The Financial Crisis and the Dynamics of the Money Market Rates

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Financial Crisis and the Dynamics of the Money Market Rates A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Hasler, Nicole Research Report The financial crisis and the dynamics of the money market rates WWZ Forschungsbericht, No. 2014/08 Provided in Cooperation with: Center of Business and Economics (WWZ), University of Basel Suggested Citation: Hasler, Nicole (2014) : The financial crisis and the dynamics of the money market rates, WWZ Forschungsbericht, No. 2014/08, Universität Basel, Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Zentrum (WWZ), Basel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/127548 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Zentrum (WWZ) der Universität Basel September 2014 The financial crisis and the dynamics of the money market rates WWZ Forschungsbericht 2014/08 (FV-24) Nicole Hasler Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Zentrum (WWZ) der Universität Basel Die Autorin: Nicole Hasler Abteilung Finanzmarkttheorie Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Zentrum der Universität Basel (WWZ) Peter Merian-Weg 6 CH - 4002 Basel Telefon: +41(0)61 267 05 23 [email protected] Eine Publikation des Wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Zentrums (WWZ) der Universität Basel. Diese Publikation und das in ihr dargestellte Forschungsprojekt wurden durch den Förderverein des WWZ finanziell unterstützt. WWZ Forum 2014 und des Autors / der Autoren. Eine Reproduktion über die persönliche Nutzung des Papiers in Forschung und Lehre hinaus bedarf der Zustimmung des Autors / der Autoren. Kontakt: WWZ Forum | Peter Merian-Weg 6 | CH-4002 Basel | [email protected] | www.wwz.unibas.ch The financial crisis and the dynamics of the money market rates Nicole Hasler∗ 8th September 2014 Abstract This paper contributes to the ongoing debate about the changing dynamics in the money market rates after 2007. It aims to analyse the interest rate channel of monetary policy transmission until the federal funds target rate reached the zero lower bound. A set of different model explains both long and short run dynamics of U.S. money market rates up to 6 months. I find that secured money market rates move together with monetary policy expectations whereas unsecured interbank rates disconnected from policy rates due to an increase in both credit and liquidity risks. JEL-Classification: E43; E52; E58 Keywords: Transmission of Monetary Policy, Financial Crisis, Money Market ∗University of Basel, Faculty of Business and Economics, Peter-Merian-Weg 6, 4002 Basel, Switzerland, [email protected] 1 Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Literature Review 2 2.1 Money market spreads and the financial crisis . 3 2.2 Monetary policy transmission and implementation prior to the crisis . 4 2.2.1 Expectation hypothesis and the money market rates . 4 2.2.2 Federal funds rate dynamics . 5 3 Data and preliminary tests 6 3.1 Order of integration . 9 4 Empirical analysis 10 4.1 Bivariate VECM . 10 4.2 EGARCH model with error correction term . 12 4.3 VAR on levels . 17 5 Findings 18 5.1 Co-movements of the money market spreads: 2007 to 2008 . 18 5.2 Transmission of monetary policy and money market volatility: 2003 to 2008 . 21 5.3 Dynamics of the interbank rates after a shock: 2007 to 2008 . 24 6 Conclusion 25 Bibliography 27 A Appendix I A.1 Variables . I A.2 Unit root and stationarity tests . II A.3 Single regression cointegration tests . IV A.4 Johansen methodology . VII A.5 Granger causality tests . IX A.6 Impulse response functions . X A.7 Variance decomposition . XI List of Figures 1 3months maturity spreads (in bps) . 1 2 Rates at 3months maturity (in bps) and the Tbill-OIS spread . 6 3 LOIS spread at 3months maturity (in bps) and risk measures . 8 2 List of Tables 1 Order of integration during the crisis . 9 2 List of exogenous variables for the VECM . 11 3 List of variables in EGARCH model . 16 4 VECM spreads without exogenous variables . 19 5 VECM spreads with exogenous variables . 19 6 VECM: Exogenous variables . 19 7 Long-run relationship based on DOLS estimates . 21 8 Results EGARCH with error correction term . 23 9 List of variables . I 10 Summary of UR and stationarity testing . III 11 Single cointegration regression testing for the spreads . IV 12 Single cointegration regression testing for the unsecured interbank rates w/o RP V 13 Single cointegration regression testing for the unsecured interbank rates w/ RP . VI 14 Johansen test for the spreads . VII 15 Granger causality tests for VAR . IX 16 Responses of Libor of 1, 3 and 6 months . X 17 Responses of 1week Libor . X 18 Responses of CD rate of 1, 3 and 6 months . X 19 Responses of ED rate of 1, 3 and 6 months . X 20 Variance decomposition LIBOR models . XI 21 Variance decomposition VAR models . XI 3 1 Introduction The subprime crisis triggered a global financial crisis and severely impaired the functioning of the unsecured interbank market in 2007. This has caused serious disruptions in the transmission of monetary policy. Unsecured interbank rates decoupled from monetary policy. The U.S. Federal Reserve Bank (Fed) responded with severe target rate cuts and launched a series of non- standard monetary policy measures to improve the funding conditions in the interbank market. Therefore, the Fed closely tracked the Libor - Overnight Index Swap (LOIS) spread as a measure how interbank rates responded relative to expected monetary policy rates. Alternatively, the TED spread, the Libor over the risk-free Treasury bill (Tbill), provides another measure of money market stress. However, this measure also covers the flight-to-safety effect in government securities. Figure 1 outlines the movements of the two spreads over time. From visual inspection it can be inferred that both spreads were both small prior to the crisis. Especially, the LOIS spread was very small prior to August 2007, whereas the TED spread appears to be larger. What becomes evident from this Figure is that both spreads follow a different pattern after autumn 2008 and when the zero lower bound (ZLB) in December 2008 was reached. 