<<

The Castle Lectures in Ethics, Politics, and Economics

Darin Christensen & David D. Laitin

African States Since :

ORDER, DEMOCRACY, & DEVELOPMENT

Yale University Press, New Haven and London Copyright © 2019 by Darin Christensen and David D. Laitin All rights reserved. This book may not be reproduced, in whole or in part, including illustrations, in any form (beyond that copying permitted by Sections 107 and 108 of the U.S. Copyright Law and except by reviewers for the public press), without written permission from the publishers.

Yale University Press books may be purchased in quantity for educational, business, or promotional use. For information, please e-mail [email protected] (U.S. office) or [email protected] (U.K. office).

Printed in the United States of America.

Library of Congress Control Number: 2018953649 ISBN 978-0-300-22661-4 (hardcover : alk. paper)

A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.

This paper meets the requirements of ANSI/NISO Z39.48-1992 (Permanence of Paper).

10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 For those many students of African politics whose research has guided us to rethink the region’s past and see its future more clearly. Parts of this book were given as the Castle Lectures in Yale’s Program in Ethics, Politics, and Economics, delivered by David Laitin in 2015.

The Castle Lectures were endowed by Mr. John K. Castle. They honor his ancestor the Reverend James Pierpoint, one of Yale’s original founders. Given by established public figures, Castle Lectures are intended to promote reflection on the moral foundation of society and government and to enhance understanding of ethical issues facing individuals in our complex modern society. Contents

List of Figures ix List of Tables xiii Preface xv Region & Country Codes xix Introduction 1

I From Great Expectations to Unfulfilled Dreams 11 Chapter 1: The Charismatic Founders and Their Dreams 13 Chapter 2: Lag in Human Development 31 Chapter 3: Lag in Democracy 49 Chapter 4: Lag in Social Order 83

II Geographic & Historical Constraints 113 Chapter 5: Geography and Demography 115 Chapter 6: Extractive Institutions 133 Chapter 7: The Missionaries 155 Chapter 8: The Partition of Africa 167 Chapter 9: The Colonial State 189

III Post-Independence Policies 205 Chapter 10: Cultural Policy 207 Chapter 11: Foreign Policy 227 Chapter 12: Economic Policy 243 viii

IV Toward a New Era? 269 Chapter 13: Democratization and the “Third Wave” 271 Chapter 14: Economic Stabilization 299 Chapter 15: Rebuilding War-Torn States 319 Chapter 16: Conclusion 347 References 351 Index of Authors 377 General Index 385 Figures

1 Conceptual Framework 5

1.1 Number of Independent States, 1940-2010 14 1.2 17 1.3 19 1.4 21 1.5 Léopold Senghor 23 1.6 Ahmed Sékou Touré 24 1.7 25 1.8 Obafemi Awolowo 27 1.9 27

2.1 GDP per Capita by Region, 1960-1990 32 2.2 GDP per Capita in Selected Cases, 1960-1990 33 2.3 Share of Population in Poverty 34 2.4 Years of Schooling by Region, 1960-1990 35 2.5 Infant Mortality by Country, 1960-1990 38

3.1 Average Polity Score by Region, 1960-1990 53 3.2 Deluge of Coups in Africa 54 3.3 Regime Change in Selected Cases, 1960-1990 56 3.4 Nigeria’s Largest Ethnic Groups 56 3.5 “Nigeria at 49” 67 3.6 Average Governance Score in 1996 68 3.7 Electoral Quality, 1960-1990 78 3.8 Ugandan MP’s Scorecard 79

4.1 Failed State-Years by Region and Decade 85 4.2 Trends in Armed Conflict by Region, 1960-1999 86 x

4.3 Cumulative Deaths from Civil Wars 94 4.4 Trade-off Between Coups and Insurgency 110

5.1 Difficult Geographies 116 5.2 Population Distribution in the Democratic Republic of the Congo 116 5.3 Hinterland Geographies 117 5.4 Population Distribution in 117 5.5 Favorable Geographies 119 5.6 Population Distribution in Rwanda 119 5.7 GDP per Capita by Geography, 1960-2008 122 5.8 Probability of Rebellion by Distance from Country’s Capital City 123 5.9 Ethnic Fractionalization and Distance to the Equator 125 5.10 Correlation Between Malaria Deaths and Distance to the Equator 126 5.11 Conceptual Framework: Geography & Demography 130

6.1 Settler Mortality and Economic Development 135 6.2 Cumulative Slave Exports by Country 140 6.3 Slavery and an Economic Reversal of Fortune 141 6.4 Economic Development by Exposure to the Slave Trade 142 6.5 Slave Exports and State Development 143 6.6 Conceptual Framework: Extractive Institutions 154

7.1 Christian Missionary Activity and Contemporary School Enrollment 161 7.2 Protestant Missionaries and Democracy 162 7.3 Contemporary Religious Composition in African States 163 7.4 Correlates of Muslim Concentration 164 7.5 Conceptual Framework: The Missionaries 166

8.1 The Berlin Conference, 1884-85 168 8.2 Murdock’s 1959 Map of Ethnic Homelands 170 8.3 Partitioned Populations and Economic Development 171 8.4 Partitioned Groups and Conflict Incidence 172 8.5 The Congo Crisis 176 8.6 The Casamance Region of Senegal 178 8.7 Somalia’s Ethnic Territories 182 8.8 Conceptual Framework: The Partition of Africa 188

9.1 Income Tax (% GDP) by Region 195 xi

9.2 Human Capital and Infrastructure by Colonizer, 1961-65 196 9.3 Political Institutions Prior to Independence 197 9.4 Convergence in Average Polity Scores 198 9.5 Conceptual Framework: The Colonial State 202

10.1 Linguistic Distance and Economic Development 212 10.2 Indigenous Language Instruction and Learning Outcomes 215 10.3 Language and Interpersonal Relations 217 10.4 Busia, Kenya, and Meatu, 219 10.5 Conceptual Framework: Cultural Policy 225

11.1 Changing Composition of Conflict, 1816-2008 236 11.2 Number of Civil Wars by Country, 1960-2010 237 11.3 Conceptual Framework: Foreign Policy 241

12.1 Income Growth in vs. Côte d’Ivoire 246 12.2 Increased Disbursements of Foreign Aid to Africa 256 12.3 Conceptual Framework: Economic Policy 266

13.1 Political Liberalization in Africa, 1980-2010 272 13.2 273 13.3 The Increased Prevalence of Election Monitoring 282 13.4 Opposition Vote Share in African Elections 291

14.1 Recent Increases in GDP per Capita 300 14.2 ’s Outlying Economic Performance 302 14.3 Improvements in Governance and Economic Growth 305 14.4 Manufacturing Employment and Economic Development 309 14.5 Adjusted (“Genuine”) Savings as a Percentage of Gross National Income 312

15.1 African Countries Mired in Conflict Post-Independence 319 15.2 Active UN Peacekeeping Operations, 1948-2014 325 15.3 Probability of Success for Different Types of PKOs 328

Tables

2.1 Average Maternal Mortality 38

3.1 The Shadow Economy 71 3.2 Ethnic Power Relations in Africa, 1960-1990 76 3.3 Ethnic Power Sharing and Civil War in African States, 1960-1990 77

4.1 Failed State Index by Region 84 4.2 Probability of Civil War Onset, 1960-1999 86 4.3 Low-Level Conflicts by Region, 1960-2014 88

5.1 Frequency of Herbst’s Types 115 5.2 Probability of Civil War by Geography 123 5.3 Latitude and Probability of Civil War 126

8.1 Separatist Conflicts in Africa 173

10.1 Average Distance from the Official Language by Region 210

15.1 UN PKOs in Africa 326

Preface

Africans have taken a long and troubled march from their exuberant moment of freedom in the early 1960s. But now is a moment for renewed optimism. Today, many coun- tries are providing growth, political voice, and security to their citizens. Still, dark clouds remain on the horizon. Throughout much of Africa, countries harbor terrorists in ungoverned spaces, struggle to control diseases that cross borders, and expel refugees fleeing civil war and abject poverty. Nonetheless, this is a moment of great possibility for African states to overcome the barriers — to economic development, to democracy, and to order — that have stifled them for a generation. Their success is consequential for all of us, whether in Africa or abroad. Despite Africa’s importance, ignorance about the continent abounds. The current US president had trouble pronouncing “Namibia” in a speech to African leaders. But this ignorance is not only among foreign- ers. Lecturing to a large audience of college-educated Nigerians at Stanford, one of the authors (David Laitin) found that none of them could recall the details of a civil war that had killed a million of their fellow citizens just a generation ago. This limited awareness of African affairs persists de- spite an outpouring of academic research in and about Africa in the past quarter century. Unfortunately, this xvi AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

research — our own included — is written in technical language and buried in specialized journals. In this book, we endeavor to make the findings from these works avail- able to a wider audience. We also develop a framework for integrating decades of research across multiple disci- plines, providing an explanation for why Africa’s leaders, despite charisma and high hopes, have struggled to es- cape their countries’ geographic and historical constraints and implement effective policies. We hope the synthesis offered here will be of use to activists in nongovernmen- tal organizations (NGOs), civil servants, entrepreneurs, university students, and the general public. This book was motivated by an invitation to David Laitin to deliver the Castle Lectures in Ethics, Politics, and Economics at Yale University. He was invited by Nicolas Sambanis and Ian Shapiro and acknowledges the honor bestowed upon him to deliver these prestigious lectures. Darin Christensen helped to craft those lectures and agreed to dramatically expand the three presentations into a broad-based book as an equal co-author. At Yale, comments by Kate Baldwin were inspiring. Melina Platas Izama pointed us to omissions and carefully reviewed part I. In early draft stage, members of the Work- ing Group in African Political Economy (WGAPE) read and commented on the manuscript. Comments at that WGAPE meeting by Daniel Posner, Karen Ferree, James Fearon, and Jeremy Weinstein were especially useful in reorganizing the material. We presented a revised version to the Center for at Stanford University, where comments by James Ferguson, Richard Roberts, Marcel Fafchamps, and David Abernethy compelled us to make further revisions. We are especially indebted to Nelson Kasfir, who read the manuscript twice, each time correcting errors while offering continued encouragement. We also received penetrating comments on our economic policy chapters from Thomas Callaghy and Nicolas van PREFACE xvii

de Walle. Kennedy Opalo provided final feedback with his exceptional knowledge of the literature on African politics. We are grateful to all these generous scholars for their critical comments and suggestions. We thank Kristin Christensen, who scolded us for jar- gon. We received excellent research assistance from Alex Ziff and Andrew Brooks, both of whom assiduously fact- checked and cleared up ambiguities. And we are espe- cially grateful to John Castle for inspiring and facilitating the production of this book.

Region & Country Codes

World Bank Regions

EAP East Asia & Pacific ECA Europe & Central Asia LAC Latin America & Caribbean MENA Middle East & North Africa NA North America SA South Asia SSA Sub-Saharan Africa

Country Codes

AGO MOZ BDI Burundi MRT Mauritania BEN MUS Mauritius BFA MWI BWA Botswana NAM Namibia CAF Central African Republic NER CIV Côte d’Ivoire NGA Nigeria CMR Cameroon RWA Rwanda COG Congo SDN Sudan COM Comoros SEN Senegal CPV Cabo Verde SLE Sierra Leone ERI Eritrea SOM Somalia ETH Ethiopia SSD South Sudan GAB Gabon STP Sao Tome and Principe GHA Ghana SWZ Swaziland GIN Guinea SYC Seychelles GMB Gambia TCD GNB Guinea-Bissau TGO GNQ Equatorial Guinea TZA United Republic of Tanzania KEN Kenya UGA LBR ZAF South Africa LSO ZAR Democratic Republic of the Congo MDG Madagascar ZMB MLI ZWE Zimbabwe

Introduction

THIS BOOK addresses a fundamental question for those interested in sub-Saharan Africa. Why have its postcolo- nial states not fulfilled their promise to deliver prosperity, good governance, and security? On these three goals, at least through a generation of independent rule, most sub- Saharan states did not keep pace with other world regions that were also considered “underdeveloped” in the early 1960s, the decade of independence for most African states. Nor had many of them fulfilled the promises of their in- dependence movements and the charismatic leaders who heralded a promising future. Many expected sub-Saharan countries to flourish once they were freed from the colonial yoke. The soaring rhetoric of Africa’s founding fathers, the assessments of international officials, and the more staid analysis of aca- demics all predicted rapid economic and political devel- opment. The UN secretary-general Dag Hammarskjöld, after an extended early-1960 tour of Africa, wrote that he had just visited “a continent launched on the road to coop- erative success by new and able young leaders” (Young, 2012, 12). Economic forecasts from a World Bank report confirmed this travelogue, claiming that Africa’s growth potential surpassed East Asia’s prospects, with at least seven newly independent countries “‘clearly [having] the potential to reach or surpass’ a 7 percent growth rate” (Easterly, 2002). Political scientists documented a sense 2 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

of optimism among Africans: Crawford Young, one of the eminent scholars conducting field work during the early independence years, recalled, “The dawn of inde- pendence seemed full of promise. . . euphoria was widely shared across the continent” (Young, 2012, 10). They were also energized by the opportunities for crafting new political cultures and institutions. Even one of the more hard-nosed early analysts of African independence, Aris- tide Zolberg, seemed awed by Africa’s bright prospects:

Most political scientists who were in the field [of African politics] sufficiently early to share in the enthusiasm of the new men at the helm of the liberating movement were caught up in the drama of man’s search for polity which was being re-enacted in a new and strange environment. The study of African politics provided a great and excit- ing intellectual adventure comparable to the quests which earlier had driven explorers to overcome apparently in- surmountable obstacles on the same continent. These intrepid men no longer sought to trace the sources of the Nile or the course of the Niger. The new challenge was to discover, with the help of imaginative theories of society, a system of rivulets which might merge into a new stream of democracy. (Zolberg, 1966, 1)

But the optimism was short-lived. In part I, we il- lustrate the failures to meet these high expectations. In the first three decades after independence, sub-Saharan African countries fell behind other regions on standard in- dicators of development, democracy, and order. In terms of the distribution of power and resources, economic re- sources failed to grow and political power quickly became concentrated in the hands of (semi)authoritarian rulers, who struggled to maintain order. Part II offers a more sober look at the conditions facing the founding fathers of Africa’s new states. The sharp di- vergence between expectations and performance becomes easier to explain after reviewing the constraints under which Africa’s post-independence leaders worked. We INTRODUCTION 3

consider, for example, how geography and demography — expansive, sparsely populated, and ethnically diverse states — affected leaders’ calculations regarding whether to expand the administrative reach of the state to periph- eral regions. We also discuss those constraints imposed by the slave trade and other extractive institutions, the presence of missionaries, the partition of the continent by poorly informed European diplomats, and the strategies of rule employed by colonial states. No matter how in- ventive or ambitious the new African leaders were, these inheritances restricted the scope of feasible reform. In part III, we discuss the policy choices in the post- independence period that contributed to economic stag- nation, weak but repressive states, and internal conflict. Due to historical constraints and unrealistic ideological commitments, new leaders and their successors failed to provide growth and security. Africa stagnated for a gener- ation. While our review is not exhaustive, we cover sev- eral important policy areas, including language choices, foreign policy, and the economic doctrines that guided government spending and monetary policy. Lest one lose faith in the ability of governments to sur- mount constraints and promote economic and political de- velopment, in part IV we discuss several recent successes. Beginning in the early 1990s, despite a few notable set- backs, movements to replace military rule and one-party states with democracy made meaningful progress. Aided by a boom in mineral prices, economic growth during the first decade of this century has been impressive in many African countries. And new solidarity pacts exemplified in the have helped cauterize civil conflict and restrain dictatorial tendencies among fellow presi- dents. The negative framing of African affairs through the and 1990s is therefore being challenged, a cau- tiously hopeful sign for the future. 4 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

The Logic of Political Rule in Africa After establishing in part I the dimensions of Africa’s post-independence lag, parts II-IV proceed (for the most part) chronologically: we begin with geographic or histori- cal constraints, discuss post-independence policy choices, and then end with a discussion of more promising re- cent trends. Yet, we also see these sections as illuminat- ing different aspects of a more general political problem: working within the constraints imposed by history or ge- ography, how do leaders survive in office and realize their policy (or personal) goals? The policy failures of the post- independence period were not simply due to bad ideas (though there were certainly some of those). A politi- cal logic guided African leaders’ decisions to champion or shelve certain policies. Where reform threatened an incumbent’s political base or outstripped the weak bureau- cracy inherited from the colonial state, we should not be surprised that a leader opted for the status quo or muddled through with a suboptimal alternative. By describing the constraints facing leaders and their political objectives, we can make sense of policies that, ultimately, contributed to three decades of dismal eco- nomic growth and political instability for too many of Africa’s newly independent states. To be sure, there have been impressive economic successes, as in Botswana and Lesotho. And countries such as Tanzania avoided violent breakdowns. But on average, compared with other post- colonial regions, African states faced policy failure. To account for this failure, we develop a simple analytical framework here that we return to throughout the book to help explain the early policy failures, as well as exam- ine the possibilities for a more successful future. When discussing leaders’ choices, we consider both sides of the political ledger — the benefits (e.g., status, economic growth) and costs (e.g., fomenting opposition, running budget deficits) that inform leaders’ decisions. We ex- INTRODUCTION 5

pect that leaders choose policies that maximize the ex- pected value of office, adopting initiatives that they expect will deliver benefits without dramatically decreasing their odds of retaining power or imposing prohibitive costs.1 1 For those comfortable with symbolic representation, we The diagram below (adapted from Acemoglu, Johnson, can express the leader’s prob- and Robinson, 2005), illustrates our framework. Starting lem as maxp P S(p)[B(p) 2 { C (p)] [1 S(p)]C (p) on the left of figure 1, geography and history — both S NS } where S(p) is the probability distant and more recent — shape the distribution of power of survival given policy choice and resources that leaders inherit. Some leaders inherit p in the set of feasible policies P, and B(p) is the benefit the a country that is ethnically homogeneous; others, an eth- leader receives from policy p. nically diverse population. Some inherit an incompetent CS(p) is costs paid if the leader bureaucracy; others, a meritocratic civil service. Some survives, while CNS(p) is costs paid if leader does not survive. enjoy oil reserves; others rely heavily on cash crops for We set (or normalize) the ben- foreign exchange. Some oversee a population that (un- efits to be zero if the leader doesn’t survive. evenly) benefited from missionaries’ educational efforts; others, a citizenry displaced and distrustful after centuries of slave trading. Some enjoy widespread support; oth- ers can count few supporters outside of their own region or . This inheritance weighs heavily on the leader, constraining what is feasible. In part II, we exam- ine how history and geography limit leaders’ choices.

