September 18, 2019

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

September 18, 2019 September 18, 2019 Overnight Borrowing Liquidity Issues Overnight borrowing rates have spiked unexpectedly this week, raising questions about whether there’s a looming liquidity issue in the market. The NY Fed implemented borderline-emergency measures to inject liquidity this week. It bought $50B in Treasurys yesterday and will buy another $75B today. The basic mechanism is that the Fed will overpay a bank to buy some of its Treasury holdings. This gives the banks cash, which in turn they can lend to other banks. Liquidity. Or as some might call it, Quantitative Easing. Jay Powell won’t call it that, but some might… The headline culprits according to the talking heads I trust the least: 1. Corporate tax bills - money was withdrawn from bank and money market accounts to pay quarterly and annual taxes (Monday was the corporate extension deadline), which reduced the amount available as deposits to banks 2. Last week’s Treasury auction - the cash payment for the $78B T auction was due yesterday and banks typically pay for their Treasurys by borrowing in the overnight market Call me a cynic, but while these may be contributing factors, are they really to blame for a liquidity event that caused some borrowing rates to spike 3x? We were hearing from traders that repo rates got as high as 8% - 10%. Think about it – you are contractually obligated to buy something (or pay for something), you will pay 10% for one night of borrower if you have to, right? How high does the interest rate need to go before you willingly default on whatever it was that required you to go borrow in the first place? Banks don’t borrower the way consumers borrower. They fund day to day operations through overnight loans as their deposits fluctuate, sort of like a line of credit they draw on and repay quickly. These are called repos (short for repurchase agreements). Repos are generally overnight loans backed by Treasurys as collateral. Some days banks need to borrow, some days they can lend. But if they don’t have cash available (or in a financial crisis meltdown, don’t want to lend), then borrowers have to pay a higher interest rate to entice them to lend. This most commonly happens at quarter and year end when banks hoard cash for the balance sheet snapshot. What is unusual is that it is happening mid-month. Banks are required to maintain a set reserve (generally 10%) of their deposits at the Fed. Anything above that amount is referred to as excess reserves. If Big Bank has $1T in deposits, it must maintain a balance of $100B at the Federal Reserve. After the crisis, the Fed wanted to encourage banks to keep an even bigger cushion, so it began paying Interest on Excess Reserves, or IOER. The Fed might say, “Dear Big Bank, you are required to keep $100B with us, so we aren’t paying you for that. But we will pay you 2.10% on any amount above that.” IOER. It usually is set in the same range as Fed Funds to avoid arbitrage scenarios. And it incentivized banks to keep a bigger cushion of cash. It worked. Banks were getting risk free interest from the federal government, so they maintained larger cash balances at the Fed. But it’s also at least partially to blame for why banks might be reluctant to lend from 10800 Sikes Pl Suite 220 (704) 887-9880 Charlotte, NC 28827 Pensford.com September 18, 2019 time to time. “Why loan money to Risky Commercial Real Estate Borrower when I can get a risk-free return from Uncle Sam each and every night?” Extrapolate that even further, and banks might ask themselves, “Why lend to a fellow bank at Fed Funds when I am getting 2.10% from the Fed?” This dilemma has been exacerbated by the flattening yield curve. It’s easy to justify getting 2.10% from the Fed while maintaining flexibility when the alternative 10 Year Treasury is yielding 1.50%. And when the alternative Risky Commercial Real Estate Borrower is borrowing at a spread over 1.50%. Easy fix – lower the IOER. If you remove the incentive to maintain excess reserves, it will instead encourage banks to lend, right? Yes, in fact the Fed will likely do that at today’s meeting. But there’s a catch…well, two actually. 