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 5 TED spread LOIS spread 4 Target rate 3 2 1 0 Figure 1: 3months maturity spreads (in bps) The main objective of this paper is to evaluate the interest rate channel and to understand the dynamics in the money market in a crisis environment. I focus on the time period until December 2008 and analyse both the short and long-run adjustment of different money market instruments up to 6 months maturity. With respect to crisis and pre-crisis literature, I employ three different empirical models to evaluate how the interest rate channel is affected in an environment of high uncertainty about funding conditions. First, in line with the crisis literature, I examine the interrelationship between Libor spreads during the financial crisis and how they respond to policy announcements. I find that Libor spreads co-move during the crisis period up to 6 months maturity due to the link between monetary policy expectations and secured interbank rates. Second, similar to pre-crisis pass- 1 through models, I investigate the interest rate channel by estimating the long-run relationship of unsecured interbank rates, monetary policy expectations, and risks. I find that the relationship deteriorated since rates are subject to additional drivers such as credit and liquidity risk. The third approach concentrates on the dynamics of the interbank rates during the crisis. I investigate how interbank rates respond to monetary policy, liquidity and credit risk shocks. Findings show that the interbank rate respond to the shocks in credit risk and monetary policy expectations. The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. In Section 2 I briefly summarise the literature about monetary policy transmission both prior and during the crisis. Section 3 presents the data and preliminary tests. Section 4 documents the empirical analysis including three different econometric approaches. Section 5 documents and discusses the findings. Finally, section 6 concludes. 2 Literature Review The money markets play a crucial role in the transmission of monetary policy. By controlling the amount of reserves, most central banks set a short-term rate and rates at the longer end of the yield curve convey information about expected path of monetary policy. The concept of the expectation hypothesis explains how interest rates are tied together. In the U.S., the effective federal funds rate is the average overnight rate at which regulated financial institution lend balances among each other to meet their reserve requirements1 at the Fed. The central bank announces a price for these reserves, the overnight federal funds target rate. Through the implementation of the monetary policy such as open market operations (OMO), temporary or permanent, the Fed determines the level of reserves and therefore steers the level of the effective federal funds rate. The next step is that expectations about future changes in the overnight rate affect the level of longer-term interest rates such as the Libor.
Recommended publications
  • September 18, 2019
    September 18, 2019 Overnight Borrowing Liquidity Issues Overnight borrowing rates have spiked unexpectedly this week, raising questions about whether there’s a looming liquidity issue in the market. The NY Fed implemented borderline-emergency measures to inject liquidity this week. It bought $50B in Treasurys yesterday and will buy another $75B today. The basic mechanism is that the Fed will overpay a bank to buy some of its Treasury holdings. This gives the banks cash, which in turn they can lend to other banks. Liquidity. Or as some might call it, Quantitative Easing. Jay Powell won’t call it that, but some might… The headline culprits according to the talking heads I trust the least: 1. Corporate tax bills - money was withdrawn from bank and money market accounts to pay quarterly and annual taxes (Monday was the corporate extension deadline), which reduced the amount available as deposits to banks 2. Last week’s Treasury auction - the cash payment for the $78B T auction was due yesterday and banks typically pay for their Treasurys by borrowing in the overnight market Call me a cynic, but while these may be contributing factors, are they really to blame for a liquidity event that caused some borrowing rates to spike 3x? We were hearing from traders that repo rates got as high as 8% - 10%. Think about it – you are contractually obligated to buy something (or pay for something), you will pay 10% for one night of borrower if you have to, right? How high does the interest rate need to go before you willingly default on whatever it was that required you to go borrow in the first place? Banks don’t borrower the way consumers borrower.