Direct Effect

Economic Development

Historic Distribution of Constraints Power & Resources Policy Choice Democracy Leader’s Objectives

Political Order

Future Distribution of Power & Resources

Feedback Loop

Figure 1 Moving to the right on our diagram, leaders make pol- Conceptual Framework icy choices. Upon coming to power, they have their own objectives: industrializing, fostering equality, and promot- 6 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

ing new national or transnational identities. Guided by these objectives and given their historical and contempo- rary constraints, these leaders pursue reforms that deliver policy or personal benefits without jeopardizing their po- litical survival.2 In part III we unpack the ideological 2 We interchange the words pol- baggage that leaders bring to office, which provides the icy and reform. However, we recognize that the leader might material for their cultural and economic policies. opt for the status quo — a clear But leaders do not always choose the optimal policy policy choice, but not one that entails reform. from the perspective of overall welfare. Constrained or not, leaders want to retain control and are unlikely to implement reforms that imperil their status, wealth, and continued rule. A potentially more beneficial policy for growth, for security, or for democracy may simply be ignored if that policy also compromises the leader’s in- cumbency. Rooting out corruption, for example, could improve public service delivery, but also anger elites that depend on rents and extortion under the corrupt system. If the leader depends on the support (or acquiescence) of those same corrupt elites, reform is unlikely. Or a floating exchange rate: while this monetary policy could boost exports, leaders might dismiss the prospect out of hand, fearing the riots that would erupt from price hikes on the imported goods that urban constituents demand. At the far right of our diagram, we see that policy choices shape the future distribution of power and re- sources. Winners win; losers lose. In redistributing economic and political power, policies also change the constraints facing the leader in the future — thus, the feedback loop connecting future to historic resources and power (one government’s future is its successor’s history). However, policy rarely reconfigures the social order, es- pecially in weak states and where the social order reflects powerful historical and geographical forces. For example, a landlocked country faces constraints to international trade, whether under colonial rule or after independence. INTRODUCTION 7

Hence, we allow for persistence in the distribution of eco- nomic and political power over time (i.e., a direct effect). As we go through the historical and geographic con- straints (in part II) and early policies instituted by post- colonial leaders (in part III), we use each chapter’s conclu- sion to refer back to this framework, filling in the boxes with specific constraints and policies. Distinguishing Our Approach Our analytical framework might appear subject to Thandika Mkandawire’s (2001) powerful, oft-cited cri- tique of African development studies. Mkandawire high- lights two contradictory sentiments in the writing of West- ern commentators: “the pessimism of the diagnosis and the optimism of the prescription” (289). These analysts can in the same breath — or, at least, a single work — lament the “impossibility of developmental states in Africa” and offer confident prescriptions for reforms that will ensure success. We cannot deny that our review of the first thirty years of independence may feel bleak. However, we wish to highlight that Africa’s geography and history, rather than serving as inescapable and enduring shackles, represent real but surmountable constraints. Moreover, we make no prescriptions for reform and remain cautiously hopeful about more recent improvements in economic develop- ment and political liberalization. Similarly, we avoid simple dichotomies posing, for example, policy versus destiny as competing explanations for African countries’ slow growth (Collier and Gunning, 1999). As we hope is already becoming apparent, we see these as complementary explanations. Although we don’t deny that history and geography can have direct effects on contemporary outcomes, they also constrain policy decisions. Another fault line in the study of African politics di- 8 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

vides “joiners” and “splitters.” Splitters through their teaching and research have sought to undermine popular views of a culturally and political homogeneous continent. Some societies, they note, are matrilineal; others patri- lineal. Some societies are pastoral, others agricultural, and still others are highly dependent upon mining. Some tribes are hierarchical; others acephalous (i.e., leader- less). Some countries faced indirect rule; others direct rule. Joiners have, on the other hand, searched for com- monalities. Until relatively recently, they wrote about Africa’s growth tragedy (Easterly and Levine, 1997). As economic prospects have improved, they’ve started to ask, “Is this Africa’s time?” (Robertson, 2012) Here African countries are seen as facing common constraints and op- portunities. Our innovation — and it may not totally satisfy either camp — is to draw upon both bodies of scholarship to help explain cross-national differences in human welfare. We’re interested in why Kenya has grown faster than So- malia, but failed to keep pace with Thailand (which had nearly the same per capita gross domestic product [GDP] in 1965). The splitters help us to answer the first part of this question, recounting Kenya’s relatively peaceful post-independence history, which contrasts sharply with Somalia’s persistent struggle to maintain peace. The join- ers take a broader perspective, explaining why East Asia and East Africa followed different policy and economic trajectories.3 3 What readers, especially the splitters among them, may find It becomes imprudent to remain as joiners in address- missing in this manuscript is ing policy choices and outcomes post-1990. At this point, much discussion of differences variation across African states becomes more prominent within individual African coun- tries and how these contribute in our analysis. Indeed, in this period, a divide has opened to inequalities across towns or between states that are advancing economically and insti- provinces (e.g., between West- ern and Central Kenya). tuting political reforms and those that are mired in slow growth, personalist rule, and peripheral rebellion. In the African Economic Research Consortium’s (AERC) re- INTRODUCTION 9

view of African growth from 1960 to 2000, Ndulu and O’Connell (2008, 26) point out that the “variation in long- run growth within SSA [sub-Saharan Africa] dwarfs the difference between average growth in SSA and average growth in any other region.” Therefore, in part IV, we narrow our focus in an effort to chart divergent outcomes — stories of tentative successes and ongoing stagnation — among African states. Whether splitters or joiners, scholars have recently made progress in getting to the roots of Africa’s lag by engaging in careful empirical research that, while keenly aware of the difficulties, tries to identify variables that have a causal effect on democracy, on economic growth, and on security. An important goal of this volume is to synthesize those contributions along each dimension. Empirical research on the question of African states’ un- fulfilled promise has been impressively robust in the past several years, but it exists mostly in highly technical jour- nals. Here, we accept the challenge of making these studies available to the general reader in a way that is both accessible and persuasive. In this endeavor, we seek, through graphical presentations and case studies, to con- vey and animate core findings. However, we must warn readers that we cannot offer definitive answers on the causes of democratic failure, economic stagnation, and conflict. The causal pathways from, for example, colonial rule to contemporary eco- nomic, political, and social outcomes are numerous, in- tersecting, and perhaps beyond the tools of social science to map fully. Moreover, failure on one outcome can im- pede progress on another, and vice versa: the failure to educate children, for example, leads to poorly informed voters, who struggle to punish officials who fail to de- liver increased spending on teachers or schools. These feedback loops (in this instance, poor education low accountability poor education) trap countries in a ru- 10 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

inous autocratic and low growth equilibrium. This makes it all the more difficult to isolate cause and effect. We hope that as the book progresses, each chapter will elaborate on our novel conceptual scheme of heroic goals confronting daunting constraints and the policy compro- mises and outcomes that result from this collision. Both the reasons for Africa’s lag and the tentative steps being taken to correct it should become clearer as the book pro- gresses. We see in this framework a realistic foundation for imagining a more democratic, a more secure, and a more prosperous continent. Part I. From Great Expectations to Unfulfilled Dreams

In their first half-century of self-rule, newly independent African states have lagged behind the rest of the world in terms of economic development, the establishment of effective governance capable of securing social order, and the consolidation of democracy. Here in part I, we first seek to capture a moment in the late 1950s: a new generation of Africans was on the threshold of becom- ing the founding fathers of states escaping colonialism. Although they acknowledged the challenges that indepen- dence would bring, their optimism and goals to restore the greatness of Africa, as we document in chapter 1, were exhilarating. Yet, as chapters 2-4 recount, the dis- placement of elected leaders with military dictators, the disease of corruption, and the specter of violence and civil war cumulatively undermined early optimism. African states’ progress was far less impressive than in other world regions on most indicators of human development and security. The symptoms of this failure plagued African polities at least through the early 1990s. In chapter 2, we focus on the lag in human development, examining indicators of income, health, and education. In chapter 3, we consider democracy and the rule of law, cataloging the undermining of democracy (with one-party states) and the cascade of coups that brought military dictatorships to many African countries. In addition, we highlight the 12 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

corruption in both civilian and military regimes that un- dermined the rule of law. In chapter 4, our focus turns to the breakdown of social order through communal conflict and civil war. In these three chapters, relying on statisti- cal evidence and accompanying case studies, we compare African states with other regions to reckon the magnitude of Africa’s lag and convey its human costs. These chap- ters raise the fundamental question of this book — what explains African states’ struggles in the first half-century of independence? 1. The Charismatic Founders and Their Dreams

WEBEGINTHISBOOKat a moment of great promise. A decade into the post–World War II peace, complemen- tary geopolitical and ideological changes enabled aspiring elites in the colonial world not only to articulate but also to fulfill a vision of dividing empires into nations. A new generation of Africans, imbued with ideals of national- ism, pan-Africanism, and independence, articulated the aspirations of their colonized brethren. Their idea that African states would escape the colonial yoke became an achievable goal as the dust settled from World War II. The war had incapacitated former empires. had been occupied, and General Charles de Gaulle, the leader of the anti-Nazi French resistance, ruled in exile until 1944. Brazzaville in the Congo, not Paris, became the symbolic capital of La France libre (Free France). Meanwhile, Britain had made vast concessions to the Congress Party in India about a future independence in return for its support during the war. All the European metropoles had expanded their armed forces by recruiting and training soldiers from their colonies, and European warfare gave African soldiers an experience of the wider world and a confidence that they could succeed with self- rule. Independence movements in sub-Saharan Africa came 14 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

on the heels of successful struggles elsewhere (figure 1.1). Figure 1.1 Nationalist uprisings against colonial rule in Vietnam Number of Independent States, 1940-2010 (French retreat after defeat in Dien Bien Phu in 1954) 200 and (the National Liberation Front was the bête World noire of the French Fourth Republic, helping its demise in 150

1958) were the major world conflicts during the postwar 100 peace. In 1955 Sukarno, the nationalist leader of Indone- 50 SSA sia, invited compatriots from other nationalist movements 0 throughout Asia and Africa to Bandung. This was the 1940 1960 1980 2000 origin of a “non-aligned” movement that foreshadowed a new era of independent states. In 1956, , who had overthrown a traditionalist monarchy in Egypt, burnished his nationalist credentials through the nationalizing of the Suez Canal, successfully defying the British and the French, who could no longer main- tain their imperial control over this crucial chokepoint of international shipping. The United States, the dominant state post–World War II, played a passive but important role in advancing the na- tionalist agenda. President Dwight D. Eisenhower refused to support the French in their attempt to retain Vietnam as a colony and seethed with anger over France and Britain’s military campaign to reestablish control over the Suez Canal. Through diplomatic channels, Eisenhower made clear that he would not wage war to sustain European empires. More publicly, the newly elected senator from Massachusetts, John Fitzgerald Kennedy, gave a vision- ary speech in the Senate in support of Algeria’s National Liberation Front on July 2, 1957, only a few months after taking his seat:

The most powerful single force in the world today is neither communism nor capitalism, neither the H-bomb nor the guided missile; it is man’s eternal desire to be free and independent. . . . If we are to secure the friendship of the Arab, the African, and the Asian — and we must, despite what Mr. Dulles [the secretary of state] says about THE CHARISMATIC FOUNDERS AND THEIR DREAMS 15

our not being in a popularity contest — we cannot hope to accomplish it solely by means of billion-dollar foreign aid programs. We cannot win their hearts by making them dependent upon our handouts. Nor can we keep them free by selling them free enterprise, by describing the perils of communism or the prosperity of the United States, or limiting our dealings to military pacts. No, the strength of our appeal to these key populations — and it is rightfully our appeal, and not that of the Communists — lies in our traditional and deeply felt philosophy of freedom and independence for all peoples everywhere. (Kennedy, 1957)

This message was not ignored in imperial headquar- ters. Recognizing a new era, Tory prime minister Harold Macmillan traveled to South Africa with a speech (on February 3, 1960) before the -supporting South African Parliament. “The wind of change,” he declared, “is blowing through this continent, and whether we like it or not, this growth of national consciousness is a political fact. We must all accept it as a fact, and our national policies must take account of it.” The inevitability of independence for Indonesia, for India, for Vietnam, and for Algeria after World War II brought a new perspective on . Liberals and democrats had long seen nationalism as antithetical to a liberal state and associated it with doctrines such as Fascism and Nazism. But the anticolonial moment pro- vided a new positive valence to nationalism — it came to represent liberation of all third-world peoples (Emerson, 1960). Aspiring African leaders would take full advantage of this moment to press for liberation. In this chapter, we seek to reconstruct this optimistic and forward-looking moment in Africa’s political history. 16 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

1 History Moved Through “Charismatic Leadership” Third-world nationalism required a dynamic leader who could both constitute a nation from the diverse pop- ulations contained within colonial boundaries and also negotiate with the metropole over the transition to native rule. These leaders had to not only connect with and unite their populations but also convince colonial administra- tors that they were ready to rule. They succeeded in the former by presenting themselves as icons of the nation rather than their tribe. Indeed, nearly half of the initial heads of government were not from the dominant ethnic group of their newly independent state and could gain wide support only by associating themselves with the na- tion.1 Many of them also earned legitimacy after being 1 Of the forty states that be- incarcerated by colonial authorities. They succeeded in came independent in this mo- ment, only twenty-three out of the latter, in part, due to their Western educations — child- forty inaugural heads of state hoods in missionary schools and university degrees from came from the dominant eth- nic groups in their countries Europe and the US — which assuaged the racist concerns (Mitchell, Morrison, and Paden, of colonial authorities. 1989). New leaders inspired their fellow nationals with an al- most magical quality, a phenomenon that the German so- ciologist Max Weber called “charisma” (from the Greek, literally “gift of grace”). Weber argued that it takes such leadership to overcome the routinized politics of everyday life; in this case, the narrow scope of political activity permitted by the colonial bureaucracy. These charismatic leaders had to convince their fellow nationals that inde- pendence was inevitable and on the path to a surmount- 2 Readers might wonder why Nelson Mandela is absent from able mountaintop, rather than an impossible uphill battle these vignettes. His charismatic against a still dominant empire. The biographies of promi- moment was in the 1990s. See nent founding fathers provide a compelling view into this Mandela (1990) for a collec- tion of his speeches and writ- pivotal moment in African history and convey their opti- ings from 1944 through to his mism regarding their countries’ and the region’s future.2 release from prison in 1990. THE CHARISMATIC FOUNDERS AND THEIR DREAMS 17