1. Panic – during periods of stress or fear, do you really care that the return from the Fed is 1.75% instead of 2.0% from a fellow bank? I was at Wachovia when it went under and I can assure you there was no amount of interest we could have paid to other banks to entice them to loan to us, even overnight 2. Lowering IOER only helps if banks have excess reserves to begin with Reverse QE (aka Balance Sheet Normalization) has reduced the cash banks have available because the Fed stopped buying their Treasurys each month. Here’s a graph from the St Louis Fed that shows how much excess reserves have fallen recently. 10800 Sikes Pl Suite 220 (704) 887-9880 Charlotte, NC 28827 Pensford.com September 18, 2019 Fewer excess reserves coupled with liquidity fears lead to a spike in overnight borrowing costs. It remains to be seen whether that will resolve itself quickly or if this is the start of a scary trend. The Real-World Implication For now, our lives probably don’t change much. But the risk of a liquidity-driven downturn has increased substantially. It’s not a definite, it’s just a greater possibility. Without liquidity, the system grinds to a halt. Sure, Big Bank may pay 10% today just to fulfill their legal obligation, but what changes do they make going forward? “Hey, loan allocations need to be scaled back because we may need that cash instead.” Now imagine the ripple effects from decisions like that… “I didn’t even know what a repo was before this morning, now you’re suggesting it might impact my ability to get a loan?” - Frustrated Commercial Real Estate Borrower. Actually, I can think of one prominent repo rate you might have known about before today…SOFR. The presumptive replacement for LIBOR is a repo rate. Readers of this newsletter know I am very skeptical about SOFR replacing LIBOR in 2021, and one of my primary reasons for this skepticism is that it swings wildly. On the one hand, the fact that LIBOR never flinches during periods of volatility like yesterday confirms the reason why the regulators want to move away from it. It feels…not accurate… On the other hand, market driven securities are subject to market driven volatility, which can create chaos. Here’s a graph of SOFR over the last year. Notice how it spikes at quarter and year end when banks don’t want to lend out cash to other banks because they are about to take a snapshot of their balance sheet. It spiked to 3.15% on 12/31/18. Yesterday, it spiked to 2.43%. LIBOR is still cruising along at 2.05%... The first implication for a SOFR-based loan is that if you have a payment reset on that day, your monthly bill could spike for no good reason. But that’s not why I don’t believe SOFR will replace LIBOR in 2021. That can be addressed by averaging the daily resets. More importantly, this inconsistency makes it difficult for traders to extrapolate a forward curve. How can you accurately price a swap or a cap with those sort of spikes? As one trader put it to me, “How would you sell a cap at 2.00% on that graph?” Good question. I wouldn’t. And neither would you. You can’t account for the spikes. 10800 Sikes Pl Suite 220 (704) 887-9880 Charlotte, NC 28827 Pensford.com September 18, 2019 Source: Bloomberg Finance, LP Oh Yeah, There’s an FOMC Meeting Today Who knew the FOMC 25bps rate cut today would not be the headliner? Markets have an 83% probability of a 25bps cut, and a 17% probability of a 50bps cut. Count me in the 25bps cut camp. But more importantly, what signals does Powell send about future cuts? The market wants a dovish Fed, and if his comments are interpreted as hawkish (or, at least not dovish enough), the market may puke. The liquidity issues this week will only magnify the response if the market believes the Fed is tone deaf. Generally, this material is for informational purposes only and is not intended as an offer or solicitation for the purchase or sale of any financial instrument or as an official confirmation of any transaction. Your receipt of this material does not create a client relationship with us and we are not acting as fiduciary or advisory capacity to you by providing the information herein. All market prices, data and other information are not warranted as to completeness or accuracy and are subject to change without notice. This material may contain information that is privileged, confidential, legally privileged, and/or exempt from disclosure under applicable law. Though the information herein may discuss certain legal and tax aspects of financial instruments, Pensford, LLC does not provide legal or tax advice. The contents herein are the copyright material of Pensford, LLC and shall not be copied, reproduced, or redistributed without the express written permission of Pensford, LLC. 10800 Sikes Pl Suite 220 (704) 887-9880 Charlotte, NC 28827 Pensford.com .