    [Show full text]
  • Curve Building and Swap Pricing in the Presence of Collateral and Basis Spreads
    Curve Building and Swap Pricing in the Presence of Collateral and Basis Spreads SIMON GUNNARSSON Master of Science Thesis Stockholm, Sweden 2013 Curve Building and Swap Pricing in the Presence of Collateral and Basis Spreads SIMON GUNNARSSON Master’s Thesis in Mathematical Statistics (30 ECTS credits) Master Programme in Mathematics (120 credits) Supervisor at KTH was Boualem Djehiche Examiner was Boualem Djehiche TRITA-MAT-E 2013:19 ISRN-KTH/MAT/E--13/19--SE Royal Institute of Technology School of Engineering Sciences KTH SCI SE-100 44 Stockholm, Sweden URL: www.kth.se/sci Abstract The eruption of the financial crisis in 2008 caused immense widening of both domestic and cross currency basis spreads. Also, as a majority of all fixed income contracts are now collateralized the funding cost of a financial institution may deviate substantially from the domestic Libor. In this thesis, a framework for pricing of collateralized interest rate derivatives that accounts for the existence of non-negligible basis spreads is implemented. It is found that losses corresponding to several percent of the outstanding notional may arise as a consequence of not adapting to the new market conditions. Keywords: Curve building, swap, basis spread, cross currency, collateral Acknowledgements I wish to thank my supervisor Boualem Djehiche as well as Per Hjortsberg and Jacob Niburg for introducing me to the subject and for providing helpful feedback along the way. I also wish to express gratitude towards my family who has supported me throughout my education. Finally, I am grateful that Marcus Josefsson managed to devote a few hours to proofread this thesis.
    [Show full text]
  • 20. the Policy Conundrum of Financial Market Complexity Hilton
    20. The Policy Conundrum of Financial Market Complexity Hilton L. Root George Mason University “Your own best footstep may unleash the very cascade that carries you away, and neither you nor anyone else can predict which grain will unleash the tiny or the cataclysmic alteration.” —Stuart Kauffman The Origins of Order: Self-Organization and Selection in Evolution (Kauffman 1993) Abstract: The first global financial sector crash eludes conventional assessments of sector risk. Singling out the usual culprits—the housing bubble, executive pay, regulators, rating agencies, risk models, and global imbalances—fails to explain either the unpredictability or the rapidity of the collapse of 2008, which in many ways resembled the avalanche of a sand pile, where at some point of criticality, avalanches occur that bear no relationship to the grain of sand that triggered them. Since appropriate financial regulation is part of the remedy, policymakers should recognize that success will depend on a more refined knowledge of why some initial events may have prompted an avalanche, while others did not. 1 I. ECONOMICS AND THE SAND PILE A pile of sand. What could be a less likely metaphor for a global financial system that contains close to $200 trillion in assets worldwide? Yet an avalanche in that sand pile caused a colossal financial meltdown that destroyed at least 15 percent of national wealth in the United States alone.1 Which grain of sand triggered the avalanche? We cannot know with certainty where it was or why it moved. Conventional risk models used by economists are poor at predicting which set or category of transactions pushed the markets into a system-wide free fall, and they fail completely at expressing the market in collapse.
