Perestroika and Production : Management's Response to Reform
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
PERESTROIKA AND PRODUCTION : MANAGEMENT'S RESPONSE TO REFORM Susan J . Lin z Michigan State Universit y Working Paper #5 7 March 198 9 Data for this study were produced by the Soviet Intervie w Project . The current Working Paper Series is supported b y Contract No . 804-13 from the National Council for Soviet and Eas t European Research, James R . Millar, Principal Investigator . International Programs and Studies of the University of Illinoi s Urbana-Champaign and the Institute for Sino-Soviet Studies o f George Washington University have also provided support that i s much appreciated . The analysis and interpretations in this stud y are those of the author, not necessarily of the sponsors . Copyright 0 Soviet Interview Project NOTE * This paper was distributed at the NATO Annual Economic s Colloquium in March, 1989 and has therefore been in the hands o f most Government specialists since that time . It contains : (a) A concise summary of Soviet economic reform in the firs t three years of Gorbachev's reign, already somewhat dated by event s since, but a useful reminder to the specialist of evolution an d contradictions, and a valuable account and reference for th e general reader . (b) An analysis of whether enterprise management, o r management training, has been a constraint on the effort t o accelerate economic growth, raise the technological level o f industry, and improve the quantity and quality of consumer goods . This analysis includes : (c) The results of surveys reported in the Soviet press t o gauge management's response to perestroika, as contrasted wit h evidence from intensive interviews with recent emigrants who hel d responsible positions in the Soviet economic bureaucracy . (d) An examination of management as a factor of productio n and the kinds of decisions Soviet managers make, and the element s which affect these decisions . (e) An analysis of management's response to new economi c conditions produced by perestroika, which concludes that Wester n analysts would be wise to question the view prevailing in th e Soviet press that Soviet managers are incapable of working in a competitive environment . Rather, rational managers will b e reluctant to alter their decisions in light of intrinsi c inconsistencies and partial implementation of reform . ---------- -------------------------------- - *Prepared by the staff of the National Council . Perestroika and Production : Management's Response to Reform Susan J . Lin z Associate Professo r Department of Economic s 101 Marshall Hal l Michigan State Universit y East Lansing, Michigan 48824-1038 (517) 353-796 1 This paper was prepared for the Annual Economics Colloquium at NATO (March 1989) . Perestroika and Production : Management's Response to Reform The economic reforms proposed in the first three years of Mikhai l Gorbache v ' s tenure as General Secretary have been impressive, embracing nearl y every sector of the economy and providing for changes in the economic syste m that most western experts previously thought would never be seriousl y considered by Soviet leaders .1 Reform rhetoric is not unique to the curren t leadership, however . Gorbachev's emphasis on reform stems in part from th e tradition in Soviet society of the political leadership seeking to improve th e performance of the economy through organizational changes, policy change s (investment, wage, or price level changes, for example), and changes in th e criteria by which economic performance is measured . So frequent have been th e reform efforts in recent decades that Gertrude Schroeder describes the Sovie t economy as trudging on a "treadmill" of reforms . 2 The tradition of reform is only part of the explanation for Gorbachev' s ambitious program for socioeconomic reconstruction . Perhaps more importan t are the complex problems the current leadership faces ; a "pre-crisis " situation which Gorbachev has argued could end catastrophically unless radica l measures are implemented . 3 Economic factors -- stagnating growth rates , rising energy costs, declining productivity, lagging technology, a growin g foreign trade deficit, regional labor shortages, a rising military burden , poor agricultural performance -- tended to dominate early discussions of th e need for reform . Social and political factors have since become equall y powerful motivating factors in the call for change . 4 In an effort to jump-start the Soviet economy and circumvent th e impending crisis, Gorbachev initially relied on "traditional" measures to improve economic performance . Labor discipline, anti-corruption, an d anti-alcohol campaigns, plus the wholesale replacement of administrativ e personnel, were implemented in 1985-1986 to reverse declining labo r productivity . 