Recommended publications
  • 20. the Policy Conundrum of Financial Market Complexity Hilton
    20. The Policy Conundrum of Financial Market Complexity Hilton L. Root George Mason University “Your own best footstep may unleash the very cascade that carries you away, and neither you nor anyone else can predict which grain will unleash the tiny or the cataclysmic alteration.” —Stuart Kauffman The Origins of Order: Self-Organization and Selection in Evolution (Kauffman 1993) Abstract: The first global financial sector crash eludes conventional assessments of sector risk. Singling out the usual culprits—the housing bubble, executive pay, regulators, rating agencies, risk models, and global imbalances—fails to explain either the unpredictability or the rapidity of the collapse of 2008, which in many ways resembled the avalanche of a sand pile, where at some point of criticality, avalanches occur that bear no relationship to the grain of sand that triggered them. Since appropriate financial regulation is part of the remedy, policymakers should recognize that success will depend on a more refined knowledge of why some initial events may have prompted an avalanche, while others did not. 1 I. ECONOMICS AND THE SAND PILE A pile of sand. What could be a less likely metaphor for a global financial system that contains close to $200 trillion in assets worldwide? Yet an avalanche in that sand pile caused a colossal financial meltdown that destroyed at least 15 percent of national wealth in the United States alone.1 Which grain of sand triggered the avalanche? We cannot know with certainty where it was or why it moved. Conventional risk models used by economists are poor at predicting which set or category of transactions pushed the markets into a system-wide free fall, and they fail completely at expressing the market in collapse.
    [Show full text]
  • FEDERAL FUNDS Marvin Goodfriend and William Whelpley
    Page 7 The information in this chapter was last updated in 1993. Since the money market evolves very rapidly, recent developments may have superseded some of the content of this chapter. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Richmond, Virginia 1998 Chapter 2 FEDERAL FUNDS Marvin Goodfriend and William Whelpley Federal funds are the heart of the money market in the sense that they are the core of the overnight market for credit in the United States. Moreover, current and expected interest rates on federal funds are the basic rates to which all other money market rates are anchored. Understanding the federal funds market requires, above all, recognizing that its general character has been shaped by Federal Reserve policy. From the beginning, Federal Reserve regulatory rulings have encouraged the market's growth. Equally important, the federal funds rate has been a key monetary policy instrument. This chapter explains federal funds as a credit instrument, the funds rate as an instrument of monetary policy, and the funds market itself as an instrument of regulatory policy. CHARACTERISTICS OF FEDERAL FUNDS Three features taken together distinguish federal funds from other money market instruments. First, they are short-term borrowings of immediately available money—funds which can be transferred between depository institutions within a single business day. In 1991, nearly three-quarters of federal funds were overnight borrowings. The remainder were longer maturity borrowings known as term federal funds. Second, federal funds can be borrowed by only those depository institutions that are required by the Monetary Control Act of 1980 to hold reserves with Federal Reserve Banks.
    [Show full text]
  • Stressed, Not Frozen: the Federal Funds Market in the Financial Crisis
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Stressed, Not Frozen: The Federal Funds Market in the Financial Crisis Gara Afonso Anna Kovner Antoinette Schoar Staff Report no. 437 March 2010 Revised May 2011 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. Stressed, Not Frozen: The Federal Funds Market in the Financial Crisis Gara Afonso, Anna Kovner, and Antoinette Schoar Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 437 March 2010; revised May 2011 JEL classification: G21, G01, D40, E40 Abstract We examine the importance of liquidity hoarding and counterparty risk in the U.S. overnight interbank market during the financial crisis of 2008. Our findings suggest that counterparty risk plays a larger role than does liquidity hoarding: the day after Lehman Brothers’ bankruptcy, loan terms become more sensitive to borrower characteristics. In particular, poorly performing large banks see an increase in spreads of 25 basis points, but are borrowing 1 percent less, on average. Worse performing banks do not hoard liquidity. While the interbank market does not freeze entirely, it does not seem to expand to meet latent demand. Key words: fed funds, financial crisis, liquidity, interbank lending, hoarding Afonso: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (e-mail: [email protected]).