    [Show full text]
  • FEDERAL FUNDS Marvin Goodfriend and William Whelpley
    Page 7 The information in this chapter was last updated in 1993. Since the money market evolves very rapidly, recent developments may have superseded some of the content of this chapter. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Richmond, Virginia 1998 Chapter 2 FEDERAL FUNDS Marvin Goodfriend and William Whelpley Federal funds are the heart of the money market in the sense that they are the core of the overnight market for credit in the United States. Moreover, current and expected interest rates on federal funds are the basic rates to which all other money market rates are anchored. Understanding the federal funds market requires, above all, recognizing that its general character has been shaped by Federal Reserve policy. From the beginning, Federal Reserve regulatory rulings have encouraged the market's growth. Equally important, the federal funds rate has been a key monetary policy instrument. This chapter explains federal funds as a credit instrument, the funds rate as an instrument of monetary policy, and the funds market itself as an instrument of regulatory policy. CHARACTERISTICS OF FEDERAL FUNDS Three features taken together distinguish federal funds from other money market instruments. First, they are short-term borrowings of immediately available money—funds which can be transferred between depository institutions within a single business day. In 1991, nearly three-quarters of federal funds were overnight borrowings. The remainder were longer maturity borrowings known as term federal funds. Second, federal funds can be borrowed by only those depository institutions that are required by the Monetary Control Act of 1980 to hold reserves with Federal Reserve Banks.
    [Show full text]
  • B. Recent Changes in the Financial Secto R
    - 21 - References Calvo, Gullermo A.,1983, “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12(3), 383–398. Gali, Jordi, and Mark Gertler, 1999, “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 44(2), 195–222. Kara, Amit, and Edward Nelson, 2004, “The Exchange Rate and Inflation in the U.K.,” CEPR Discussion Papers No. 3783. Roberts, John M.,1995, “New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 27(4), 975–984. Walsh, Carl E., 2003, Monetary Theory and Policy, 2nd Edition, Cambridge, The MIT Press. - 22 - 1 III. FINANCIAL SECTOR STRENGTHS AND VULNERABILITIES—AN UPDATE A. Introduction 1. This chapter reports on strengths and vulnerabilities that may have developed in the financial system since the time of the Latvia Financial System Stability Assessment (IMF Country Report No. 02/67), and discusses measures available to the authorities for further strengthening of the system. The FSSA found that the banking system was well capitalized, profitable and liquid. It was “fairly resilient” to interest rate increases, rapid credit expansion and possible withdrawal of nonresident deposits. The FSSA recommended continued vigilance by banks and the Financial and Capital Markets Commission (FCMC) to ensure that new vulnerabilities did not develop in these areas. Nonbank financial institutions were judged not large enough to be a source of systemic risk. Supervision and regulation were judged to be robust. 2. The present assessment is based mainly on an analysis of financial soundness indicators, including macroeconomic indicators such as inflation, and on stress tests of the financial system.
    [Show full text]
  • Stressed, Not Frozen: the Federal Funds Market in the Financial Crisis
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Stressed, Not Frozen: The Federal Funds Market in the Financial Crisis Gara Afonso Anna Kovner Antoinette Schoar Staff Report no. 437 March 2010 Revised May 2011 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. Stressed, Not Frozen: The Federal Funds Market in the Financial Crisis Gara Afonso, Anna Kovner, and Antoinette Schoar Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 437 March 2010; revised May 2011 JEL classification: G21, G01, D40, E40 Abstract We examine the importance of liquidity hoarding and counterparty risk in the U.S. overnight interbank market during the financial crisis of 2008. Our findings suggest that counterparty risk plays a larger role than does liquidity hoarding: the day after Lehman Brothers’ bankruptcy, loan terms become more sensitive to borrower characteristics. In particular, poorly performing large banks see an increase in spreads of 25 basis points, but are borrowing 1 percent less, on average. Worse performing banks do not hoard liquidity. While the interbank market does not freeze entirely, it does not seem to expand to meet latent demand. Key words: fed funds, financial crisis, liquidity, interbank lending, hoarding Afonso: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (e-mail: [email protected]).