5 A capital modernization program, based on an increase i n total capital investment by 5 percent annually from 1986 to 1990, was t o permit the reconstruction, re-equipping, and retooling of existing industria l facilities . Gorbachev called for the replacement of over one-third of th e total capital stock by 1990 (doubling the retirement rates for capita l assets), and placed a greater emphasis on quality -- 90 percent of al l machinery was to meet "world standards" by 1990, compared to about 20 percen t in 1985 . 6 Finally, organizational changes were introduced in an effort t o streamline the economic bureaucracy by consolidating or eliminatin g administrative positions . 7 These traditional reform measures were t o generate sufficient productivity gains to achieve the economic growth rat e targeted by the Twelfth Five-Year Plan . Gains in economic performance achieved in 1986 by traditional refor m measures were insufficient to meet Gorbachev's goals of uskoreniye (acceleration in the growth of output), intensifikatsiya (improved efficienc y in resource utilization), and perestroika (restructuring the economi c bureaucracy) . 8 Rather than drop these goals, Gorbachev pushed forward i n mid-1987 with a series of "radical" reform measures to fundamentall y restructure the Soviet economy . 9 Central to this version of reform is th e decentralization of economic decision-making by curtailing central directiv e planning and expanding the rights and responsibilities of industria l enterprises over production and distribution . The components of the radica l reform package directed toward decentralizing decision-making include : (i) the law on state enterprise, (ii) the joint venture decree, and (iii) the laws o n cooperatives and leasing . Under the Law on State Enterprise, Soviet industrial firms are grante d more responsibility for formulating annual plans and acquiring the necessar y inputs by direct contracting . 10 Managers and workers' collectives ar e accorded more autonomy in production decisions, and are to be guided in thei r decision-making by improved performance criteria and enhanced materia l incentives . Improvements in the performance criteria are to include a comprehensive revision of wholesale and retail prices, profit as the primar y success indicator, and performance-based pay for workers . The law encourage s managers to negotiate all aspects of production and exchange, with the righ t to mutually determine selected prices . Firms are permitted to reinvest a portion of their profits on a self-directed basis to facilitate industria l expansion and technological advance . Firms also are granted the right t o allocate ruble credit balances to alternative uses . 11 Firms unsuccessful i n generating profitable production under the new conditions face bankruptcy . Gorbachev proposed the legalization of joint ventures as a secon d measure to decentralize decision-making in the economic bureaucracy . A decre e approved by the USSR Council of Ministers on 13 January 1987 authorized Sovie t and foreign firms to form limited liability companies, with foreign control o f up to 49 percent of the equity . Joint ventures represent a devolution o f Gosplan ' s control over the economic bureaucracy because these firms have th e right to make decisions regarding production and distribution independent o f Gosplan's material balance planning . Planners perceive potential benefit s that outweigh the loss of direct control over these firms -- an opportunity t o gain access to Western technology and managerial and technical training, t o increase exports of Soviet manufactured goods and obtain hard-currency, to generate additional investment, and to produce domestically what previousl y had been imported . Despite a rather adverse economic environment, 30 0 applications for joint ventures were submitted to the Ministry of Financ e within the first year, of which 50 were registered . 12 To accelerate th e formation of joint ventures with Western producers, the Soviet governmen t proposed new regulations, effective January 1989, that (i) allow Western firm s to own the majority of equity, (ii) make profit repatriation easier, (iii ) reduce the joint venture ' s tax liability, and (iv) lower tariffs on equipment brought into the USSR.13 As a consequence, Serge Raslovleff reports 25 2 joint ventures registered as of February 1989 . 1 4 The producer and consumer cooperatives allowed by the Law o n Cooperatives, approved by the Supreme Soviet in May 1988 and put into effect 1 July 1988, 15 are an important component of Gorbachev's efforts t o decentralize decision-making and accelerate the production of consumer good s and services in the Soviet economy . At the same time, however, cooperative s and leaseholding arrangements have been one of the most