    [Show full text]
  • Trade Dynamics in the Market for Federal Funds∗
    Trade Dynamics in the Market for Federal Funds∗ Gara Afonso Ricardo Lagos Federal Reserve Bank of New York New York University February 2012 Abstract We develop a model of the market for federal funds that explicitly accounts for its two distinctive features: banks have to search for a suitable counterparty, and once they have met, both parties negotiate the size of the loan and the repayment. The theory is used to answer a number of positive and normative questions: What are the determinants of the fed funds rate? How does the market reallocate funds? Is the market able to achieve an efficient reallocation of funds? We also use the model for theoretical and quantitative analyses of policy issues facing modern central banks. Keywords: Fed funds market, search, bargaining, over-the-counter JEL Classification: G1, C78, D83, E44 ∗We are especially grateful to Todd Keister for his generous feedback at various stages, and to Darrell Duffie for his discussion at the 2011 NBER Asset Pricing Meeting in Stanford. We also thank Tan Wang, our discussant at the 46th Annual Conference of the Western Finance Association. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. 1 Introduction In the United States, financial institutions keep reserve balances at the Federal Reserve Banks to meet requirements, earn interest, or to clear financial transactions. The market for federal funds is an interbank over-the-counter market for unsecured, mostly overnight loans of dollar reserves held at Federal Reserve Banks.
    [Show full text]
  • Volatility in the Overnight Money-Market Rate in Bangladesh: Recent Experiences PN 0707 Md
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by University of Southern Queensland ePrints Volatility in the Overnight Money-Market Rate in Bangladesh: Recent Experiences PN 0707 Md. Shahiduzzaman* Mahmud Salahuddin Naser* Abstract This paper tries to investigate the pattern of volatility in the overnight money market rate (call money rate) in Bangladesh using subjective judgment as well as econometric techniques during the period Jan '03 to Dec '06. The study results show significant variation in volatility during the sample period: a "clustering" of large and small variances of call money rate. In addition, there is strong evidence that the volatility shocks are quite persistent. The volatility in the call money rate perhaps reflects the effect of the open market operations and seasonal factors, and it is closely linked with the behavior of the repo rate. 1. Introduction Call money rate -the rate at which short term funds are lent and borrowed among banks- is the core of an overnight money market for credit. Volatility of the overnight money market rate (call money rate) is a very usual phenomenon for a well-functioning market. Market participants determine the rate according to their perceptions of the current and future liquidity condition in the market. Thus this rate reflects the supply and demand behavior of bank reserves, and hence, gives important signals to the central bank to understand the market pressure. Given this reasoning, the rate is often closely linked with other interest rates in the market or the foreign exchange rate. Therefore, many central banks implement policy in a way such that the call money rate does not deviate much from the central bank's policy rate.
    [Show full text]
  • Final Offering Circular Luxse
    OFFERING CIRCULAR U.S.$300,000,000 Banco do Brasil S.A. acting through its Grand Cayman branch 8.5% Subordinated Notes due 2014 Banco do Brasil S.A., a bank with limited liability organized as a sociedade anônima under the laws of the Federative Republic of Brazil (“Banco do Brasil” or the “Bank”), acting through its Grand Cayman branch (the “Grand Cayman Branch”), is issuing U.S.$300,000,000 aggregate principal amount of 8.5% Subordinated Notes due 2014 (the “Notes”). The Notes will mature on September 20, 2014, unless the maturity of the Notes is extended as a result of certain currency exchange or transfer restrictions being in effect on the maturity date, in which case the maturity of the Notes will be no later than March 20, 2016. The Notes will be subject to redemption only in the event of certain changes in Brazilian and other withholding taxes, subject to the prior approval of the Central Bank of Brazil (the “Central Bank”). In addition, if payment of interest or principal on the Notes would otherwise result in violation of capital adequacy ratios required of Brazilian banking institutions, payment of interest and principal will be suspended for the duration of that inadequacy. Interest on the Notes will accrue from and including September 20, 2004 and will be payable semi- annually in arrears on March 20 and September 20 of each year, commencing on March 20, 2005. See “Description of the Notes”. The Letter of Credit Custodian, on behalf of the Noteholders, will have the benefit of an irrevocable standby letter of credit (the “Letter of Credit”) provided by Credit Suisse First Boston, acting through its Cayman Islands branch (the “Letter of Credit Issuer”), to provide coverage (in an amount equal to three payments of scheduled interest on the Notes (plus an amount equal to 30 days of interest payable on three accrued payments of scheduled interest), and 18 months of fees (but not expenses) due and payable to the Trustee under the Indenture) in the event of the Bank’s inability to convert Brazilian Reais into U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • A Black Swan in the Money Market