    [Show full text]
  • Reform of Interest Rate Benchmarks for Q4 2019
    Annex 1 Results of Survey on Reform of Interest Rate Benchmarks for Q4 2019 1. Hong Kong banking sector’s exposures referencing LIBOR (LIBOR exposures) (HK$ trillion, as at end-September 2019) Assets Liabilities Derivatives Total amount of LIBOR exposures (note) $4.5 $1.6 $34.6 as a % of total assets or liabilities denominated in 30% 11% N/A foreign currencies LIBOR exposures which will mature after end-2021 $1.5 $0.5 $16.1 of which without adequate fall-back $1.4 $0.5 $14.7 outstanding amount as a % of total LIBOR assets, liabilities or derivatives 33% 32% 46% Note: Includes exposures referencing LIBOR in five currencies (i.e. USD, EUR, GBP, JPY and CHF), as well as benchmarks calculated based on LIBOR, including Singapore Dollar Swap Offer Rate (SOR), Thai Baht Interest Rate Fixing (THBFIX), Mumbai Interbank Forward Offer Rate (MIFOR) and Philippine Interbank Reference Rate (PHIREF). 2. Hong Kong banking sector’s exposures referencing HIBOR (HIBOR exposures) (HK$ trillion, as at end-September 2019) Assets Liabilities Derivatives Total amount of HIBOR exposures $4.7 $0.2 $12.2 as a % of total assets or liabilities denominated in HKD 49% 2% N/A 3. AIs’ preparation for transition to alternative reference rates (ARRs) Key components in AIs’ preparatory work for transition to ARRs % AIs having the component in place Establishment of a steering committee and/or appointment of a 63% senior executive for overseeing the preparation for transition Development of a bank-wide transition plan 38% Quantification and monitoring of LIBOR exposures 48% Impact assessment across businesses and functions 42% Identification and evaluation of risk associated with the transition 38% Identification of affected IT systems and development of a plan to 39% upgrade these systems Identification of affected internal models and development of a plan 36% to modify these models Development of a plan to introduce ARR products 28% Development of a plan to reduce LIBOR exposures 25% Development of a plan to renegotiate LIBOR-linked contracts 24% 4.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade Dynamics in the Market for Federal Funds∗
    Trade Dynamics in the Market for Federal Funds∗ Gara Afonso Ricardo Lagos Federal Reserve Bank of New York New York University February 2012 Abstract We develop a model of the market for federal funds that explicitly accounts for its two distinctive features: banks have to search for a suitable counterparty, and once they have met, both parties negotiate the size of the loan and the repayment. The theory is used to answer a number of positive and normative questions: What are the determinants of the fed funds rate? How does the market reallocate funds? Is the market able to achieve an efficient reallocation of funds? We also use the model for theoretical and quantitative analyses of policy issues facing modern central banks. Keywords: Fed funds market, search, bargaining, over-the-counter JEL Classification: G1, C78, D83, E44 ∗We are especially grateful to Todd Keister for his generous feedback at various stages, and to Darrell Duffie for his discussion at the 2011 NBER Asset Pricing Meeting in Stanford. We also thank Tan Wang, our discussant at the 46th Annual Conference of the Western Finance Association. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. 1 Introduction In the United States, financial institutions keep reserve balances at the Federal Reserve Banks to meet requirements, earn interest, or to clear financial transactions. The market for federal funds is an interbank over-the-counter market for unsecured, mostly overnight loans of dollar reserves held at Federal Reserve Banks.
    [Show full text]
  • Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards
    5 Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards In this chapter we will learn about • Eurodollar Deposits • Eurodollar Futures Contracts, • Hedging strategies using ED Futures, • Forward Rate Agreements, • Pricing FRAs. • Hedging FRAs using ED Futures, • Constructing the Libor Zero Curve from ED deposit rates and ED Fu- tures. 5.1 EURODOLLAR DEPOSITS As discussed in chapter 2, Eurodollar (ED) deposits are dollar deposits main- tained outside the USA. They are exempt from Federal Reserve regulations that apply to domestic deposit markets. The interest rate that applies to ED deposits in interbank transactions is the LIBOR rate. The LIBOR spot market has maturities from a few days to 10 years but liquidity is the greatest 69 70 CHAPTER 5: EURODOLLAR FUTURES AND FORWARDS Table 5.1 LIBOR spot rates Dates 7day 1mth. 3mth 6mth 9mth 1yr LIBOR 1.000 1.100 1.160 1.165 1.205 1.337 within one year. Table 5.1 shows LIBOR spot rates over a year as of January 14th 2004. In the ED deposit market, deposits are traded between banks for ranges of maturities. If one million dollars is borrowed for 45 days at a LIBOR rate of 5.25%, the interest is 45 Interest = 1m × 0.0525 = $6562.50 360 The rate quoted assumes settlement will occur two days after the trade. Banks are willing to lend money to firms at the Libor rate provided their credit is comparable to these strong banks. If their credit is weaker, then the lending bank may quote a rate as a spread over the Libor rate. 5.2 THE TED SPREAD Banks that offer LIBOR deposits have the potential to default.