Kwame Nkrumah of Ghana

Kwame Nkrumah (figure 1.2), the charismatic founder Figure 1.2 of Ghana (from the British Gold Coast colony), was a Kwame Nkrumah prominent guest of Sukarno in Bandung and one of the visionaries of the non-aligned movement. He was born in 1909 to an Nzima-speaking family, a language group representing less than 3 percent of the Gold Coast’s pop- ulation. In the Gold Coast, Nkrumah was educated by Catholic missionaries and won a scholarship to the pres- tigious colonial college Achimoto. He did not qualify for a university scholarship in London but, through the intervention of an uncle, he was accepted to Lincoln Uni- versity in Pennsylvania (one of America’s historic black colleges and universities); after that, he enrolled in the London School of Economics. Still abroad in 1947, Nkrumah was induced to return home by J. B. Danquah, the founder of the earliest na- tionalist organization in the Gold Coast, the United Gold Coast Convention. Danquah offered the young Nkrumah the position of party secretary. Shortly after Nkrumah assumed this position, veterans of World War II rallied in Accra demanding their rightful benefits. A riot ensued that led to two deaths. Colonial authorities implicated Nkrumah, and he was detained in a remote village in the colony’s north. Upon his release, he challenged Dan- quah’s conservatism and created the Convention People’s Party (CPP). campaigns organized by the CPP led to Nkrumah’s arrest and a prison sentence of fourteen months. Upon his release, 100,000 people were waiting for him on the streets. He had now established his street credibility. An enlightened colonial governor, Charles Noble Arden-Clarke, understood the threat and opportunity that Nkrumah represented and brilliantly ap- pointed him as the colony’s prime minister. The sources of Nkrumah’s charismatic appeal were 18 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

manifold. He articulated a theory of “consciencism” (Nkrumah, 1970) that skillfully combined the Euro- Christian, the Islamic, and the African traditions into a compelling ideology for modern Africa. Wearing West- ern suits, he could earn the trust of the British governor as a serious and responsible future leader, yet (wearing kente cloth robes), he could also earn the trust of country villagers as a simple man who could sit on the ground and share a meal with them. In the Gold Coast, he stood for youth against age, for peasants against chiefs, and for “Ghanaians” against the British. Nkrumah was savvy enough to be on the right side of history on all three of these dimensions. This revealed impressive vision and earned him admiration to match the charismatic aura that he exuded. His vision was clear, powerful, and yet initially deemed implausible. He envisioned self-government for a re-named country, Ghana (after a defunct but once pow- erful West African kingdom), as a first step to liberating and uniting all of Africa. He presented this vision in his protest speeches, in Parliament in his role as prime min- ister, and in speeches throughout the countryside, which he traversed in his Cadillac. Speaking to Nkrumah’s charisma, journalistic reports claimed that touching that car yielded ecstasy and a sense of connection to the future among his rural audiences. Thanks to the presence of the American journalist John Gunther (Gunther, 1955, 809–812), we have a record of Nkrumah’s “independence” resolution in the Gold Coast Legislative Assembly in July 1953. He stood before the Legislative Assembly wearing “a cotton smock, white with vertical black stripes [that] symbolizes simplicity in contrast to the ornate regalia of the chiefs.” He began with a quotation from Edmund Burke emphasizing the need for political maturity and then one from Aristotle emphasizing the need for political virtue. He moved from THE CHARISMATIC FOUNDERS AND THEIR DREAMS 19

biblical imagery (“The heroes of our future will be those who can lead our people out of. . . serfdom, into the valley of light”) to practical wisdom (“As long as somebody else has charge of us, we can lay our mistakes at their door”). Yet his purpose was unmistakable: “We prefer self-government with danger to servitude in tranquility.” To be sure, Nkrumah faced opposition in the Assembly, especially from the cocoa regions that were to be heavily taxed to support his grand schemes. But on that day, the cheers at virtually every line were dutifully recorded by the Hansard stenographers. Gunther reports that upon leaving his private ante- room after this speech, Nkrumah was “lifted off his feet. Deputies, party friends, colleagues, seized him and, while he was laughing and struggling, carried him on their hands around and around the open square. There was a mad clatter of excitement and the parliamentarism we had just seen exploded into a wild, cheerful frenzy, and people began to sing and dance. Breathless, Nkrumah got off the shoulders of his partisans. “If Winston Churchill were ever to be captured outside Downing Street and hoisted into the air by Yeomen of the Guard dancing a jig,” Gun- ther imagines, “the scene would be equivalent.” Gunther then overhears an African onlooker, nearly weeping, who cried out, “The Prime Minister’s speech is the turning Figure 1.3 point of my life. All my life I have thought that the white Julius Nyerere man was my enemy. Now I know that he is my friend!” This was the quintessential charismatic moment. Julius Nyerere of Tanzania Julius Nyerere (figure 1.3), the future leader of Tan- zania, offered a somewhat more sedate appeal. He con- ceived of himself, and was regarded by the multitudes in Tanganyika (the name of the colony before the acces- sion of Zanzibar), as both mwalimu (teacher) and baba wa taifa (father of his nation). He constantly admon- 20 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

ished his people as if he were their primary school teacher. Mwalimu scolded his countrymen for failing to match the world’s great powers: “Our friends are using their brains while our [people] sleep and grow fungus; they are sending rockets into outer space while we are eating wild roots!” Nyerere vigorously promoted Swahili as a common language: he spoke only Swahili in country, and even translated Shakespeare’s Julius Caesar to demonstrate the language’s adaptability. Despite his commitment to Swahili, Nyerere was brilliantly articulate in English and was the first Tanganyikan to get a university degree over- seas (in Scotland). He was also baptized Catholic at age twenty. Coming from a small tribe, he was not associated with any significant subgroup of Tanganyikans and faced almost no opposition in his election as president of the first nationalist party, the Tanganyikan African National Union (TANU). As president of independent Tanganyika, he refused to live in the state house and reported that was far more comfortable joking with peasants on the road than speaking with diplomats. Typical of the first gener- ation of leaders, he was also trusted by the British (who administered Tanganyika as a trust territory after German defeat in World War I). As independence was foreseen by the trust arrangement, Nyerere never engaged in the kind of agitation that would get him arrested. It was several years later, after articulating a visionary statement for his country, that his fame reached charis- matic proportions. He released his Arusha Declaration in 1967 (supplemented by his essay “Education for Self- Reliance”), in which he articulated an ideology of Uhuru na (Freedom and ). This was followed by the nationalization of banks, insurance companies, sisal estates, and other large establishments, and a code of conduct (moving them toward monastery rules) for all party officials. This announcement set off a spontaneous THE CHARISMATIC FOUNDERS AND THEIR DREAMS 21

set of celebrations and marches across the country, with reports from the local press that an “entire village was seething with revolutionary enthusiasm emitted by the Spirit of Arusha.” Later on, during a long march led by Nyerere, The Standard reported that “Mwalimu’s brisk march into the town [of Mwanza] stunned the masses who on seeing him in sound health were driven wild with admiration and excitement to borders of near frenzy. The entire town was gripped with the revolutionary fervor of the Spirit of Arusha.” Nyerere’s vision for Tanzania — and indeed for Africa — was one that would build on native socialism and hard work to catch up with the great powers. That vision captured the imagination of his countrymen, many of whom believed his capabilities for transforming their society were extraordinary. Jomo Kenyatta of Kenya Jomo Kenyatta (figure 1.4), Kenya’s first independence Figure 1.4 leader, may not have been credited with magical powers Jomo Kenyatta or adulation. Yet, during his long rule, few questioned that the presidency was his entitlement. He was seen not as a transitory political leader but rather as an embodiment of his country. An orphan, he was enrolled in a Scottish mission school near Nairobi. As a Kikuyu, he was a member of the plurality linguistic group in Kenya (representing about 21 percent of the population). The Kikuyu are not only Kenya’s largest group, but also centrally located and, thus, were the primary victims of land seizures by the colonists establishing plantations in Kenya’s central high- lands. The group’s numbers and grievances facilitated their political mobilization. Taking advantage of this op- portunity, Kenyatta (then known as “Johnstone,” the name given him by missionaries) became active in Kikuyu orga- 22 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

nizations and by 1928 was publishing a Kikuyu-language newspaper in Nairobi. A year later he emigrated to the United Kingdom and, while there, married an English woman. He studied an- thropology at the London School of Economics (and later in Moscow) and worked under Bronisław Malinowski, considered one of the most important anthropologists of the twentieth century. While physically removed from Kenya, Kenyatta remained focused on the country and, specifically, Kikuyu history and culture, entitling his the- sis Facing Mount Kenya: The Tribal Life of the Gikuyu (1938) — a collection of essays that described the social ruin brought on by colonial policy. Seeking to enhance his credibility among Kenyans, he dropped the surname “Johnstone” and became “Kenyatta.” Kenyatta returned to his homeland in 1946 and joined the Kikuyu Central Association to help recover the “White Highlands,” the area in central Kenya heavily settled by European farmers. Shortly, he became its secretary general. The Association was dissolved by the British government for its radical- ism, but it reemerged as the Kenya African Union (KAU), seeking to expand beyond Kikuyu membership. Kenyatta became the KAU’s president. As he traveled throughout the country, his speeches attracted tens of thousands of people and gave subtle signals of his support for the Mau Mau, the insurgent group seeking to retake the highlands. When violence broke out between the Mau Mau and white settlers, Kenyatta was arrested. He refused to denounce the insurgency and, after a five-month trial, was convicted in 1953 and sentenced to seven years. In that same year, the KAU was banned. Kenyatta’s persecution as a spokesman for indepen- dence gave him a unifying appeal. His charisma now combined with widespread support. When Kenyatta was freed in 1961, he assumed control of the dominant in- dependence movement (now called the Kenyan African THE CHARISMATIC FOUNDERS AND THEIR DREAMS 23

National Union, or KANU). And with KANU’s victory in the independence election, he had an uncontested claim on the country’s presidency — a post he held until his death in 1978. Léopold Senghor of Senegal With some 95 percent of Senegalese professing the Muslim faith, and with Wolof speakers constituting a majority of Senegalese, Léopold Senghor (figure 1.5) was Figure 1.5 a double minority: his father was a Serer Catholic, and his Léopold Senghor mother was a Muslim from the Peul-speaking community. As a child, he was sent to a Catholic boarding school. Later, he transferred to a secular French school, where he excelled in French literature and won a scholarship to study in France. He studied there through university and was honored with an appointment as a literature professor in Tours and in Paris. He took on French citizenship in 1932 and became the first African to be an elected member of the Académie Française. Senghor served in the French army in World War II. He was captured and interned in a German prison camp, and when he was released, he joined the French resistance. After the war, he won a seat in the French National Assem- bly as a member of the French Socialist Party. Senghor served as a state secretary and then an advisory minister in the Fourth Republic’s socialist governments. He was on the drafting committee for the Constitution of the Fifth Republic. Up until independence, he favored Senegal being an equal region within France but retained strong socialist ideals. Part of Senghor’s international prestige was built on his poetry (written in French) that gave beauty and substance to the glorification of blackness, in the philosophy of négritude. Here he connected his personality and his future to African culture and sensibility. Upon his return to Senegal, he lent his support for African workers when 24 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

conductors (bringing groundnuts to Dakar) went on strike against the French national railways. His combination of international prestige and a message combining culture and socialism earned him great honor. He became the first president of independent Senegal as a revered figure throughout the country. Ahmed Sékou Touré of Guinea

Sékou Touré (figure 1.6) earned his charismatic status Figure 1.6 quite differently from Nkrumah, Nyerere, and Senghor, Ahmed Sékou Touré all of whom combined overseas European education with an ability to connect with villagers. To be sure, he studied at a French technical school in Conakry, Guinea’s capi- tal, but he was more a rebel than a prized student in the colonial system. He was expelled from school for leading a food riot. After landing a job in the postal service, he quickly became a labor organizer there and led the first successful labor union strike in French West Africa. Unlike Senghor and Nkrumah, Touré was not from a marginalized ethnic group. He was a Mandé, a group that made us some 48 percent of Guinea’s population. But he identified himself even more broadly. He portrayed himself as a descendant of Samory, one of the great an- ticolonial rebel fighters in the nineteenth century who had an appeal beyond today’s Guinea, including today’s Burkina Faso and Mali. He legitimated himself not by tribe but by a broader category of nation. Like Senghor, he got elected to the French National Assembly in 1951. But unlike Senghor, he was not per- mitted to take his seat. He was twice rebuffed to take his legislative seat in Paris. But after his election as mayor of Conakry, Guinea’s capital, French colonial authorities granted him permission to sit in 1956. His great fame and heroic status came two years later, when President de Gaulle offered French colonial territo- ries the right to either demand immediate independence or THE CHARISMATIC FOUNDERS AND THEIR DREAMS 25

recognize their long-term interests as fellow members of the newly created . Touré was the only leader who lobbied for the former, making Guinea the first independent French-speaking state in sub-Saharan Africa, with Touré as its elected president. This turned him into a national hero, the only client of the French who would stand for true independence. His revolutionary and anticolonial ardor continued throughout his presidency (Touré, 1973). His nationalist prestige allowed him to retain presidential power for twenty-six years, until 1984, when he died in office. After the vote of 1958, when Guinea voted to demand its independence from France, the French tore out every phone hookup, removed all their office equipment, and left the newly independent country with no infrastructure. Unfazed, Touré turned to the for support, a bold move during the height of the . Later, after Nkrumah was ousted from power by a coup d’état, he became an honored guest in Guinea. Touré contin- ued to have an uncanny ability to marginalize competing elites (surviving numerous coup attempts and assassina- tion plots) while basking in the adulation of the masses. Patrice Lumumba of Congo (Kinshasa) Patrice Lumumba’s charisma was amplified by his mar- Figure 1.7 tyrdom (figure 1.7). Unlike the British and French in their Patrice Lumumba colonies, the Belgians did not educate or train a profes- sional class of Africans. In the late 1950s, there were almost no Congolese with European university experi- ence. This was true for Lumumba. His education by both Protestant and Catholic missionaries qualified him for a job as a postal clerk. He became active in the Belgian Liberal party, bringing him into some pan-African circles, and in 1958 he created a nationalist party, the Mouvement National Congolais (MNC). History suddenly moved all too quickly. In October 26 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

1959, while leading a rally in Stanleyville (today’s Kisan- gani), Lumumba was arrested for fomenting a riot in which thirty people were killed. He was saddled with a sixty-nine-month prison sentence for his instigating role. But when his party won a decisive victory in the first local elections to be held in the Congo in , he was released to participate in a roundtable conference in Brus- sels to discuss Congo’s future. Belgium agreed to liberate Congo in six months’ time, with national elections to be held in May. Lumumba’s youth (he was then thirty-four years old) and radical vision made him wildly popular in electoral rallies. After the vote, he became the first prime minister of independent Congo. He differentiated himself from the president, Joseph Kasavubu, by his populist and ardent rhetoric on the day power was transferred, June 30, 1960. Lumumba (Lumumba, 1961, 44–47) railed against the atrocities unleashed on the population of the Congo Free State under Belgium’s King Leopold II:

No Congolese will ever forget that independence was won in struggle, a persevering and inspired struggle carried on from day to day, a struggle, in which we were undaunted by privation or suffering and stinted neither strength nor blood.. . . The Republic of the Congo has been proclaimed and our beloved country’s future is now in the hands of its own people. Brothers, let us commence together a new struggle, a sublime struggle that will lead our country to peace, pros- perity and greatness.. . . We shall show the world what the black man can do when working in liberty, and we shall make the Congo the pride of Africa.

With the (Belgium-supported) of the Katanga province months later, the West did nothing to support the central government in Kinshasa. Lumumba THE CHARISMATIC FOUNDERS AND THEIR DREAMS 27

went to the Soviet Union for support. Although the So- viets had limited resources to influence events in Congo, the resulting foreign accord led to a break with President Kasavubu, who arrested his own prime minister. Lu- mumba was brought to Katanga, where he was tortured and killed by a firing squad. Lumumba became a martyr, representing socialism, nationalism, and an African future freed from the colonial yoke and continued interference. Figure 1.8 Obafemi Awolowo and Nnamdi Azikiwe of Nigeria Obafemi Awolowo Awolowo (Awo) and Azikiwe (Zik) were Nigeria’s preeminent “southern” nationalist leaders, creating all- Nigerian movements for independence. Awolowo (fig- ure 1.8) was a Yoruba from the southwest, a lan- guage group representing about 20 percent of Nigerians. Azikiwe (figure 1.9) was an Igbo from the southeast, a language group representing some 17 percent of Nigeri- ans. While both Yoruba and Igbo were plurality groups Douglas Miller, Hulton Archive, Getty Images in two of Nigeria’s three regions, they were minorities compared with the Hausas (representing about 29 per- Figure 1.9 cent of the population), who constituted a plurality in the Nnamdi Azikiwe Northern region. In the late 1950s, as Awolowo and Azikiwe traveled through their respective regions, the massive crowds chanted “Awo” and “Zik,” nicknames that later became the titles of their treatises. (Awolowo, 1960; Azikiwe, 1961). They fostered an enormous optimism and hope for what the inevitable independence of Nigeria would yield. Awo got a law degree in London and came back to Nigeria as a journalist. In 1947, he founded the Egbe Omo Oduduwa (the Society for the Sons of Oduduwa, Oduduwa being the traditional Yoruba deity) and then the “Action Group,” the political party that in 1951 was demanding independence in a federal republic. Awo be- came western premier, and with great funding from the cocoa marketing boards, he was the first to bring universal 28 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

primary education and free health care for all to a region anywhere in Africa. He was lionized for this progressive agenda. Zik was trained by Methodists in Lagos, and then went to the United States to attend Howard University and fi- nally Lincoln University, where he received a university degree. He returned to Nigeria and founded the West African Pilot, the most influential nationalist newspaper on the continent. He was based then in Lagos, the coun- try’s capital in the Yoruba-dominated southwest. This gave him a national vision, well beyond his home region. He founded his own political party, the National Council of Nigeria and the Cameroon (NCNC), with a goal for a unified (i.e., non-federal) Nigeria. He became chief minister of the Eastern Region in the late colonial period and then governor-general (formal head of state) at inde- pendence. With the proclamation of Nigeria as a republic (1963), in an electoral alliance with the Northern party, he became Nigeria’s first independent president. Zik was celebrated in the east, but through his editorship of the Pilot and his vision for a free and independent Africa, was endowed with charisma throughout Nigeria. 2 Conclusion The late 1950s and early independence years were a sort of Jeffersonian moment in Africa. A generation of largely Western-educated nationalists took the helm of newly independent African states to overcome the op- pressive, racist, and anti-developmental colonial states, envisioning independent Africa freed from the colonial yoke. In their constitutions, they fashioned new goals of educational and economic advancement as obligations of their states to their citizens (Spiro, 1960, 76). For exam- ple, the Somali constitution, written for one of the poorest countries of the world, promised all citizens free primary education and social security (Articles 35 and 37). Freed THE CHARISMATIC FOUNDERS AND THEIR DREAMS 29

from colonial dictates, African states would serve the real needs of their citizens. Fast-forwarding, Nkrumah declared himself a demi- god and was ignominiously overthrown by his own army. Lumumba was killed by regional warlords. Nyerere sur- vived, but watched his country stagnate economically for a generation. Senghor left office with honor, but with his country in similar economic straits. Touré’s exper- iment in radical independence provided Guineans with little but poverty and stagnation. Awo and Zik survived, not without controversy, but both gave way to a succes- sion of military rulers who were impervious to the more progressive visions of Nigeria’s charismatic founders. Clearly, charisma did not lead African states to a promised land. In chapters 2-4, we catalogue the eco- nomic, security, and democratic deficits that turned un- tamed hope into a gallows humor of disappointment, as many of the promises of the founding fathers went unful- filled.