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES A Black Swan in the Money Market John B. Taylor Stanford University John C. Williams Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco April 2008 Working Paper 2008-04 http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2008/wp08-04bk.pdf The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. A Black Swan in the Money Market* John B. Taylor Stanford University John C. Williams Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco First Version: February 21, 2008 Updated: April 2, 2008 ABSTRACT At the center of the financial market crisis of 2007-2008 was a highly unusual jump in spreads between the overnight inter-bank lending rate and term London inter-bank offer rates (Libor). Because many private loans are linked to Libor rates, the sharp increase in these spreads raised the cost of borrowing and interfered with monetary policy. The widening spreads became a major focus of the Federal Reserve, which took several actions—including the introduction of a new term auction facility (TAF)—to reduce them. This paper documents these developments and, using a no-arbitrage model of the term structure, tests various explanations, including increased risk and greater liquidity demands, while controlling for expectations of future interest rates. We show that increased counterparty risk between banks contributed to the rise in spreads and find no empirical evidence that the TAF has reduced spreads.
    [Show full text]
  • Trading Partners in the Interbank Lending Market
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Afonso, Gara; Kovner, Anna; Schoar, Antoinette Working Paper Trading partners in the interbank lending market Staff Report, No. 620 Provided in Cooperation with: Federal Reserve Bank of New York Suggested Citation: Afonso, Gara; Kovner, Anna; Schoar, Antoinette (2013) : Trading partners in the interbank lending market, Staff Report, No. 620, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New York, NY This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/93625 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Trading Partners in the Interbank Lending Market Gara Afonso Anna Kovner Antoinette Schoar Staff Report No.
    [Show full text]
  • Target Practice: Monetary Policy Implementation in a Post-Crisis Environment∗
    Target practice: Monetary policy implementation in a post-crisis environment∗ Elizabeth Klee and Viktors Stebunovs† December 10, 2012 Abstract Traditionally, the Federal Reserve targeted the federal funds rate, expecting this rate to transmit a monetary policy stance to other short-term and longer-term rates. However, at the height of the financial crisis, the pass-through from the federal funds rate to other short-term rates deteriorated. Furthermore, market participants reportedly anticipate that the inception of liquidity requirements might weaken the federal funds market and therefore its linkages with other money markets. At the same time, however, most anticipate that high quality collateral repo markets should remain active. We argue that, in principle, instead of the federal funds rate, the Federal Reserve can target the Treasury General Collateral repurchase agreement rate, and explore the Federal Reserve’s capacity to do so empirically. Our results suggest that a target repo rate might be an alternative policy tool to the target federal funds rate in the post-crisis environment. Keywords: target federal funds rate, Treasury general collateral repo rate, liquidity cov- erage requirements, liquidity effect, monetary policy implementation framework, open market operations, M3. ∗Very preliminary. Do not cite or quote without permission. The views expressed in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of anyone else associated with the Federal Reserve System. †We thank the discussant, Gabriel P´erez Quiro, and the participants of the ECB workshop “The post-crisis design of the operational framework for the implementation of monetary policy” and seminar participants at the Swiss National Bank for helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Interest Rate Determination in the Interbank Market
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO. 351 / APRIL 2004 INTEREST RATE DETERMINATION IN THE INTERBANK MARKET by Vítor Gaspar Gabriel Pérez Quirós and Hugo Rodríguez Mendizábal WORKING PAPER SERIES NO. 351 / APRIL 2004 INTEREST RATE DETERMINATION IN THE INTERBANK MARKET1 by Vítor Gaspar 2 Gabriel Pérez Quirós 3 and Hugo Rodríguez Mendizábal 4 In 2004 all publications will carry This paper can be downloaded without charge from a motif taken http://www.ecb.int or from the Social Science Research Network from the €100 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=533013. 1 The views expressed are authors’ own and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB, the Bank of Spain or the Eurosystem.We thank the anonymous referee, H-J Klockers, Fernando Restoy, Ulrich Bindseil and seminar participants at the Bank of Spain, ECB, Centra and University of Alicante for helpful comments and suggestions.We also thank the European Banking Federation for graciously sharing their data. Rodríguez Mendizábal aknowledges financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology through grant SEC2000-0684 and SEC2003-0036 and from the Barcelona Economics Program of CREA. 2 European Central Bank 3 Banco de España and CEPR 4 Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona and CENTRA © European Central Bank, 2004 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Internet http://www.ecb.int Fax +49 69 1344 6000 Telex 411 144 ecb d All rights reserved. Reproduction for educational and non- commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Are There No Intraday Money Markets? (Why Is There an Overnight One??)