    [Show full text]
  • Results on the FISIM Tests on Maturity and Default Risk
    SNA/M1.13/02 8th Meeting of the Advisory Expert Group on National Accounts, 29-31 May 2013, Luxembourg Agenda item: 2 Topic: FISIM Introduction During 2011/2012, tests were carried out in Europe on the inclusion/exclusion of maturity and credit default risk, as recommended by the European Task force on FISIM. Based on the results of these tests the EU Directors of Macro-economic Statistics (DMES) decided, in November 2012, to keep the present FISIM allocation method. This means that, in the 2010 ESA, a single reference rate based on inter-bank loans and deposits will continued to be applied, and that the default risk will not be excluded from FISIM. The ISWGNA Task Force on FISIM assessed the report of the European Task force based on a note by the ISWGNA containing a summary of the results of the FISIM-exercise, as conducted by the EU countries and two non-EU respondents. The summary also includes the main issues related to the debate on credit default risk. Guidance on documentation provided The final report of the ISWGNA FISIM Task Force. Main issues to be discussed The AEG is asked to provide opinions on the following recommendations made in the report: • For international trade in FISIM: FISIM should be calculated by at least two groups of currencies (national and foreign currency). • The reference rate for a specific currency need not be the same for FISIM providers resident in different economies. Although they should be expected, under normal circumstances, to be relatively close and so national statistics agencies are encouraged to use partner country information where national estimates are not available.
    [Show full text]
  • EURIBOR Reform
    10th September 2019 Important Disclaimer: The following is provided for information purposes only. It does not constitute advice (including legal, tax, accounting or regulatory advice). No representation is made as to its completeness, accuracy or suitability for any purpose. Recipients should take such professional advice in relation to the matters discussed as they deem appropriate to their circumstances. Frequently Asked Questions: EURIBOR reform This Frequently Asked Questions (“FAQ”) document, which may be updated from time to time, contains information regarding the EURIBOR benchmark reforms. 1. What is EURIBOR? The Euro Interbank Offered Rate (EURIBOR) is a daily reference rate published by the European Money Markets Institute (EMMI). 2. What is happening to the EURIBOR benchmark methodology? EMMI is reforming the EURIBOR benchmark by moving to a ‘hybrid’ methodology and reformulating the EURIBOR specification. The hybrid EURIBOR methodology is currently being gradually implemented (see Question 10 for further information). In Q18 of the EMMI - EURIBOR questions and answers, EMMI describes the hybrid methodology (described further in Q6 below) as a, “robust evolution of the current quote-based methodology”. EMMI has reformulated the EURIBOR specification, separating the Underlying Interest from the benchmark methodology, in order to clarify the former. EURIBOR's “Underlying Interest” is: “the rate at which wholesale funds in euro could be obtained by credit institutions in the EU and EFTA countries in the unsecured money market.” (https://www.emmi-benchmarks.eu/euribor- org/about-euribor.html)”. In Q18 of the EMMI - EURIBOR questions and answers, EMMI states that EURIBOR reform “does not change EURIBOR’s Underlying Interest, which has always been seeking to measure banks’ costs of borrowing in unsecured money markets”.
    [Show full text]
  • Evidence from a Financial Crisis Emanuela Giacomini *, Xiaohong
    Effects of Bank Lending Shocks on Real Activity: Evidence from a Financial Crisis a a Emanuela Giacomini *, Xiaohong (Sara) Wang a Graduate School of Business, University of Florida, Gainesville, FL 32611-7168, USA January 15, 2012 Abstract U.S. banks experienced dramatic declines in capital and liquidity during the financial crisis of 2007-2009. We study the effect of shocks on banks’ capital and liquidity positions on their borrowers’ investment decisions. The recent financial crisis serves as a natural experiment in the sense that the crisis was not expected by banks ex-ante, and had a detrimental but heterogeneous impact on banks’ capitals and liquidity positions ex-post. Consistent with our hypothesis, we find that borrowers of more affected banks reduced more investment during the crisis. We find that borrowing firms whose banks have a higher level of non-performing loans and lower level of tier one capital, hold less liquid asset, and experience greater stock price drop tend to invest less in the capital expenditure when comparing investment before and during the crisis. Shocks on banks, however, have limited effect on firm R&D expenditures and net working capital. Our results suggest that shocks on banks’ capital and liquidity positions negatively affect borrowers’ investment levels, in particular their capital expenditures. EFM Classification Codes: 510, 520. * Corresponding author. Tel.: 352 392 8913; fax: 352 392 0301. E-mail address: [email protected] (Emanuela Giacomini), [email protected] (Xiaohong (Sara) Wang). 1 1. Introduction During the 2007-2009 financial crisis, U.S. banks experienced dramatic declines in capital from bad loan write-downs and collateralized debt obligation value plunges.
    [Show full text]