2. Lag in Human Development

THE DREAMS OF INDEPENDENCE were scintillating. The young and ambitious generation of founding fathers articulated visions of négritude, , and pan-Africanism, all of which pointed from an oppressed past to a glorious future. Alas, on dimensions of hu- man development, security, and democracy, the post- independence era was fraught. In this chapter, focusing on income, education, and health — all components of human development — we chronicle African states’ strug- gles to fulfill expectations. 1 Income Since 1960, Africa has lagged other regions of the world in per capita income.1 As we see in figure 2.1, 1 The three-letter abbreviations average per capita income in sub-Saharan states stag- used for regions and countries can be found on page xix. nates from 1960 (the year of independence for most sub-Saharan states) to 1990 — three decades that saw economic growth in most other regions. While growth has been more robust since 2000 (our subject in chap- ter 14), recent growth spurts have not dramatically nar- rowed the gap between African countries and other parts of the world.2 2 As we discuss in chapter 14, Botswana is an outlier within Some might argue that this is an unfair race, and that sub-Saharan Africa, experienc- we should be comparing African states to other coun- ing relatively consistent growth tries that were similarly impoverished in 1960. Yet, sub- since the 1960s. Saharan states don’t fare better in this comparison. First, 32 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

NA Figure 2.1 20 GDP per Capita by Region, 1960-1990

15

10 ECA

● EAP

● 5 ● MENA

Average GDP per Capita (1000s USD) Average ● LAC ●

● ● SSA SA 0 1960 1970 1980 1990

we identify a group of thirty-six countries with an average per capita income similar to sub-Saharan African (SSA) states: in 1960, this comparison group had an average GDP per capita of 1,182 USD, 65 USD more than the SSA sample. By 1990, average GDP per capita in this comparison group had increased over 125 percent (i.e., more than doubled); in our SSA sample, the increase over that same period was only 34 percent. Second, we look at specific examples of countries within and beyond sub-Saharan Africa that began the 1960s at similar levels of economic underdevelopment. The poor performance of resource-rich countries like An- gola, Kenya, and Nigeria is especially striking when com- pared with the development trajectories of an Asian “tiger,” , and the new colossus, . As figure 2.2 illustrates, all five states languished in deep collective poverty in 1960. Books and articles on Korea and China pointed to the barriers preventing economic growth, and LAG IN HUMAN DEVELOPMENT 33

South Korea Figure 2.2 GDP per Capita in Selected Cases, 1960-1990 7.5

5.0

2.5

Average GDP per Capita (1000s USD) Average China

Nigeria Kenya Angola

1960 1970 1980 1990

these expositions were not much different from what was written about Africa’s poverty.3 But in the mid-1970s, 3 In her lead article for a sym- Korea broke from the pack with rapid growth. By 1990, posium on “International Co- operation for Social Welfare,” the average income in South Korea reached nearly $9,000 Henderson (1960, 3) argues: per year, roughly ten times the levels achieved by Nigeria, “One half of the world’s popula- tion lives in monsoon Asia [in- Kenya, and Angola. China broke from the pack a decade cluding Korea]. Within this re- after Korea and by 1990 had a per capita income roughly gion, the concentration of pop- two times larger than these African states — a divergence ulation in countries already fac- ing tremendous problems of that continued to grow after 1990. poverty, illiteracy, and ill health, This dismal economic performance among African presents the most serious chal- lenge to national and interna- states forced many economists to question earlier Nobel tional economic and social poli- Prize–winning models of economic growth, which pre- cies and programs.” dicted that poorer countries would grow at a faster rate and, thus, uniformly converge to the higher income levels of more developed states (Sachs and Warner, 1995). These per capita figures are averages. Perhaps sub- Saharan countries are succeeding in raising the floor but simply are not producing exorbitantly wealthy citizens, 34 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

who occupy the long right tail of the income distribution in more developed states. In figure 2.3, we focus instead on whether those at the bottom are escaping dire poverty, and the numbers tell the same story. Using the available data from 2000 to 2010, we calculate the percentage of the population living on less than roughly 3 dollars per day (3.20 in 2011 dollars, to use the World Bank’s precise cutoff). In thirty-five (or 81 percent of) African countries, more than half of the population falls below this level of subsistence; only ten other countries in the world reach such alarming levels. Note that this figure looks more bleak if we exclude the small island countries of Mau- ritius (MUS), Seychelles (SYC), and Comoros (COM). While these less-impoverished islands constitute half of the countries with poverty rates below 40 percent, their combined population (2.9 million in 2010) is miniscule.

EAP ECA LAC 40

30

20

10

0

MENA SA SSA 40

Number of Countries 30

20

10

0 0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100

Percentage of Population Living on Less than 3.20 USD (Average of Non-Missing Data from 2000−2010)

Figure 2.3 2 Education Share of Population in Poverty Income is not the only way to measure development. Nobel Prize winner Amartya Sen has forcefully argued LAG IN HUMAN DEVELOPMENT 35

that development involves enhancing individuals’ “capa- bilities” to lead lives that they value (Sen, 2001). From the individual perspective, education is a central capabil- ity that increases one’s ability to experience and produce “works and events of one’s own choice, religious, liter- ary, musical, and so forth” (Nussbaum, 2011). From the societal perspective, education creates “human capital,” which economists see as an essential driver of economic growth. A great deal of development aid to Africa has gone into the educational sector, but with only limited success. While citizens in other regions can expect to receive nine or more years of education by their mid-twenties, the average African student will not receive more than an elementary school education (see figure 2.4). As one might expect, this affects student achievement; children in many African countries are deprived a basic education and, thus, score below their peers on international exams.

Figure 2.4 Years of Schooling by Region, 1960-1990 12 NA ECA

9 ● EAP LAC ● MENA

● 6 SSA ● SA Average Years of Schooling (Ages 20 − 24) Years Average

0 1960 1970 1980 1990 36 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

More fine-grained evidence comes from the Southern and Eastern Africa Consortium for Monitoring Educa- tional Quality (SACMEQ), a consortium of education ministries, policymakers, and researchers that, in conjunc- tion with UNESCO’s International Institute for Educa- tional Planning, collects primary school data from eleven African countries.4 From their surveys, we have standard- 4 SACMEQ’s Round II survey ized student achievement tests in reading and mathematics includes information on around 40,000 students, 5,300 teachers, for students who were then in the sixth form. The data and 2,000 headmasters from show that about 60 percent of the students do not reach 2,000 primary schools. what SACMEQ considers the minimum acceptable read- ing level, and 86 percent fail to reach what is classified as a desirable reading level. UWEZO, a nongovernmental organization operating in East Africa, reports similar findings from its house- hold surveys in Kenya, (mainland) Tanzania, and Uganda (UWEZO, 2014). Between 2009 and 2012, the NGO col- lected data on 823,074 school-aged children from age six (seven in Tanzania) to sixteen and (in the final round) on 10,422 schools. Their results reveal that “less than a third of children enrolled in grade 3 have basic grade 2 level literacy and numeracy [and] a significant number. . . do not possess foundational grade 2 level skills even as they approach the end of the primary school cycle” (4). More- over, and despite considerable efforts at reform, there were no positive trends over the three rounds of surveys. One plausible answer to the disappointing results comes from the school inspections, which found that at least 10 percent of the teachers were absent from school on any given day. Analysts have pointed to problems beyond the failure to monitor teacher absenteeism: leakage from education budgets (usually supplemented with generous foreign aid, both public and private), high levels of pupil absenteeism (with 34 percent of the students marked as “often absent”), and high dropout rates (24 percent of the schools report LAG IN HUMAN DEVELOPMENT 37

drop-outs occur often) (Devarajan and Fengler, 2013). The culprits are manifold — and we will discuss one candidate cause, the language of instruction, in greater detail in chapter 10— but here we report the outcome: a failure in independent African states to match other regions in the production of human capital. 3 Health Health has been a bright spot in recent African develop- ment. Data from the World Health Organization indicate that germ-based diseases account for a declining share of deaths in sub-Saharan Africa, due in large part to mass vaccination campaigns. Measles has been effectively elim- inated, the percentage of deaths from malaria has been reduced by about 25 percent, and substantial progress has been made on HIV/AIDS and diarrheal diseases. Recog- nizing these trends, the Economist editorialized in 2012 that the decline in African child mortality is “the best story in development.” Yet, despite these recent improvements, mortality rates in Africa remain relatively high. Consider infant mortal- ity, the indicator most often used to judge the quality of a nation’s health sector.5 As can be seen from figure 2.5, 5 Infant mortality is measured sub-Saharan African countries made progress in the thirty by the World Development In- dicators (WDI) as the number years after independence: from well over 100 deaths per of infants dying before reaching 10,000 births, the mortality rate in Africa fell by 30 per- one year of age per 1,000 births. cent in a generation. But, that was the slowest improve- ment of all regions, and the rate in 1990 remained the worst in the world. Returning to our earlier cases, China and South Korea saw rates converging to European stan- dards, while infant mortality rates remained stubbornly 6 According to the World high in Angola and Nigeria. Health Organization, maternal mortality is the number of Africa has an even greater gap looking at maternal mor- women per 100,000 live births tality (see table 2.1).6 This indicator is more indicative that die within forty-two days of the termination of pregnancy of government failures than infant mortality, as mothers’ from any cause related to deaths are typically due to poorly organized clinics and pregnancy or its management. 38 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

180 Figure 2.5

● Infant Mortality by Country, ● 1960-1990

● ● ●Angola ● ● Nigeria ● ●

● 90 ●India ● ●

● ● Kenya

● ● ●China Infant Mortality per 1,000 Live Births Mortality per 1,000 Live Infant

● ● South Korea 0 1960 1970 1980 1990

limited availability of urgent care (rather than the local Table 2.1 Average Maternal Mortality disease burden). While data on maternal mortality does Region 1990 2000 %D not extend as far back in time, even in 1990 the lag re- mained pronounced. By 1990, the rate in Africa was SSA 900 767 –15 SA 687 421 –39 above 900 (per 100,000 live births); compare this to about EAP 259 166 –36 200 for other less developed countries and virtually zero LAC 136 113 –17 MENA 129 91 –29 for Europe. In the subsequent decade, African states made ECA 32 24 –26 considerable progress. Yet, they continued to underper- NA 9.5 10.5 11 form all other regions. While maternal mortality in China declined to fifty-eight by 2000, rates in Angola, Kenya, and Nigeria remained between thirteen and twenty times higher. Poverty, minimal education, and poor health are not independent outcomes: it is difficult for unhealthy chil- dren to keep up in school and, thus, obtain the education that wins them a good job. To be more concrete, consider the effects of intestinal worms (e.g., hookworm, round- worm, whipworm, and schistosomiasis), parasites that LAG IN HUMAN DEVELOPMENT 39

infect about 1.3 billion people worldwide. A study in southern Busia, a farming region in Kenya close to Lake Victoria, found that 92 percent of students surveyed had at least one infection related to these diseases (Miguel and Kremer, 2004). (This could be an underestimate, as stu- dents absent on the day of the survey may have had even higher rates of infection.) The economists who conducted this study found that treating the intestinal worms reduced student absenteeism.7 Disease, then, can not only directly 7 The magnitude of both the di- affect quality of life, but also have an indirect effect on rect effects and existence of any positive spillovers have been educational outcomes. the subjects of a heated de- bate. Humphreys (2015) offers Noncommunicable Health Threats a “nonpartisan’s” summary of the “worm wars.” If progress has been impressive in dealing with germ- based diseases, a growing concern for African health comes from noncommunicable factors, such as nutrition, alcoholism, obesity, and road accidents. A tragic accident occurred in Cameroon in April 2016, where a lead car in a convoy transporting the US ambassador to the UN — driv- ing at breakneck speed — ran over and killed a young boy celebrating the ambassador’s arrival (Hume, Halasz, and Tanku, 2016). This unsettling incident brought attention to a larger problem: road travel in much of sub-Saharan Africa entails considerable risk. In 2013, the Economist reported 26.9 fatalities for every 100,000 people (The Economist Data Team, 2015).8 Compare that with just 8 See also Mathers and Lon- 9.3 fatalities in Europe, despite per capita car ownership car (2006), who estimate that road accidents will be the fourth that is ten times higher than in Africa. Or compare this largest cause of death in low- instead with countries that were similarly underdeveloped income countries in the coming years. Habyarimana and Jack in the early 1960s: India has 16.6; Korea, 12.0 deaths by (2009) suggest why African road accident per 100,000 people (World Health Organi- roads are dangerous and how zation). Moreover, eight of the ten worst countries in the this public health problem can be (partially) remediated. world in terms of automobile death rates are in Africa. And pedestrians bear a good deal of the burden, account- ing for 40 percent of Africa’s road deaths, compared with a world average of 22 percent. 40 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

The AIDS Pandemic Africa’s AIDS epidemic is by far the worst in the world. To be sure, there has been notable progress in stemming its tide in sub-Saharan Africa. There were, according to UN data, 2.3 million new HIV infections detected in 2000; in 2014, that number was down to 1.4 million, a drop of 41 percent (UNAIDS, 2015). Still, in 2017, according to AVERT, 25.7 million people were HIV positive in Africa, which amounted to 70 percent of the global total, with 660,000 AIDS-related deaths in 2017 computed for Africa (AVERT, 2015).

A South Africa Case Study

Given the scale of the epidemic, we dive deeper into the South African case, drawing on excellent qualitative work by Lieberman (2009). As it is challenging to summa- rize Lieberman’s statement of the problem without also previewing his explanation, this section briefly touches on some proposed causes of South Africa’s HIV/AIDS epidemic — a discussion we otherwise largely defer to parts II and III. Health data from South Africa again reveal that poverty can not fully explain mortality. After all, South Africa ranks among the top five richest countries in Africa. Yet, it is also the country that has had the largest HIV/AIDS 9 This comes from the CIA Fact- epidemic, with an estimated 6.3 million people (19.1 per- book. In percentage terms, as of cent of the general population) living HIV positive.9 In 2011, southern Africa is the re- gion most affected by the virus. KwaZulu-Natal, a province east of Lesotho, for women In Botswana, Lesotho, Swazi- between the ages of thirty and thirty-four, the infection land, and South Africa, the per- centage of the population living rate exceeds 35 percent. HIV-positive ranges from 19.9 At the beginning of the crisis in the early 1980s, nearly (South Africa) to 26.5 (Swazi- land). Nearby Zimbabwe, Zam- 90 percent of the diagnosed AIDS cases were among bia, Mozambique, and Namibia males, mostly homosexual and bisexual. But by 1989, have somewhat lower percent- ages, but all over ten percent. heterosexual transmission became the principal means No other country in the world of transmission, and the epidemic grew extraordinarily breaks ten percent. LAG IN HUMAN DEVELOPMENT 41

fast. By 2005, an estimated 320,000 South Africans had died of AIDS-related causes. Average life expectancy in South Africa was sixty-four in 1992; ten years later it fell to forty-six, a shocking decline due almost entirely to HIV/AIDS. Although South Africa has a democratically elected government, its response to the crisis was halting and slow; it was not until 2000 that AIDS programs appeared as a line item in the national budget. The health ministry, wracked with resignations by senior officials assigned to the AIDS program, was not only slow to respond but antagonistic to potential partners. The ministry was un- willing to support nongovernmental efforts to provide medical aid, leading civil society organizations to protest against and, ultimately, sue the government for nonful- fillment of the National AIDS Plan. The government also alienated the international medical community by promoting its own AIDS drug without any evidence of its effectiveness. The government seemed uninterested in solving the public health crisis, as it failed to target information to the gay community, the early victims of the epidemic, and even cut its AIDS-education budget in the mid-1990s, just as the percentage of cases was rising. It was not until 2007 that South Africa belatedly agreed to address this health catastrophe with reporting that met international standards. What distinguishes South Africa’s delayed response to this health crisis from similarly situated countries else- where in the world? In an ingenious comparison with Brazil’s more comprehensive and rapid response to AIDS, Lieberman is able to rule out standard explanations such as regime type (both South Africa and Brazil were third- wave democracies), bureaucratic competence (both had moderately effective government services), and civil so- ciety (both had well-positioned activists demanding gov- ernment action). Instead, Lieberman focuses attention 42 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

on these countries’ different levels of electoral competi- tion. He shows that opposition parties in South Africa, namely the Democratic Alliance and Inkatha Freedom Party, were unable to challenge the African National Congress’s (ANC’s) dominance in 2004. Facing little competition, the ANC could remain silent on the epi- demic, despite the government’s glaring failure to address the public health crisis.10 10 Unlike Brazil or even other African countries, the ANC’s Yet, the ANC’s unassailable electoral control cannot be leadership in ending apartheid the entire explanation. Autocrats, such as Yoweri Musev- earned them loyalty among a eni of Uganda and Rwanda’s , also faced lit- great majority and insulated them from cries for action in tle political competition. However, they responded much response to HIV/AIDS. Nelson more aggressively to HIV/AIDS. Mandela, whose charismatic au- thority was unquestioned, did Sharp and reified racial boundaries provide another not use his bully pulpit to speak plausible explanation for South Africa’s delayed response out on AIDS, as he feared it would hurt his electoral stand- to the epidemic (Lieberman, 2009, 143). The rigid cat- ing (Lieberman, 2009, 140). egories of “black/African,” “Coloured,” “Indian,” and His successor , despite his technocratic back- “white/European” date back to the apartheid era and re- ground, followed suit and had main highly relevant. For example, surveys from the his health minister promote a 1990s suggest that nearly 25 percent of South Africans do healthy diet as the proper anti- dote. Jacob Zuma, Mbeki’s suc- not want a neighbor of a different race, and interracial mar- cessor, continued this despica- riage is almost nonexistent. Indeed, race almost perfectly ble political tradition of denial, recommending a shower after predicts the language spoken in the home and the house- sex with an HIV victim to re- hold’s media diet. Perhaps unsurprisingly, discussions duce the risk of infection. about AIDS in South Africa have also been racialized, with blacks (blaming white gays) and whites (blaming black sex workers) each seeing the other as responsible. Conspiracy theories abound in the popular press about how the disease is being used by one group to decimate the other. This racialism reached embarrassing levels when the head of the South African National Blood Ser- vices proposed disposing of blood from black donors in fear of infecting the wider society. In the face of this racialization, a technical and un- biased approach to treating the epidemic was politically challenging. In office, Mandela was silent on the issue. LAG IN HUMAN DEVELOPMENT 43