    Why are there no intraday money markets? (why is there an overnight one??) By Antoine Martin, Jamie McAndrews (M&M) Discussion Paolo Angelini Bank of Italy A summary • Intraday mkt can in principle be organized like an ON mkt • Desirability depends on several factors/mechanisms • Paper carefully discusses such factors, but does not attempt to draw a normative conclusion • Analysis distinguishes between two cases concerning supply of ON reserves by cb: i. Supply at positive marginal cost ii. Supply at zero marginal cost • Under (ii) paper argues that distinction between intraday and overnight becomes blurred; usefulness of overnight market is questioned 2 Overall comments • Thought-provoking paper, full of insights • Paper raises interesting issues concerning monetary policy operational framework and overnight market that may need further analysis (not necessarily in this paper); key question is: Do the benefits generated by the overnight market exceed its costs? • Revealed preference approach (confirmed by recent New Zealand experience) suggests that answer so far is ”Yes” 3 Interesting insight “In both [the overnight and the intraday market] the ‘price’ is a policy variable and the supply is under the control of the central bank ” (p. 11) Therefore, “The price of funds in the overnight market does not aggregate information in the way other markets usually do ” (p. 11) Same would hold true in an intraday mkt 4 So what is the purpose of an intraday market, or of the ON market? Section 3.a: M&M convincingly argue that an intraday market could be organized like an overnight mkt • Thus, they review arguments for and against overnight mkt, checking whether they also apply to intraday mkt • Distinguish between systems in which overnight funds are provided at a positive marginal costs by cbs, and systems in which this cost is zero 5 Section 3.b: Arguments in favor of an overnight/intraday mkt when marginal cost of ON funds is positive • Little literature on issue.
    [Show full text]
  • Focus 3 the Usefulness of TARGET2 Transaction Data for the Analysis Of
    Box 3 The usefulness of TARGET2 transaction data for the analysis of the unsecured overnight money market Despite the importance of money markets, granular information on transactions is generally not readily available. Overnight transactions mainly take place over the counter, and when recording these, the few trading platforms typically focus on certain jurisdictions. For the euro area, daily information on unsecured overnight lending is collected for a panel of banks, and the weighted average of their rate contributions gives rise to the euro overnight index average (EONIA) as the reference rate for the overnight unsecured segment. However, the panel bank contributions are not at the level of individual transactions, but daily aggregates of their lending activity. As of mid-2016, money market transaction data will be collected for the euro area under the Money Market Statistical Reporting Regulation, under which, initially, 53 banks will report.1 TARGET2 (the Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross settlement Express Transfer system) offers an unparalleled source of granular overnight money market information. While information on overnight unsecured loans in TARGET2 is not directly available, it can be accessed by screening the set of transactions that occur through the payment system for the settlement of the two legs of an interbank loan.2 This method has long been used worldwide and allows for the reconstructing of significant parts of the unsecured overnight money market activity. The large coverage of banks in TARGET2 provides a comprehensive picture of the unsecured overnight money market. A key benefit of using TARGET2 data for analysis is the high number of banks (around 1,000) participating in the payment system.3 Although a small fraction of overnight market trading settles privately outside TARGET2, TARGET2 data still provide a close representation of the euro area overnight market.
    [Show full text]