was the development of an aggregate growth theory with more realistic micro-foundations of firm behavior. Now theorizing and modeling of evolutionary economic processes is also a preoccupation of chaos theorists. Fleet evolution in a competitive fishery displays many features of interest, one of which is the strong similarity with predator-prey relationships in population biology. However, aggregate data on Heel behavior sometimes reveal humps or "ears"' which, when fitted to differential equations explaining stock and fleet evolution, are smoothed. Such smoothing reveals the dominant process, but it filters out other important secondary processes of interest to resource managers. These secondary processes can include price effects, technological innovation and diffusion, and complexities in the ecosystem that change stock parameters. This paper discusses how an evolutionary economics approach to modeling firm behavior
    [Show full text]
  • Opportunity-Cost Conflicts in Corporate Law
    Case Western Reserve Law Review Volume 66 Issue 1 Article 4 2015 Opportunity-Cost Conflicts in Corporate Law Abraham J.B. Cable Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/caselrev Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Abraham J.B. Cable, Opportunity-Cost Conflicts in Corporate Law, 66 Case W. Rsrv. L. Rev. 51 (2015) Available at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/caselrev/vol66/iss1/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Journals at Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Case Western Reserve Law Review by an authorized administrator of Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. Case Western Reserve Law Review·Volume 66·Issue 1·2015 Opportunity-Cost Conflicts in Corporate Law Abraham J.B. Cable† Abstract Delaware corporate law has a new brand of loyalty claim: the opportunity-cost conflict. Such a conflict arises when a fiduciary operates under strong incentives to withdraw human and financial capital for redeployment into new investment opportunities. The concept has its roots in venture capital investing, where board members affiliated with venture capital funds may have incentives to shut down viable start-ups in order to focus on more promising companies. Recognizing this type of conflict has conceptual value—it provides a coherent framework for assessing a fiduciary’s incentives, and it may help explain frequently criticized features of corporate fiduciary law. But this article argues that courts should invoke the doctrine sparingly to avoid upsetting the law’s current balance between policing managerial abuse and litigation abuse.
    [Show full text]
  • Opportunity Cost Neglect in Public Policy
    Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 170 (2020) 301–312 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jebo Opportunity cost neglect in public policy ∗ Emil Persson a, Gustav Tinghög a,b, a Department of Management and Engineering, Division of Economics, Linköping University, Linköping 581 83, Sweden b The National Center for Priority Setting in Health Care, Department of Medical and Health Sciences, Linköping University, Linköping 581 83, Sweden a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t Article history: Opportunity cost is the foregone benefit of options not chosen. If opportunity costs are Received 14 January 2019 neglected in decisions about public policy, there is a high risk that the best options are Revised 9 December 2019 overlooked. We study opportunity cost neglect in public policy in experiments with mem- Accepted 13 December 2019 bers of the general public in Sweden and international experts on priority setting in health Available online 10 January 2020 care ( n = 957). We find strong evidence of opportunity cost neglect in public policy, where JEL Classification: participants who acted in the role of policy makers were between six and ten percentage C9 points less likely to invest in a public health program when reminded about opportunity D1 costs (money could fund other health programs). To our surprise, we failed to confirm an H4 effect consistent with opportunity cost neglect in private consumption; but exploratory H5 analyses revealed a substantial age effect that reconciles our findings with previous litera- ture.
    [Show full text]
  • Competitive Equilibrium Hyperinflation Under Rational Expectations
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics No 578 ISSN 0104-8910 Competitive Equilibrium Hyperinflation under Rational Expectations Fernando de Holanda Barbosa, Alexandre Barros da Cunha, Elvia Mureb Sallum Janeiro de 2005 Os artigos publicados são de inteira responsabilidade de seus autores. As opiniões neles emitidas não exprimem, necessariamente, o ponto de vista da Fundação Getulio Vargas. Competitive Equilibrium Hyperinflation under Rational Expectations Fernando de Holanda Barbosa Professor of Economics Getulio Vargas Foundation Graduate School of Economics Alexandre Barros da Cunha Assistant Professor Ibmec School of Business Elvia Mureb Sallum Associate Professor Institute of Mathematics and Statistics University of SãoPaulo Abstract This paper shows that a competitive equilibrium model, where a representative agent maximizes welfare, expectations are rational and markets are in equilibrium can account for several hyperinflation stylized facts. The theory is built by combining two hypotheses, namely, a fiscal crisis that requires printing money to finance an increasing public deficit and a predicted change in an unsustainable fiscal regime. Keywords and Phrases: Hyperinflation, Rational Expectations, Competitive Equilibrium, Fiscal Crisis. JEL classification: E31, E42, E63. Competitive Equilibrium Hyperinflation under Rational Expectations Fernando de Holanda Barbosa* Alexandre Barros da Cunha** Élvia Mureb Sallum*** 1. INTRODUCTION Cagan’s (1956) seminal work provided the first attempt to explain the hyperinflation phenomenom. That essay was so influential that small variations of Cagan’s model can be found in several textbooks such as Blanchard and Fischer (1989), Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996), Romer (2001) and Sargent (1987). Cagan’s model is capable of generating hyperinflation under two types of expectation mechanisms: adaptive and rational.
    [Show full text]
  • The Law of Supply
    M03_COHE5831_02_SE_C03.indd Page 50 03/12/14 3:38 PM user /201/PHC00142/9780133135831_COHEN/COHEN_MICROECONOMICS_FOR_LIFE_SMART_CHOICES_FOR ... Show 3 Me the Money The Law of Supply LEARNING OBJECTIVES After reading this chapter, you should be able to: 3.1 Explain why marginal costs are ultimately opportunity costs. 3.2 Define sunk costs and explain why they do not influence smart, forward-looking decisions. 3.3 Explain the law of supply and describe the roles of higher profits and higher marginal opportunity costs of production. 3.4 Explain the difference between a change in quantity supplied and a change in supply, and list six factors that change supply. 50 M03_COHE5831_02_SE_C03.indd Page 51 16/12/14 2:47 PM user /201/PHC00142/9780133135831_COHEN/COHEN_MICROECONOMICS_FOR_LIFE_SMART_CHOICES_FOR ... ASSOCIATED PRESS MONEY IS THE MARKET’S REWARD to individuals or businesses who give up something of value. Your boss rewards you with an hourly wage for supplying labour services. A business producing a top-selling product is rewarded with profits (as long as revenues are greater than costs). What goes into decisions to sell or supply services or products to the market? What price do you need to get to be willing to work? How much money does it take before a business is willing to supply? This chapter focuses on choices businesses make every day in producing and selling. Economists use the term supply to summarize all of the influences on business decisions. You will learn about influences that change business supply, which include new technologies like noodle-slicing robots! Business decisions seem more “objective” than consumer decisions that seem to be based on “subjective” desires and preferences.
    [Show full text]