Thabo Mbeki, his successor, argued publicly in 2001 that civil society groups had a hidden agenda; their demands for action were, in fact, proclamations that “our conti- nent is doomed to an inevitable mortal end because of our unconquerable devotion to the sin of lust” (quoted in Lieberman, 2009, 158).11 Racial boundaries, a clear fact 11 Once out of office, Mandela of life in many sub-Saharan states, but especially in South changed course. At an interna- tional conference in in Africa, have reinforced a culture of blame and denial of 2001, he gave implicit support responsibility that has not served citizens well in the face to the international response to AIDS. In January 2005, the of a health catastrophe. cause became personal with his One might ask, if Lieberman is correct, how do we last surviving son, Makgatho, dying of AIDS-related compli- explain the vigilant government response to the pandemic cations. Politically, however, he in Rwanda, a country in which ethnic boundaries divid- walked a fine line, never crit- ing Tutsis and Hutus (reified under the Belgians) have icizing Mbeki’s reluctance to endorse the international cam- been portrayed as racial? Indeed, since the 1994 geno- paign to fight AIDS. cide, there has been a “dramatic increase in [international] resources to fight the HIV/AIDS epidemic. . . and a corre- sponding increase in the availability of services. . . . With these resources, the Government of Rwanda has rapidly launched and brought to scale national HIV/AIDS ser- vices” (Kayirangwa et al., 2006, i27). One explanation is that post-genocide, many Tutsi women were infected with AIDS due to the gender-based violence perpetrated during the genocide. Kagame’s Tutsi-led government was, even in the absence of political competition, especially concerned with addressing the needs of this constituency and invited international organizations to help. But this cannot be the full answer. Well before Kagame’s administration, “in 1986, Rwanda was the first country in the world to conduct and report on a nation- ally representative HIV seroprevalence survey. Also, in 1986, the Ministry of Health, the Red Cross, and the Norwegian Red Cross initiated an extensive AIDS educa- tion program using radio and public health educators. In 1987, the National AIDS Program was established in col- laboration with the World Health Organization (WHO)” 44 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

(Kayirangwa et al., 2006, p. i27). Consistent with Lieber- man’s argument, it could be that HIV/AIDS was never racialized in Rwanda, with one group blaming the other for the disease and using their alleged culpability as an excuse to deny public services. We do not have the data to support or refute that story. Whether sharp racial bound- aries impede public health campaigns outside of South Africa, thus, remains an open question. In either case, South Africa’s failure to stem the AIDS pandemic cer- tainly weakens the Economist’s sanguine evaluation of Africa’s health programs. The Influence of PEPFAR on African Public Health Foreign assistance has been a popular approach for addressing Africa’s underdevelopment (see chapter 12 for our discussion of foreign aid’s effectiveness). The President’s Emergency Plan for AIDS Relief (PEPFAR) was US president George W. Bush’s singular effort to address the international AIDS pandemic. From 2003 to 2013, $42 billion was allocated for prevention, treatment, and palliative care. There were fifteen focus countries in this program, twelve of them in Africa. PEPFAR is an exceptionally resourced example of aid targeted at a specific problem. Indeed, PEPFAR constituted an infu- sion of funds larger in many cases than the entire health budget of the recipient countries. At one point, PEPFAR equaled 118 percent of the government’s health budget in Ethiopia, 128 percent in Rwanda, 155 percent in Kenya, 234 percent in Mozambique, and 249 percent in Uganda. There is little question that PEPFAR has been conse- quential in reducing adult deaths due to HIV/AIDS. One study estimates that the program averted 2.9 million HIV infections from 2004 to 2013 and, by increasing the life span of those infected, reduced the number of orphans on the continent by nine million (Heaton et al., 2015). But the scope of the intervention’s effects has been LAG IN HUMAN DEVELOPMENT 45

limited. For example, there is no evidence that the heavy emphasis on abstinence as a preventive measure had any effect on sex behavior (Lo, Lowe, and Bendavid, 2016). Similarly, PEPFAR has not helped to reduce neonatal mortality rates, and if anything, evidence suggests a slight increase in such deaths after the PEPFAR intervention. Lee and Izama (2015) suggest this is due to low-quality primary health systems, which did not benefit from the infusion of PEPFAR funds. These authors argue that PEPFAR not only failed to improve local health services, but actually crowded out more effective domestic pro- grams; the increased funding and salaries for those treat- ing HIV/AIDS diverted qualified staff from other health care services. Ebola Outbreak in 2014 The Ebola outbreak in 2014 provides additional per- spective on the health lag in sub-Saharan Africa. As of early 2016, there were 11,315 deaths in Africa caused by Ebola since the most recent outbreak. In Liberia, the figure is 4,809; in Sierra Leone, 3,955; in Guinea, 2,536, and in Nigeria, 8 (BBC News, 2016). A new outbreak in the town of Beni in the Democratic Republic of Congo in 2018, despite the development of new vaccines, sadly reveals that this disease remains a threat in Africa. Fighting Ebola demands state capacity; tracking in- dividuals who have come in contact with infected indi- viduals requires extensive government surveillance and record keeping. A professionalized medical establishment with clear rules of engagement thus appears essential for containing and preventing Ebola. We see some indica- tion of this among the affected West African countries. Christensen et al. (2018a) test this claim experimentally: roughly a year before the Ebola outbreak in Sierra Leone, two interventions were randomly assigned to government- run health clinics. One focused on community monitoring 46 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

of clinics and the other on status awards for nurses. The authors find that these programs increased the perceived quality of local health care, encouraged sick patients to seek care, and increased the reported number of Ebola cases. Nigeria quickly contained confirmed cases and stemmed the spread of the disease — a feat that Guinea, Liberia, and Sierra Leone struggled with. Nigeria has about four physicians and eighteen trained nurses and midwives per 10,000 people, about four times that of the countries least successful in containing the outbreak. But trust in government also played a role. In deal- ing with this epidemic, public health officials in Sierra Leone, Liberia, and Guinea called upon communities to change deep-rooted behaviors, such as burial customs. These dramatic behavioral changes would be a tall order in any setting; following years of poor service provision and corruption scandals, many distrusting citizens de- fied such demands, with some health workers in Guinea being killed by a skeptical and fearful mob. Based on a unique survey in , Liberia, Tsai, Blair, and Morse (2015) suggest that distrust in government con- tributed to the spread of the disease: dubious households were less likely to use preventive measures and exhibited lower support for containment policies. (In part 2, we discuss the slave trade as one historical explanation for this high level of distrust.) It is informative to compare the crisis response to Ebola in West Africa with the SARS epidemic in East Asia, af- fecting China, Hong Kong, Vietnam, , , and Malaysia, with further isolated cases around the world. Its sudden outbreak in October 2002 at first was kept un- der cloak and veil by the Chinese government. But within months the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) and the World Health Organization (WHO) were in full investigative mode, Hong Kong and Singapore es- tablished quarantines, and the Chinese premier shortly LAG IN HUMAN DEVELOPMENT 47

thereafter issued quarantine orders and threatened to pun- ish local officials who did not report SARS cases in a timely and accurate manner. Within five months of the outbreak, the affected countries set up a joint ministerial task force to address the health pandemic, and in July 2003, nine months after outbreak, the WHO was able to announce that the disease had been contained (Timeline of the SARS outbreak, 2016). While there are of course many differences between SARS and Ebola — including the threat to African cultural practices from isolating vic- tims from their kin — the ability of East Asian states (a region with average incomes just slightly above those of sub-Saharan African countries in 1960) to resolve their health problem without facing massive distrust from their own citizens reveals the special problem many African states face in addressing crises that challenge the health and safety of their own populations. Health and Human Development in Africa Health is a crucial component of human development. There is much to applaud about recent improvements in post-independence Africa. But on several dimensions we see a persistent lag compared with the rest of the world. First, although communicable diseases now account for fewer deaths, the gap with the rest of the world remains. Second, there is a disturbing rise in Africa of deaths due to noncommunicable conditions, whether from obesity, al- coholism, or road safety. And, as shown with road safety, these death rates are greater than in other postcolonial countries that were underdeveloped a half-century ago. Third, in areas where government intervention is key to success, such as in AIDS treatment or responding to unan- ticipated public health epidemics (Ebola), many African governments lack the professionalism and trust to mount an effective response. 48 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

4 Conclusion Human development is a multifaceted concept, includ- ing income, education, and health. In this chapter we reviewed the record of African governments in advancing the human development of their citizens. On all three dimensions, we report progress since independence but not enough to close the gap with most other countries of the world. This is but one part of Africa’s lag that this book seeks to explain. 3. Lag in Democracy

INTHEFINALYEARSOFCOLONIALRULE, African leaders negotiated the transition to independence, hag- gling over the details of constitutions based largely on Western European traditions. Both colonial authorities and those inheriting the newly independent states hoped for democracies that would respect the rule of law. Yet, this hope was short-lived. In this chapter, we describe the collapse of democratic rule under a deluge of military coups and the rise of states built on selling offices rather than impartially administering law — what Max Weber called “prebendal,” but Africanists now dub “neopatrimo- nial” (Bratton and van de Walle, 1994).1 1 In a patrimonial state, power flows directly from the leader. 1 Turn to Authoritarian Rule The “neo-” prefix indicates a mixed system, in which both Charismatic founders were largely young men, traditional authority and bureau- cratic agencies command re- schooled by missionaries, recipients of European uni- sources. versity educations, and commoners. Peaceful anticolonial mobilization brought them to power, and they presided over constitutions derived from European democratic tra- ditions. They had grand ambitions for their countries and for their continent and were revered by their fellow citizens. Yet, in a few short years, the optimism we describe in chapter 1 gave way to authoritarian tendencies. Zolberg (1966, 66) presciently observed the first generation of 50 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

leaders transforming their political regimes using a variety of tactics:

Co-optation, intimidation, exile, or detention of political opponents; modification of the electoral system to make competition impossible or at least unlikely; transforma- tion of the constitution inherited from the European tradi- tion to give wide discretionary authority to the executive and to restrict the activities of representative assemblies; the use of a criterion of political loyalty to select key administrators and division of the country into satrapies; administrative control over local government; reduction of the independence of the judiciary. . . ; transformation of major voluntary associations into ancillary organs of the party or their political neutralization; control over writ- ten and radio communications; reduction of consultation within the party and of accountability of the leadership to the members.

In sum, Zolberg distinguished two complementary projects of the charismatic generation after independence: “the attempt to achieve unanimity by erasing all traces of political opposition” and merging their political party and the government by creating what has become known as the “one-party state” (122-27). Despite their charisma and the excitement of inde- pendence, these early leaders faced real (if not subver- sive) opposition movements. Consider J. B. Danquah; he founded the United Gold Coast Convention in Ghana and helped elevate Nkrumah to the national political stage. He became a strong advocate of free speech and a power- ful opponent of preventive detention. Similarly, Lamine Guèye of Senegal, although he remained a member of the Union Progressiste Sénégalaise, publicly criticized Senghor’s autocratic tendencies. Politicians of stature and integrity spoke out against the first generation of post- independence leaders. Fearing disintegration and eager to reclaim political and economic control from colonial in- LAG IN DEMOCRACY 51

terests, these leaders greeted this dissent with censorship and repression. Guinea’s charismatic founder, Sékou Touré, led the way in demonizing and repressing dissenters. As an ap- prentice in the French communist labor union, Touré had been schooled in authoritarian values. Upon assuming leadership of Guinea’s Parti démocratique de Guinée (PDG), he saw unity as the party’s principal goal. In speeches, he insisted that any opposition to the PDG rep- resented saboteurs associated with the ancient colonial state. His political enemies languished in notorious dun- geons. Alas, Touré’s ideas were not exceptional in the early independence period. In Ghana, documents from Kwame Nkrumah’s Convention People’s Party (CPP) rejected the notion that political opposition was important for democ- racy. In Tanzania, Julius Nyerere denied that the ab- sence of a political opposition was tantamount to dictator- ship (Sigmund, 1963, 193, 197). In Mali, Madeira Keita (1960, 19) published an article titled “Le Parti Unique en Afrique,” or “The Single Party in Africa.” In it he claims that “if the party is the true expression of the genuine aspirations of the people,” there is no need for civil soci- ety. Finally, in Senegal, Léopold Senghor (1961) wrote that opposition can only be “tempted to serve foreign powers. . . . Our duty is to prevent subversion.” While the elimination of competing parties under- mined political accountability, the imposed unanimity did not facilitate the rapid expansion of public services or the adoption of growth-promoting policies. The indepen- dence parties were not unlike L. Frank Baum’s portayal of the Wizard of Oz: imposing in their awesome rhetoric, but pathetically weak in their ability to implement the wishes of their populations. When Bienen (1970) sought to find similarities between the Tanganyika African Na- tional Union (TANU) and the Communist Party of the 52 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Soviet Union (CPSU), he was shocked to find empty of- fices outside the then capital in with hardly any organizational structure.2 Nkrumah (1962) similarly 2 Bienen (1970, 470) concludes noted that a year after independence, “the general staff [of that the TANU “does not pro- vide an institution which can the CPP] numbered less than thirty. The office was poorly transform the economy. . . it is equipped.” He ordered a rapid party-building campaign too weak and too loose and has too few material and human re- that eventually led to the declaration of Ghana as a one- sources to tackle development party state in 1964. A year later, in Côte d’Ivoire, at its problems.” first congress after independence, with its leading party having staved off several internal rebellions, the PDCI declared itself “a single party, for a single people, with a single leader” (Zolberg, 1966, 100). Nyerere could appeal to African roots of community to justify one-party rule, and Nkrumah could appeal to utopian goals. Others pointed out that since there were no ideological differences among factions, it would be best to resolve distributional issues in the context of a single party. But W. Arthur Lewis, a distinguished West Indian economist and adviser to Nkrumah, saw it for what it was. “The single-party,” he proclaimed, “fails in all its claims. It cannot represent all the people; or maintain free discus- sion; or give stable government; or above all, reconcile the differences between various regional groups. It is not natural to West African culture, except in the sense in which cancer is natural to West African culture. . . . It is partly the product of the hysteria of independence when some men found it possible to seize the state and suppress their opponents” (quoted in Tignor, 2006, 209). The de- scent into authoritarian rule — however cynical or noble the motivations — came shortly after independence. 2 Breakdown of Civilian Rule For many countries, democracy was threatened through military takeover or coups d’état. Generals com- posed a first generation of coup leaders intent on stamping out the corruption and tribalism that infected young civil- LAG IN DEMOCRACY 53

ian regimes. But noncommissioned officers led a second wave of coups, and these leaders relied heavily on the loy- alty of ethnic kin rather than the support of the military or a broad political party. While coup leaders often promised to relinquish power to democratically elected successors, reforms were usually short-lived. As is apparent in fig- ure 3.1, sub-Saharan states became more autocratic (on average) between 1960 and 1990 according to Polity, a common measure of regime type.3 While the region actu- 3 Polity is an annualized coun- try score ranging from 10 (a ally beats the Middle East and North Africa on this metric, full autocracy) to +10 (a full that feat offers little consolation. democracy) The halfway house The antidemocratic trend began all too quickly. In between democracy and autoc- racy, in the range from 5 to Comoros and what is now the Democratic Republic of +5 on the Polity scale, has been the Congo, chaotic transitions provoked coups in the very dubbed “anocracy.” year of independence. The trend continued in more sta- ble countries just three years later. In 1963 Sylvanus Olympio, president of Togo, was overthrown and assassi- nated. He was deposed by an army of only 250 soldiers,

Figure 3.1 10 ECA Average Polity Score by Region, 1960-1990

LAC 5

● EAP ●

● ● ● SA 0 ● ● Average Polity Score Average −5 SSA MENA

−10

1960 1970 1980 1990

Democracy Anocracy Autocracy 54 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

joined by Togolese veterans of France’s brutal war with Algeria. When France decommissioned its Togolese sol- diers, these men expected to be honored and employed in Togo’s national army. Yet, Olympio sealed his fate by refusing, claiming that the veterans were “mercenar- ies who were killing our Algerian friends when we were fighting for independence” (First, 1970). The perpetrators of the coup replaced the president with his political ri- val, Nicholas Grunitsky. Under Grunitsky, the post-coup army expanded to 1,200 soldiers, accepting 700 veterans of the French forces (Grundy, 1968). Four years later, one of the coup leaders, Lt. Col. Gnassingbé Eyadéma, assumed power and ruled Togo for a generation. This stunning coup, which challenged the democratic future of a newly independent African state, was not an anomaly but rather a blueprint for soldiers in other African states. Indeed, Togo’s coup was only the start of a deluge of coups across much of the continent. Figure 3.2 illus-

BEN 63 65 65 67 69 72 72 75 120 SSA SDN 66 66 69 71 75 76 77 COG 63 66 68 68 69 70 72 GHA 66 67 72 78 79 79 UGA 66 71 74 74 80 SLE 67 67 68 71 NGA 66 66 75 76 LAC ETH 60 61 74 77 90 BDI 65 66 66 76 TCD 75 76 77 SOM 61 69 78 BFA 66 74 80 ZAR 60 65 TGO 63 67 NER 74 76 60 MRT 78 80 MLI 68 78 GNQ 69 79 COM 75 78 CAF 66 79 ZMB 80 SYC 77 Cumulative Number of Coups Cumulative 30 MENA EAP SEN 62 RWA 73 ● ● MOZ 75

● 74 ● ECA MDG ● SA LBR 80 GNB 80 0 GAB 64 AGO 77 1960 1970 1980 1990 2 4 6 8 Number of Coups and Year (1960−1980) (a) Total Number of Coups by Region (b) African Coups, 1960-1980 (Black = Success)

Figure 3.2 Deluge of Coups in Africa LAG IN DEMOCRACY 55

trates a sharp and sustained increase in coups beginning in the mid-1960s. Between 1960 and 1980, there were ninety-one coup attempts in Africa, of which fifty-one succeeded. In those two decades, twenty-six different African countries experienced a successful coup; seven states saw three or more successful challenges (Benin, six; Ghana, four; Burkina Faso, three; Burundi, three; Nigeria, three; Republic of Congo, three; Uganda, three). Even while challenges to civilian leadership declined sharply in Asia and the Americas in the 1980s (i.e., the total number of coups in figure 3.2(a) levels off for all other regions), African states have seen continued military interventions: between 1960 and 1990, there was only one year (1988) in which the continent was coup-free (Powell and Thyne, 2011).4 4 Factors that predict coups in- clude higher levels of demo- Corruption, economic crises, and ethnic tensions cratic competition, rapid social quickly undermined electoral democracies in the postcolo- change (e.g., urbanization), eth- nial period. The first-generation military leaders came nic tensions, economic down- turns, and decreasing military into power presenting themselves as “caretakers,” seeking spending. Electoral support to restore integrity and nationalism and, ultimately, place for the winning party in early elections and armies that are democracy on a stronger footing. But instead of politi- not constituted from anticolo- cally neutral officers bringing order as national saviors, nial rebels or colonial armies these initial coups were followed by a second era of mili- are associated with reduced coups risk (Londregan and tary rule, during which more junior officers transformed Poole, 1990; Jackman, 1978; into personalist leaders. Figure 3.3 offers a simple but McGowan and Johnson, 1984; Powell, 2012). revealing timeline for the four cases we review below: elected leaders are replaced by military brass and, espe- cially toward the end of the period, personalist dictators. 3 The Senior Officers Intercede Nigeria Nigeria’s two coups in 1966 were perhaps the most dra- matic failures of British-inspired democratic institutions in Africa. The country was not named by a charismatic founder, as was the case in Ghana. Rather, three sep- 56 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Regime Type DEMOCRACY MILITARY (PARTY−)PERSONAL

Benin

Uganda

Ghana

Nigeria

1960 1970 1980 1990

Figure 3.3 Regime Change in Selected arate regions were imagined as a coherent state by the Cases, 1960-1990 wife of the colonial governor, Lord Frederick Lugard, who called the combined territory “Nigeria.” Lugard es- tablished a colonial order through what he dubbed the “Dual Mandate” (1926) — a system that provided salaries to traditional leaders (chiefs, kings, emirs) in return for their loyalty (a strategy of indirect rule that we discuss at greater length in chapter 9). Lugard presumed that these traditional leaders enjoyed local legitimacy, making it eas- ier for them to control their constituents. He ruled through emirs in the Hausa-dominated Northern region; through ancestral-city kings in the Yoruba-dominated West; and 5 An acephalous, or egalitarian, society lacks political hierar- through “warrant chiefs” (a modern imposition on an chy. acephalous society) in the Igbo-dominated East (Afigbo, Figure 3.4 1972).5 Nigeria’s Largest Ethnic Groups These three regions — the North, West, and East — were quite heterogeneous, rife with minorities who bris- tled at the favored roles accorded to the dominant group Hausa−Fulani in each region (figure 3.4). A constitution for Nigeria, ne-

gotiated in 1954 and serving as a prelude to independence, Yoruba gave substantial powers to the three regional governments, Igbo much to the chagrin of the minority groups. These smaller LAG IN DEMOCRACY 57

groups appealed to the British-appointed Minorities Com- mission, but their claims were rejected in 1958. In addition to these internal conflicts, the regional gov- ernments disagreed about the allocation of power in an independent Nigeria. Emirs in the North feared south- ern dominance. Northern populations tended to have lower levels of education.6 Thus, the North preferred 6 This educational gap was due continued British administration to a prospective admin- in part to colonial authorities’ decision to discourage Chris- istration run by “southerners” (i.e., Yorubas and Igbos). tian missionaries from working Meanwhile, there were deep tensions within the South. in the North for fear they might cause unrest in a predominantly Obafemi Awolowo, the Yoruba leader we discussed in Muslim population. chapter 1, invested revenues from the 1950s cocoa boom in free education and health care. Igbos, on the other hand, saw lower returns on their palm products and, thus, feared losing out on civil service positions to the economically ascendant Yoruba. Under these conditions, post-independence politics be- came a dangerous game. First, the key pre-independence elections deepened the rivalry between Awolowo and Nnambdi Azikiwe, the leading Igbo politician. The North seized upon this rivalry, allying with the East to form a government: Azikiwe assumed the presidency, while a Northern leader, Sir Abubakar Tafawa Balewa, became the prime minister. Second, battles broke out over the census. While a census may sound like a simple count- ing exercise, it is a political lightning rod in countries where the allocation of power or public spending depends on groups’ relative sizes.7 A first census tally in 1962 7 Clifford Geertz, the preemi- worked to the East’s advantage; a recount then inflated the nent American cultural anthro- pologist of his time, and part numbers of the other two regions. Census politics turned of the founding group of the into a life and death issue, as the results determined which University of Chicago’s Com- mittee on New Nations, consid- ethnic group was most likely to assume and maintain po- ered census-taking in new states litical power. Third, an intra-Yoruba political rivalry led a “pole. . . around which para- to electoral violence in the regional elections of 1964. political vortices tend to form” (Geertz, 1973, p. 275). Awolowo refused to accept the North-East compact and sought to build a leftist coalition by mobilizing Hausa 58 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

commoners (talakawa). His Yoruba rival, Samuel Ladoke Akintola, came from a different ancestral city, served as Western governor, and wanted to work in concert with elected federal authorities. Awolowo plotted a takeover in the Western region, and the federal army had to restore order. Amid this political uncertainty, rumors of a coup prolif- erated. And on January 15, 1966, in a poorly coordinated operation, military plotters murdered one Yoruba (Ak- intola) and two Hausas (Balewa and Sir Ahmadu Bello, the head of the Northern People’s Congress, the political party representing Hausa interests). The plotters missed Awolowo and did not detain or kill any Igbo politicians. This first coup quickly sparked a second overthrow. Igbo officials had escaped assassination during the initial coup; moreover, an Igbo officer, General Johnson Thomas Umunnakwe Aguiyi-Ironsi, assumed leadership following the unrest. To many, these two facts suggested an Igbo power play. Their fears were amplified when General Ironsi sought an end to regional governance, which was in- terpreted as a plot to establish Igbo hegemony throughout Nigeria. Elements in the military, whose officer corps was largely Hausa, quickly plotted a counter-coup. On July 29, 1966, only seven months after the first coup, Ironsi was assassinated. Yakubu “Jack” Dan-Yumma Gowon, a Christian from a minority group in the North, took the helm. Since January 1966, Nigeria has spent half of its existence under military rule. Ghana The early coups became a deluge with the fall of Nkrumah — a coup that shocked even careful observers of African politics. In retrospect, it is more easily under- stood. Nkrumah was at his charismatic height when he demanded independence and could blame Britain for any policy failures (Apter, 2015). But once independent and LAG IN DEMOCRACY 59

in power in 1957, his monumental goals faced complex re- ality. He indulged himself by building useless monuments (including statues of himself) and portraying himself as the country’s redeemer (osagyefo). More hopeful, he in- vested in a massive electrical project that included a dam on the Volta River. This was to be paid for, in part, by taxes on farmers, who were forced to sell their product (co- coa most importantly) to marketing boards that continued the colonial practice of paying below-market prices. The marketing boards could buy low and sell high on world markets with the difference accruing to the state and its development projects. As we document in chapter 12, this economic doctrine had a number of problems. Principally, farmers learned that they could surreptitiously cross the border into Côte d’Ivoire, where they could get a much better price for their goods. This smuggling impoverished the Ghanaian treasury. Economic failure unleashed political opposition. Nkrumah responded by either imprisoning or forcibly exiling his political opponents. In a tense political envi- ronment, a military coup in February 1966 brought an end to democratic institutions. A “National Liberation Coun- cil,” a joint operation of the police and army with a clear army command structure under General Joseph Ankrah, took power. Political parties were banned, and the Council promised order, security, freedom, and a quick restora- tion of democracy. Indeed, they did return the country to democracy, but it was a short-lived civilian regime, succeeded by a generation of military regimes. Nkrumah became an exile in Guinea. He died in 1972, and, by then, his dreams for restored Ghanaian glory were long dead. The then president of Ghana, Ignatius Kutu Acheampong (who also came to power through a coup), graciously allowed Nkrumah to be buried in his homeland. There is now a mausoleum in his hometown serving as a 60 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

tourist site. But his fall from grace marked an end to the optimistic vision of his charismatic cohort of founders. Uganda received no mention in our discussion of Africa’s charismatic founders. Unlike Jomo Kenyatta in neighboring Kenya, Ugandans never united behind Obote, who constantly struggled to garner a legislative majority. Obote led the Ugandan People’s Congress (UPC) — an alliance of his ethnic group, the Langi (6 percent), the Acholi (5 percent), the Toro (3 percent), and the Banyoro (3 percent). As these population shares indicate, the party represented a small share of the country’s population. Obote’s rise to power, despite this small support base, had less to do with his leadership qualities and much more to do with internal conflicts within other, larger ethnic groups. Most importantly, the Baganda were split. The Baganda are Uganda’s largest linguistic group ( 16 per- ⇠ cent). Its king (the Kabaka), a Protestant, never submitted to British rule; instead, by treaty, his kingdom became a British protectorate. But in preparation for indepen- dence, the British refused to accord his kingdom special status. His supporters therefore boycotted the final elec- tion before independence in 1961. This handed victory to the Democratic Party, which garnered the votes of the Catholic Baganda, who still participated in the election. Recognizing this error, in the first election after inde- pendence, the Kabaka led a monarchist party called the Kabaka Yekka or “king only” party. Perhaps unsurpris- ingly, this party didn’t enjoy much support outside of Baganda or among Catholics. Obote’s UPC, the Kabaka Yekka, and the Democratic Party all contested the 1962 election. The Democratic Party emerged with the most seats, though not a major- ity. Fearing that the Democratic Party might threaten the LAG IN DEMOCRACY 61

monarchy, the Kabaka struck a deal with Obote: Obote assumed the role of prime minister, granting the Kabaka assurances that his royal prerogatives would be main- tained. At this pivotal moment, Obote demonstrated less charisma than political cunning. As was the case in Nigeria, politics became a high- stakes game. Obote proposed a referendum that would transfer land from the Baganda to the Banyoro, which the latter believed the British had wrongly seized and redistributed to the Baganda. The Kabaka responded by leveling a corruption charge against Obote in the National Assembly. Obote quickly abrogated the colonially in- spired constitution of 1962 and deposed the Kabaka, driv- ing him into exile in London. Obote relied on his northern troops to crush Baganda militias comprising World War II veterans, and sought popularity by articulating a left- ist program, called the “Common Man’s Charter.” This move to the left led to a rapid outflow of capital and en- suing unemployment and inflation. Urban gangsterism (kondoism) became rife. Obote needed the army, largely composed of the Acho- lis from Uganda’s far north, to confront the Baganda.8 8 Andrew Brooks (dissertation A mutiny in 1964 was a warning that the military’s co- in progress) estimates that, pre- independence, the Acholi rep- operation required accommodations. Obote gave virtual resented 70 percent of the sol- autonomy to the deputy commander, , who began diers; the Baganda, less than 2 percent. recruiting soldiers from his Kakwa ethnic group. Many of the Kakwa troops were from neighboring southern Su- dan, where they had honed their fighting skills against the Sudanese government in Khartoum. Amin’s army became an autonomous force of wealth and power throughout the country. Even Obote feared Amin and built a special presidential guard from his Langi coethnics. In April 1971, elections were imminent, and observers thought that Obote, through a proposed alliance with the 62 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Baganda, would maintain power. But Amin intervened and, despite the presidential guard, displaced Obote be- fore the elections. Unlike the coup in Ghana, this was not a peaceful replacement of civilians for soldiers. Amin brought a reign of terror, with large-scale imprisonments and an estimated 250,000 Ugandans killed in the blood- bath that ensued. 4 Junior Officer Coups and the Dominance of Personalist Rule Junior officers, those commissioned officers ranking below colonels and generals, followed the examples pro- vided by their superiors. While the first successful coups involving senior officers occurred in the same year of in- dependence (Comoros; the Democratic Republic of the Congo), junior officers didn’t successfully overthrow a government until the fourth year of independence (in Bu- rundi). The average number of years of independence before the first successful senior officer coup was 12.5 years; the average number of years for the first successful junior officer coup was 18.5 years (A. Brooks, 2016).9 9 These statistics include some North African cases, including These junior officers not only struck later, they also re- Algeria, , , and lied on different strategies for establishing and consolidat- Tunisia. ing control. Unlike the generals, junior officers could not count on the support of the military hierarchy; they were, after all, ignoring the chain of command. Instead, these junior officers created populist parties (often with a leftist slant) and, more importantly, surrounded themselves with ethnic kin to protect against counter-coups. Their youth and energy gave them some of the charismatic appeal ac- corded to many of Africa’s founding fathers. These once junior officers who became personalist dictators include (Liberia), Mathieu Kérékou (Benin), Jerry Rawlings (Ghana), and and Blaise Cam- paoré (Burkina Faso, formerly Upper Volta). Vignettes of LAG IN DEMOCRACY 63

the coups in Benin and Ghana illustrate the progression from military rule to personalist dictatorship. Benin Immediately after independence, Benin suffered from corruption, , and forced austerity. Per capita GDP fell by almost 5 percent between 1960 and 1962. The increasingly authoritarian rule of Hubert Maga brought popular discontent and then an outpouring of sympathy when Colonel Christophe Soglo led a coup in 1963. Soglo permitted a quick return to civilian rule, but power oscillated between military officers and civil- ian politicians. At one point the country was ruled by a three-member presidential council, whose members ro- tated power. Maga — the premier overthrown just seven years earlier — actually enjoyed a brief return to power under this system, chairing this presidential council from 1970 to 1972. Despite this frequent turnover (perhaps even because of it), political gridlock paralyzed the government. Junior officers then moved in, led by Mathieu Kérékou. He was a low-level officer who served as an aide-de-camp to Maga during his first presidency. Kérékou advanced in rank after his cousin, Maurice Kouandété, became military ruler in 1967. In October 1972, he took control of the country, replacing an ineffective civilian regime (Allen, 1989). Kérékou was a populist whose rule marked a break with the past. His first major speech to the population, the Discours-programme in November 1972, called for an end to foreign domination, which he blamed for the country’s woes. Kérékou promoted indigeneity, support- ing the teaching of indigenous languages through mass literacy programs and in universities (Igue and N’Oueni, 1994). While initially skeptical of both capitalism and so- cialism, which he regarded as foreign ideologies, Kérékou 64 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

embraced the latter and, in 1975, renamed Dahomey the People’s Republic of Benin. Although he had been promoted to major before stag- ing the coup, his rule ignored the top brass: the initial coterie of officers he invited to join his revolutionary gov- ernment were all under the age of forty (East and Thomas, 2003, 55). Despite his public commitment to socialism, Kérékou eschewed political equality, surrounding himself with his fellow northerners and marginalizing the Fon, Benin’s largest ethnic group, which is concentrated in the country’s south. Kérékou’s Parti de la Révolution Popu- laire du Bénin (People’s Revolutionary Party of Benin) dominated the parliamentary elections of 1979, 1984, and 1989 — perhaps unsurprisingly, as it was the only party allowed to compete. Kérékou was elected president in 1980, an event that portended not a return to democracy but rather a decade of personalist rule. Ghana Coup leader General Joseph Ankrah passed the torch to fellow General A. A. Afrifa, who then transferred power peacefully to an elected civilian government led by pro- fessor Kofi Busia, an internationally respected sociologist. Economic stress compelled Busia to cut pay to judges and soldiers, but he quickly learned how counterproductive it would be to challenge the economic security of the officer- corps. The military intervened again in 1972, in a coup led by General Ignatius Kutu Acheampong. Acheam- pong sought to institutionalize military rule in Ghana by providing officers a decisive political role and outlawing political parties. (This was dubbed a “no party” system in a “Unigov” constitution.) Acheampong’s reforms were hugely unpopular. He was also famously corrupt, as later audits showed 500 million pounds missing from the accounts of the Cocoa Marketing Board, and he had an alleged personal for- LAG IN DEMOCRACY 65

tune of $100 million (Young, 1982). General Frederick W. K. Akuffo led a counter-coup that promised national elections. Nearly all these officers — Ankrah, Afrifa, Acheampong, and Akuffo — were from the Ashanti eth- nic group, and most were graduates of the UK’s presti- gious military academy at Sandhurst.10 10 In 1972, an international Catholic news outlet wrote of Junior officers observed this rotation of Sandhurst- the “Sandhurst Way,” observ- educated Ashantis with disdain. In May 1979, a thirty- ing that “given the economic five-year old flight lieutenant, Jerry Rawlings, attempted problems facing the emergent nations of Africa, it is paradoxi- a coup but was caught and jailed. However, fellow junior cal that Sandhurst has provided officers sprung him and, on June 4, a second attempt to more rulers there than the Lon- don School of Economics” (The grab power succeeded. In power, Rawlings instigated the Tablet, 1972). assassination of Akuffo, Acheampong, and Afrifa. This was the kind of brutality championed by Machiavelli — celebrating Hannibal’s cruelty among “his other virtues” as a model for a ruler — in his advice to the Florentine prince. Rawlings was young, dynamic, and not from the “Akan cluster,” which included the Ashanti (with 44 percent of the population) and had dominated Ghanaian politics. Rawlings’s mother was Scottish and his father Ewe, a language community from the east that accounts for just over 10 percent of Ghana’s population. (Rawlings did marry an Ashanti, providing him a useful tie to powerful social networks.) After his coup, he called for immediate elections, and a career diplomat from the north of the country, Dr. Hilla Limann, was elected president. This lasted a mere two years before Rawlings returned to power through a coup on New Year’s Eve 1981, promising “noth- ing less than a revolution” for Ghana. His Provisional National Defense Council was not beholden to the mili- tary hierarchy that he helped decimate. After dominating the political scene in Ghana and providing a taste of polit- ical order, he instituted democratic elections and ran as a civilian, winning two successive elections as Ghana’s president. 66 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Rawlings was a mixed blessing for Ghana. Ultimately, he returned his country to a viable democracy. Yet, his twenty-two years of political dominance represented per- sonalist rule by junior officers turned popular leaders who permitted no meaningful political competition. 5 A Retrospective on Democratic Failure Democratic aspirations were quickly undermined in many independent African countries. Charismatic lead- ers turned into autocrats, purging opponents. Economic failure and fears of minority ethnic groups created social tensions in which intervention by the military initially ap- peared as a respite from chaos. Senior officers promised a return to democracy once order was restored. But Africa’s democratic deficit continued to grow in the first genera- tion of independence. Instead of democratically elected prime ministers, and instead of politically neutral senior officers restoring order, the archetypal regime became one led by a junior officer turned personalist leader, who relied on ethnic kin rather than broad-based parties. The fail- ure of young democracies to take root, while not unique to sub-Saharan Africa, has left it lagging most other re- gions in terms of political freedom and accountability (see figure 3.1 on page 53). 6 Corruption in the Prebendal State Consider the Nigerian cartoon “Nigeria at 49” in fig- ure 3.5. Its message is simple but powerful: governance failures are a shared quality of the country’s civil and military governments. As of 2018, Nigeria had an elected head of state from 1960 to 1966, 1979 to 1983, and 1999 to 2018; the remainder, unelected military rule. That is, twenty-seven of Nigeria’s fifty-eight years of indepen- dence have involved rule by elected leaders. But even when leaders have been elected, they have not been ac- LAG IN DEMOCRACY 67

Figure 3.5 “Nigeria at 49” Source: THISDAY Newspapers Limited.

countable; as the cartoon sardonically illustrates, theft and greed reign under either system of rule. While Nigeria has come to exemplify corruption (Smith, 2010), it is not unique among African states. The Worldwide Governance Indicators measure how effec- tively states control corruption, as well as whether they permit political voice and impartially enforce the law.11 11 The Worldwide Governance By all of these metrics, sub-Saharan states (on average) Indicators (WGI), an academic project developed by Daniel lagged all other regions when the data were first compiled Kaufmann and Aart Kraay, re- in 1996 (figure 3.6). Sadly, between 1996 and 2010, there ports aggregate and individual governance indicators for over is little indication that the region is closing this gap. two hundred countries and terri- To be sure, some countries are worse than others: in tories from 1996 to 2015. 2008, Botswana scored better than the average for all other regions. South Africa, Namibia, and Rwanda also scored reasonably well (as did smaller island nations, like Cape Verde, Mauritius, and Réunion). But most African states continue to struggle in their attempts to control corruption and remain toward the bottom in international rankings. 7 Systemic Corruption Political scientists have developed powerful descrip- tions of this endemic corruption. Rather than focus on specific scandals, they unpack the methods and motives of leaders who use corruption not only to profit, but also to maintain control. There have been several terms pro- posed for this systemic corruption; many Africanists refer 68 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Figure 3.6 Strong Average Governance Score in NA 1996

NA NA

1

ECA ECA ECA EAP EAP LAC 0 LAC EAP LAC & MENA Average WGI Score (1996) Average MENA SA SA SA SSA MENA SSA SSA Weak Corruption Voice Rule of Law

to it as “neopatrimonialism.” As described by van de Walle (2001, ch. 3), many African leaders at the mo- ment of independence found themselves at the helm of weak and insufficiently legitimate states. They had lit- tle choice but to rely on patronage and rents to assure their tenure against threats from a range of challengers. The result, van de Walle explains, was neopatrimonialism, combining a façade of rational-legal rule with the private appropriation of public resources by state elites. Here we review work describing this syndrome by three exemplary scholars, who help us understand the administrative systems (or lack thereof) that permit — or even facilitate — the defrauding of state revenues. These accounts suggest that the bureaucracies with whom diplo- mats, donors, and scholars regularly interact have been hollowed out by rulers who fear, rather than reward, com- petent administrators. What results are blocks of min- istries in capital cities like Monrovia or Kinshasa that LAG IN DEMOCRACY 69

might be better described as Potemkin villages than cen- ters of authority. Prebendalism According to the seminal sociological work of Max Weber (Weber, Gerth, and Mills, 1946, 207), “prebends” are payments for the conferred right to the rents from land or other sources in return for “the fulfillment of actual or fictitious office duties; they are goods permanently set aside for the economic assurance of the office.” Tax farming is a quintessential prebend. In early modern times, a lord conferred on subordinates the right to tax, so long as they returned an agreed-upon amount to the lord. Tax farmers, if they demonstrated loyalty to the lord, could pass their right to tax on to their descendants. In many developing countries today, directing a cus- toms house in a port is an obvious prebend. Traffic police in the Democratic Republic of the Congo are also ex- emplary. An ongoing study in the capital of Kinshasa measures the extortion capabilities of traffic policemen at key intersections (Sanchez de la Sierra and Titeca, in progress). Following the money, the authors compute how much of each bribe goes to the policemen and their superi- ors. They find that officers who refuse to extort motorists or don’t send the expected payments up the chain get reassigned to less profitable intersections. While readers may not be surprised to learn that police can extort bribes, directors of hospitals or educational establishments have similar opportunities to tax (or, better, extort) clients for admittance or services. One of Richard Joseph’s (1987) contributions is to identify the many opportunities for prebendalism in the dispensation of licenses, letters of 12 credit, and other forms of bureaucratic access. These relationships are some- times described as “clientelis- How are these prebends allocated? In many African tic.” Leaders (patrons) dis- pense benefits to subordinates states, political leaders (our contemporary “lords”) and (clients) in return for political their subordinates tend to share a common ethnicity.12 support. 70 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Like any boss, leaders need to monitor and occasionally prod their underlings. This is easier done when both parties share a common language and social network. What Joseph’s work demonstrates is that corruption is not an unexpected or deviant behavior; rather, preben- dalism is a governing strategy.13 State power is used 13 Writing more recently, to establish a private market for public goods (e.g., safe Joseph (2013) notes that eliminating prebendalism is roads or emergency medical services). This benefits lead- difficult precisely because ers in two ways: first, leaders share in whatever revenues citizens in states like Nigeria, Kenya, and Uganda expect the prebend collects; second, leaders assure the electoral their leaders to use political loyalty of prebend holders, who want to retain their lucra- office to benefit supporters. tive positions. Politicians can actually be punished at the polls for failing The Shadow State to engage in corruption. Prebendalism depends on state power; if the importers simply disregard the customs officer, then the value of controlling the port diminishes. Yet, William Reno argues that leaders who take of- fice with a tenuous grasp on power do not want to build powerful states:

An actuarial calculation showed that as of 1991 the 485 postcolonial African rulers faced a 59.4 percent chance of dying, being imprisoned, or being exiled as a con- sequence of holding office. Rulers of weak states risk having strongmen appropriate bureaucracies that are ef- fective at accumulating resources. . . . Rulers who face threatening internal behavior intentionally cripple the arms of the state. (Reno, 1999, 19; emphasis added)

Several sub-Saharan states are, as a result, evanescent and unable to maintain a monopoly on legitimate violence, the defining characteristic of modern states, according to Weber. Always fearing their imminent demise, Reno’s “warlord politicians” — such as Doe and Taylor in Liberia, Mobutu in Congo, Momoh in Sierra Leone, Dos Santos in Angola — do not allocate prebends to officials, who might later become rivals. Rather, these leaders create a “shadow LAG IN DEMOCRACY 71

state” that relies on foreign corporations and governments to supply revenues in exchange for access to natural re- sources or, in Liberia’s case, a dollar-denominated bank- ing system that facilitates money laundering.14 To guard 14 Reno (1999) notes that (obliv- against insurgents without risking a coup, these rulers ious) international donors were all too happy to see state bu- do not build a cohesive officer-corps, but instead depend reaucracies contract, as they re- on (many of whom are South African ex- garded these ministries as hope- lessly corrupt. military, who found gainful employment post-apartheid providing private security to mining companies and heads of state) (Reno, 1999, 63). Reno’s cases illustrate how traditional state functions are farmed out to private, often foreign, firms (see table 3.1 Table 3.1 for estimates of the size of shadow economies). Consider The Shadow Economy Average % GDP the role of the Firestone Tire and Rubber Company in Region (1999-2007) Liberia, which established its Liberian concession in 1926 SSA 42 when it leased a million acres for ninety-nine years for LAC 41.7 just over a nickel per acre (Reno, 1999, 84). Successive SA 34.5 rulers in Liberia were only too happy to allow Firestone ECA 30.5 EAP 27.5 to take on roles typically reserved to the state: Samuel MENA 27 Doe and previous presidents “had brought in foreign firms NA 12.5 Shadow Economy and aid organizations. . . to fill in for missing bureaucratic Cases capacity and a local revenue base. . . . [Firestone] had long (2000) assessed and collected taxes, provided housing for em- D.R. Congo 48 Sierra Leone 40.2 ployees, managed local chiefs, and enforced local laws.” Liberia 43.2 As Doe’s eventual successor, Charles Taylor, attempted Source: Dreher and to seize power in a brutal civil war, he deployed Fire- Schneider, 2009 stone’s communications technology (e.g., their satellite phones) to plan attacks on international ECOMOG forces in the capital — another instance of private infrastructure serving elites’ needs (100). In Zaire (today’s Democratic Republic of the Congo), private businessmen paid the army’s salaries to protect their businesses; those who did not pay were attacked (Reno, 1995, 19). In other words, the army was not a national army (protection by the state in return for taxes) but rather a private enterprise running a protection racket. 72 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Why did Mobutu refuse to pay his soldiers from state coffers? “He could use his security forces to disorganize rivals, but that risked bolstering military units that could remove him in his weakened state” (Reno, 1999, 158). Mobutu preferred an unruly and fractious military that, while offering little protection, also posed no real threat to his incumbency. It may not be surprising that shadow states offered little to citizens in the form of public services. Where rulers receive revenues and security from foreign sources, they often see no need to serve domestic constituencies. In 1990 Mobutu allocated just 2.1 percent of government spending to health and education; compare that to 17.5 percent in 1972. As export revenues contracted, he “safely abandoned expensive health care facilities, schools, and public works — all of which served citizens but con- tributed little to his stock of political resources” (Reno, 1999, 153). The Political Marketplace Alex de Waal has been an analyst of, and participant in, several peacemaking operations in the Horn of Africa (a region that includes Djibouti, Eritrea, Ethiopia, and Somalia) and neighboring Sudan. To set up his most re- cent book (de Waal, 2015), he reports on the machinations of Abdel Wahid, the representative of Darfur in negoti- ations with the Sudanese state. Parties to the genocide then in progress were negotiating a settlement in Abuja, Nigeria’s capital. Wahid did not devote his attention to negotiating with the mediators or with the perpetrators of the genocide. Rather, he spent his time on a mobile phone with leaders of factions in Darfur determining how much cash they would need to not defect from any deal Wahid might sign. De Waal infers from this story (and many others) that human allegiance can be rented, and African LAG IN DEMOCRACY 73

leaders (whether of countries or rebel movements) need a “political budget” to pay that rent. While the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank may pay attention to the public budget, that’s not as consequential as the “political budget,” the funds available to rulers for discretionary spending to retain political support. This pot is garnered from state rents, funds provided by businesses, and loyalty payments from foreign sponsors. The political budget is the fuel of what de Waal calls “the political marketplace system,” and its supply is a key indicator of regime survival or crisis. Maximizing the political budget, that is, sustaining cash flow and ensuring that claimants are paid, at mini- mum cost, is the route to continued rule. There are several rules for success. First, leaders (or political business man- agers [PBMs], in de Waal’s terms) seek to reduce the costs of coercion by building up ties of ethnicity, national- ism, or religion. The more PBMs succeed in building an ethnic base, the more they can save to spend on renting loyalty from non-coethnics. Second, leaders can provide tax breaks for transnational corporations (on crude oil ex- ports or on their acquisition of land) in return for regular deposits in the PBM’s account in a tax haven. The PBM can then “round trip” those funds into his political budget back home. Cash flow rather than public service is the coin of the realm. But African PBMs face challenges, especially from the entrepreneurs of peripheral rebellions. De Waal sees these rebellions as “rent seeking” in that their leaders attempt to stage mutinies or rebellions in order to advertise their intent and determination. To the extent that any rebel leader mobilizes militias that can cause damage and death, he will be able to induce a round of bargaining, done through both violent escapades and peace talks. If quite successful, according to de Waal, the rebel leader could induce the United Nations Security Council to establish a 74 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

peace-keeping operation (PKO). The goal of the rebel is to win a “payroll peace,” where he is given a promotion and his fighters are put on the army payroll, with arrears. The result of this continued quest for an adequate “po- litical budget” is a syndrome de Waal calls “turbulence.” And we saw this turbulence reflected in the coups and counter-coups where founders were toppled by generals and junior officers. Figure 3.2(a) shows that the first half- century of independence involved over 150 coup attempts. Yet, keen observers will note that these coups, peripheral rebellions, alliance shifts, and tentative peace pacts, while dizzying, have not altered the status quo. As de Waal notes, while every day may seem different for those ob- serving the corridors of power, those who return to the presidential palace after a hiatus of several years will note that everything looks precisely the same (de Waal, 2015, 17). The only differences are the names of the PBMs and perhaps the increasing costs to rent loyalty. 8 The Costs of Prebendalism Prebendalism, shadow states, and the turbulent politi- cal marketplace are three characterizations of the failure of many postcolonial African countries to build modern bureaucratic states based on public law and funded with public budgets. The syndromes were delineated through what might be thought of as clinical observations, but the implications of these syndromes for the health of the body politic remain to be shown. In this section, we examine the systematic failures of African states in the fair distribution of pub- lic goods, in the sharing of power across ethnic groups, in election administration, and in the accountability of elected representatives to their constituents. LAG IN DEMOCRACY 75

Public Goods Prebendalism predicts systematic bias in the distribu- tion of state benefits. What are called “public goods” in theory (i.e., available to all; excludable to none) are in practice biased toward those favored by the country’s leader. Evidence of such a bias has been hard to come by. An important paper by Kasara (2007), in fact, reveals the op- posite. She finds that the taxes are higher on agricultural products from the leader’s region, and when a new leader comes from a different region, the higher (on average) tax burden moves to the region of the now-current leader. Similarly, Kudamatsu (2007) reports that changes in the ethnicity of the Guinean leader had no effects on levels of infant mortality among various ethnic groups. In a follow-up paper, Kramon and Posner (2013) show that the degree of ethnic favoritism for public goods depends in good part on the country and the type of public good (education, water, electricity, and infant survival). Edu- cation in Kenya and Malawi, electricity in Zambia and Senegal, water in Zambia, and infant survival in Benin all show significant payoffs for populations who share an ethnicity with the current president. But education in Senegal and Mali, electricity in Mali, and infant survival in Senegal show significant advantages to non-coethnics of the president. In the four types of public goods in six countries, eleven of the cases (out of twenty-four) show no ethnic advantage. Yet, other recent work provides more compelling (and distressing) evidence of ethnic bias in the distribution of public goods. Franck and Rainer (2012) study the demo- graphic and health surveys conducted in eighteen African countries over the past fifty years. Combined, these sur- veys amount to more than a million African respondents. Each respondent was assigned an ethnic cluster, and for 76 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

the year of the survey, it was noted whether the president of the country was from the same ethnic cluster. This allowed the researchers to compare improvements among coethnics of the president to changes observed among other groups in the same state — a research design com- monly referred to as a difference-in-difference.15 The 15 This research design exploits authors find that coethnics are more likely to receive and over time changes within the same ethnic group, comparing, complete primary education and have lower rates of infant for example, (1) the change mortality. This is the strongest evidence we have of ethnic in infant mortality among the Temne in Sierra Leone before bias in the dispensing of public goods in Africa. and after their coethnic Koroma assumed power in 2007 to (2) Ethnic Power Sharing the change in infant mortality In allocating cabinet positions, political business man- among other groups in Sierra Leone. This analysis accounts agers need to build a robust coalition without running a for any static differences be- deficit on their political budget. To that end, they often tween groups (e.g., geographic or climactic features of northern need to incorporate some non-coethnic ministers (espe- Sierra Leone that affect Temne cially when their own group is relatively small) to ensure health outcomes) that might oth- that their minimum winning coalition (i.e., the cheapest erwise confound our ability to isolate the effects of coethnic- team capable of retaining power) does not face an insur- ity. gent challenge. Testing this notion, Cederman, Wimmer, and Min (2010) embark on an ambitious data collection effort, coding for every ethnic group, in every year, whether they were included in the ruling coalition (and, if so, as Table 3.2 Ethnic Power Relations in a junior or senior partner). Those out of the inner circle Africa, 1960-1990 are classified as excluded, powerless, or facing discrim- Status Freq. % ination. Their “Ethnic Power Relations” data set has Monopoly 117 2 nearly 30,000 observations, an observation for every eth- Dominant 253 5 nic group in every year. The authors’ analysis reveals that Senior Partner 722 14 Junior Partner 1,563 30 the constraints on the political budget are substantial: over Separatist half of the groups are classified as excluded from power Autonomy 6 <1 Regional in an average year (table 3.2). And the consequences are Autonomy 89 2 equally powerful: excluded groups are more than twice Irrelevant 426 8 as likely in any given year (5.1 percent vs. 2.3 percent) Discriminated 697 13 Powerless 1,304 25 to initiate a violent conflict against the state. The prob- Unit of observation: ability that groups initiate violent conflicts goes down group-year. LAG IN DEMOCRACY 77

substantially with income, perhaps suggesting that PBMs in richer states have more ample political budgets to dis- tribute to prevent defection. In many African states, it appears that meager political budgets compel leaders to exclude non-coethnics, despite the violent repercussions (table 3.3).

Status Pr(Onset) Pr(Ethnic Onset) N Table 3.3 Ethnic Power Sharing and Civil 1 Excluded Group 0.051 0.034 682 War in African States, No Excluded Groups 0.023 0.007 433 1960-1990 Unit of observation: country-year.

Electoral Misconduct As was apparent in the first figure in this chapter (3.1), most sub-Saharan countries failed to introduce meaning- ful political competition in the first few decades of self- rule. Most elections were in one-party states. When elections were held, fraud served only to amplify the in- evitable victory of the incumbent party. But with the return of real electoral contests in many African states (to be more fully evaluated in part IV), some political business managers have turned their at- tention to buying votes. The National Elections across Democracy and Autocracy (NELDA) data set provides in- formation on every executive election between 1960 and 1990, including whether they were expected to be “free and fair,” whether the opposition was harassed, whether the media was biased in the incumbent’s favor, or whether riots occurred (Hyde and Marinov, 2012). Figure 3.7 in- dicates that, across three of these four variables, Africa lagged most regions in the first three decades after inde- pendence. (The likelihood of riots is actually higher in South and East Asia.) This figure does mask some variation within Africa. According to Afrobarometer surveys, most citizens in 78 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

0.75 Figure 3.7 MENA SSA Electoral Quality, 1960-1990

EAP

0.50 SA EAP EAP LAC SSA MENA

SSA LAC 0.25 EAP

LAC LAC

Probability for Executive Elections (1960 − 1990) Probability for Executive SSA 0.00

Pr(Not Free/Fair) Pr(Harass) Pr(Media Bias) Pr(Riots)

Botswana agree that their elections are “free and fair”; yet respondents in Nigeria, Kenya, and Zimbabwe are cog- nizant of systematic fraud (Collier and Vicente, 2011).16 16 According to its website, Other questions from Afrobarometer indicate that vot- “Afrobarometer is a pan- African, non-partisan research ers in these countries express concern about vote buying, network that conducts public party-induced violence, and fraud. Even in Ghana, which attitude surveys on democ- racy, governance, economic has been a success story for democratic consolidation conditions, and related issues post-Rawlings, voters report a concern for the violence in more than 35 countries in that occurs around elections. In 2017, Kenyan courts Africa.” invalidated the presidential tally due to allegations of cor- ruption. If African states are to become full democracies (and escape the middling range of anocratic states), they must ensure that elections permit free expression and political turnover. Political Accountability In democracies, one commonly proposed solution for rooting out corruption is transparency. If voters know LAG IN DEMOCRACY 79

which politicians are stealing from the public purse, they can punish these bad actors at the polls. In an ingenious experiment conducted in Uganda, Members of Parliament were evaluated using report cards (Humphreys and Weinstein, 2012). These report cards (see figure 3.8 for an example) were disseminated to civil society groups and to voters in a way that would allow the researchers to gauge their impact on electoral out- comes. These report cards included evaluations of MPs’ attendance at plenary sessions, participation in committee work, and in provision of constituency service. Provided with an objective assessment of MPs’ efforts to serve the national electorate and their own constituents, researchers expected that voters would punish officials shown to be shirking their duties.

Figure 3.8 Ugandan MP’s Scorecard (Humphreys and Weinstein, 2012) 80 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Yet, while Humphreys and Weinstein (2012) find that harder-working MPs are more likely to be reelected, they do not find that providing the report cards changed voting behavior. To infer this, they examined constituency scores and grades (e.g., Mr. Mutabaali received a score of 57 and a letter grade of C) for each MP. They then looked at the numerical cutoff, say from a letter grade of B and C at 65. From this setup, they could compare sets of candidates who had different letter grades but virtually similar scores (say 64 getting a C and 66 getting a B). They found no difference in reelection chances between these high C and low B candidates. In some instances, it appears that candidates with lower grades were more successful in the next election — for example, candidates with low to middling A grades had a lower probability of reelection than candidates receiving high C or B grades. Sadly, this experiment suggests that voters do not re- ward candidates for performance, providing little incen- tive for elected officials to serve their constituents’ inter- ests. Indeed, this lack of accountability if anything helps sustain corruption (i.e., the provision of private goods to ethnic kin) and the failure to provide public goods. The Prebendal or Shadow State and Its Implications Formal African states — the ones with constitutions, legislatures, ministries, and UN seats — are not the prin- cipal projectors of authority over their populations. Those who have observed the real projection of power see in- stead informal arrangements that grant prebends to influ- ential regime supporters, that rent loyalty from potential insurgents, and that govern in the shadows of formal insti- tutions. While these governance failures are apparent in corruption measures, they also have consequences for cit- izens’ welfare: public goods are either sold to the highest bidder or distributed to coethnics, electoral competition is limited, and accountability is minimal. Corruption has LAG IN DEMOCRACY 81

become so rife in many African countries, it is now sus- tained by expectations that someone who assumes power will use that power to reward friends and family. Even if it is not their intention to enrich their kin with the spoils of office, officials find themselves bombarded with requests to help relatives secure access to schools or jobs, and will be scorned by their ethnic kin should they demur (Smith, 2010). We see again the lag in Africa, here in the pro- vision of honest government to its citizens, blurring the grand visions of the independence era. 9 Conclusion The transition to democracy and the rule of law in Africa, so optimistically envisioned in the late 1950s, was quickly subverted by corruption, ethnic favoritism, budget allocations to purchase political support, the banning of opposition parties, and ultimately the collapse of civilian rule in nearly half of Africa’s independent states. The modern state apparatus was visible in the United Nations General Assembly, where African ambassadors voted for the interests of their state and the continent. But, back home, all too many citizens were being ruled by “shadow states” that engaged in extortion and the limited and se- lective allocation of state benefits. The democratic deficit is an essential feature of Africa’s unfulfilled promise, and accounting for this deficit (and that of social disorder and economic stagnation) is a principal concern of parts II and III of this book.

4. Lag in Social Order

THE FUNDAMENTAL POLITICAL BARGAIN between state and citizen, going back at least to Thomas Hobbes’s Leviathan, revolves around the provision of public order: citizens cede authority to a government, which provides security in return. Some of the coup plotters we met in the previous chapter pointed to a breakdown of this funda- mental bargain, justifying their revolutions as necessary to escape the chaos of civilian rule. Yet, despite the con- centration of power in a new generation of authoritarian leaders, these rulers failed to hold up their side of the bargain. Callaghy (1987) dubs them “lame leviathans” — leaders with the power to intimidate their people, but not the power to protect them. The failure to consistently provide physical security to citizens is another dimension along which states in post-independence Africa did not fulfill their promise. This chapter first illustrates the failure of African states to provide order. It then explores the variety of violent conflicts — communal conflicts fought in rural areas, ur- ban riots, coups, and insurgencies seeking to overthrow established governments — that demonstrate the limited capacity of post-independence states to provide security to their populations. While these different types of con- flict are often studied separately, we summarize research which suggests that civil wars and coups both emerge from the same political logic — rulers facing a zero-sum 84 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

trade-off between protecting against threats from inside the palace or in the periphery (Roessler, 2016). Before concluding, and presaging a fuller discussion in part IV, we consider the implications of civil war (versus interna- tional wars) for state-building. While the number of violent conflicts in sub-Saharan African states remains disturbingly high, some observers incorrectly portray the region as a cacophony of violence, with tribe fighting tribe in endless conflicts over identity and (political) status. But, as Fearon and Laitin (1996) observe, this view is radically mistaken. If you consider every neighboring ethnic group in Africa, the probability of a violent conflict between any two in a given year is tantamount to zero. When reporting on ethnic conflict, the press rarely acknowledges just how rare violent outbreaks are given the many zones where ethnic groups meet.1 1 This is an example of a more Although African states have struggled more to contain general mistake: failing to con- sider the denominator. To com- conflict than some other regions, our discussion does not pute the probability of an event imply that violence is ubiquitous. Nonetheless, many occurring (e.g., a conflict or an illness), we need to know how citizens in sub-Saharan countries remain insecure, and many times it could have hap- this chapter reveals the breadth and devastating human pened, even if it never did. consequences of their states’ failures to provide social order. 1 African State Failures to Provide Table 4.1 Failed State Index by Region Basic Security Region FSI (2010) Failed states cannot provide basic order. The Fund for SA 93 Peace constructs a Fragile States Index, which assesses SSA 88 MENA 75 each state’s risk of failure. The index consists of twelve LAC 70 indicators (e.g., deterioration of public services, popula- EAP 70 ECA 53 tion displacement, widespread human rights violations), NA 32 each ranked from 0 to 10. The maximum score is then Country FSI (2010) 120, and Somalia once attained a score of 114.9. The (Rank) average index value for sub-Saharan states in 2010 is just Somalia (1) 114.3 under 90 (see table 4.1), outpacing all but South Asia in Chad (2) 113.3 Sudan (3) 111.8 the likelihood of state failure. Three African states topped LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 85

the index in 2010: Somalia, Chad, and Sudan. In Robert Rotberg’s (2002) accounting of states that have actually failed, seven out of eight were in sub-Saharan Africa. As we see in figure 4.1, these fragile states have fre- quently failed: in the 1990s, nearly 7 percent of cases (i.e., 32 of 480 country-years) in Africa were considered failed states according to the Polity data set. While the Fund for Peace may rank South Asian states as more prone to collapse, sub-Saharan Africa saw the highest rates of state failure in the 1990s. Interestingly, when it comes to armed conflict, Africa’s report card is not significantly worse than in parts of Asia or North Africa. These regions have all seen high and sustained levels of internal conflict since the 1970s (see figure 4.2 for annual counts of civil and interstate wars). (Note that with only eight countries in the South Asia region, conflict in any one state pushes the rate up by 12.5 percent; conflict in one of sub-Saharan Africa’s forty- eight states increases the regional rate by only 2 percent.) Although sub-Saharan states do not stand out on this in-

SSA SA 6%

MENA

4% SA

EAP MENA

EAP

% Failed State − Years % Failed 2% LAC SSA

ECA LAC MENA SSALAC Figure 4.1 0% SSA● ● ● ● Percentage of Failed 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s State-Years by Region and Decade (Polity) 86 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

EAP ECA LAC

10

5

0

MENA SA SSA

10 States Experiencing Conflict 5

0 1965 1980 1995 1965 1980 1995 1965 1980 1995

Conflict Type Interstate Intrastate

Figure 4.2 Trends in Armed Conflict by Region, 1960-1999 (UCDP) dicator, their performance is hardly reassuring: between 1960 and 2010, thirty-two different sub-Saharan countries experienced at least one internal or interstate conflict ac- cording to the Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP), which defines an armed conflict as “a contested incompat- ibility which concerns government and/or territory where the use of armed force between two parties, of which at least one is the government of a state, results in at least 25 battle-related deaths.” Table 4.2 Probability of Civil War Onset, And these are not minor episodes of violence. Fearon 1960-1999 and Laitin (2003) use a threshold of 1,000 killed to iden- Region Pr(Onset) tify civil wars. Using their data, we find that the prob- SA 0.047 ability of a civil war starting in any given country and SSA 0.022 MENA 0.016 year is over 2 percent in both sub-Saharan states and EAP 0.014 South Asia — nearly twice the rate in other regions (ta- ECA 0.011 ble 4.2). These conflicts exact a considerable toll: newly LAC 0.010 NA 0.000 compiled data from Fearon and Laitin implies that over LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 87

six million people died in African civil wars in the four decades following independence. Worse, these deaths are mostly noncombatants associated with collateral damage, refugee starvation and disease, and gratuitous violence against civilians by undisciplined troops. Readers may think it unfair to compare newly indepen- dent African states to long established countries. To be sure, African countries struggled to maintain order in their first years of self-rule. This was equally true in the states that emerged from the former Soviet Union and in North Africa. However, civil conflict in Africa peaked in the late 1980s and early 1990s, three decades after independence. This suggests that order does not inevitably emerge as independence struggles fade from view. The conflict data reveal that states throughout the de- veloping world have struggled to fulfill their most basic function — namely, to provide security to their popula- tions. While sub-Saharan Africa is not anomalous in this regard, its absolute performance has been lackluster. We now review different types of conflicts, ranging from low- level communal fights to open rebellions against the state, that generate instability in different sub-Saharan states. 2 Low-Level and Communal Conflicts Many conflicts do not reach the scale of civil wars. Between 1960 and 2014, there were twenty-five “minor” armed conflicts in sub-Saharan Africa — that is, conflicts that claim at least twenty-five battle deaths every year but fewer than 1,000 deaths across the entire conflict. The best available estimates (from the Uppsala Conflict Data Program) suggest that this violence resulted in the deaths of just over 6,200 combatants (table 4.3), the most of any region. Less than thirty minor armed conflicts may seem like a small number. However, each conflict involves a number of pitched battles or violent acts against civilians. (More- 88 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Minor Total Average Table 4.3 Region Conflicts Deaths Duration Low-Level Conflicts by Region, 1960-2014 SSA 25 6,279 3.7 ECA 17 5,325 3.0 EAP 14 2,632 4.1 LAC 11 3,800 7.0 SA 10 2,985 2.4 MENA 4 1,485 8.8 over, many episodes of political violence do not result in twenty-five combatant deaths per year and, thus, are excluded from this count.) The Armed Conflict Loca- tion and Event Data (ACLED) tracks individual violent events in Africa since 1997 regardless of the death toll. By ACLED’s count, between 1997 and 2015, there were nearly 33,000 battles and over 31,000 acts of violence against civilians in sub-Saharan Africa. While a majority of these events involved no fatalities, their collective toll is striking (dominated by the massive death count in what has come to be called Africa’s Great War in the Demo- cratic Republic of the Congo): over 590,000 killed.2 2 ACLED defines a conflict as “a single altercation where of- These low-level violent events include many distinct ten force is used by one or actors and motivations: terrorist acts, small insurgent more groups for a political groups, abusive army platoons, and violent cattle-rustlers. end, although some instances — including protests and non- Yet, scholars have identified classes of conflicts with com- violent activity — are included mon motivations. We briefly summarize descriptive re- to capture potential pre-cursors or critical junctures of a conflict” search on three common types of low-level conflict: land- (Raleigh, Linke, and Dowd, related conflicts, electoral violence, and Salafist attacks. 2014). Conflicts Between Herders and Farmers The war in Darfur started in the early 2000s in western Sudan. While precise figure are elusive, many estimates place the death toll from fighting, disease, and starvation in the hundreds of thousands and the number of inter- nally displaced people in the millions (Minority Rights Group International 2015). This war is often understood LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 89

as an ethnic conflict that pitted a marginalized non-Arab population against the politically dominant Arabs who controlled the Sudanese state. Yet, this intense interethnic violence can be traced to a long-standing economic conflict between camel and cattle herders, who were predominantly Arab, and farmers, who were more often “African” (Faris, 2007).3 Droughts and 3 DeWaal (2004) argues that the desertification in Africa’s semiarid region (between ethnic cleavage between Arabs and Africans is a relatively re- the Saharan and the southern savannas) forced cent construction: “In fact there nomadic herders to migrate further south in search of are no discernible racial or reli- gious differences between [Dar- water and pasture. Migrating camels and cattle often furian Arabs and Africans]: all trampled the crops of farmers in central and southern Dar- have lived there for centuries; fur (Lefkow, 2004); severe droughts in the 1980s even all are Muslims (Darfur’s non- Arabs are arguably more devout prompted nomads to establish semipermanent settlements than the Arabs); and until very in Darfur’s southern regions. recently, conflict between these different groups was a matter Historically, southern farmers tolerated herders: Faris of disputes over camel theft or writes, “the nomads were welcome passers-through, graz- grazing rights, not the system- atic and ideological slaughter of ing their camels on the rocky hillsides that separated the one group by the other.” fertile plots. The farmers would share their wells, and the herders would feed their stock on the leavings from the harvest.” Yet, as productive land became scarce, farm- ers started to obstruct nomads by erecting fences and burning grasses (de Waal, 2004). This competition for resources boiled over into conflict, with episodes becom- ing increasingly violent in the late 1980s after an infusion of automatic weapons and with the breakdown of inter- communal tribal conferences that had previously resolved disputes. The central government failed to fill the vacuum left by the cessation of tribal conferences; worse still, politicians in Khartoum frequently provided support to Arabs in these conflicts in order to gain favor in factional battles among the ruling elites (Roessler, 2016). This fa- voritism marginalized the African populations that would later contest the government’s authority. Violence between herders and farmers is not new or unique to Sudan; rather, it is a recurring phenomenon 90 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

in the Sahel. Studies have documented violent conflicts between herders and farmers dating back to the seven- teenth century and ranging geographically from Turkana, Kenya, to Mali, to Senegal (Hussein, Sumberg, and Sed- don, 1999). According to Boone (2014), these conflicts between herders and farmers are merely a subset of land-related disputes. She argues that increased demand for arable land, due to rising population density or foreign in- vestment, has increased the frequency of land conflicts. Poorly defined customary property rights allow chiefs in some countries to sell customary land out from under their constituents, engendering a violent backlash. Electoral Violence In his review of conflict trends in Africa, Straus (2012) argues that the declining frequency of large-scale con- flicts raises the salience of both land-related conflicts and electoral violence in Africa. According to the African Electoral Violence Database compiled by Straus and Tay- lor, roughly 20 percent of elections in sub-Saharan Africa between 1990 and 2008 were marred by high levels of electoral violence (i.e., targeted assassinations or more than ten related deaths); another 40 percent involved ha- rassment. Most often, it is the incumbent that perpe- trates this violence. Between 1990 and 2010, elections in Côte d’Ivoire (2000), Kenya (1992, 2007), Nigeria (2007), South Africa (1994), Togo (2005), and Zimbabwe (2008) led in each country to over one hundred deaths (Salehyan and Linebarger, 2013). While there is no evidence of a sustained upward trend in electoral violence, recent con- tests do not suggest that this conflict is abating: eleven of seventeen elections in 2011 involved some form of vio- lence, and conflict following the presidential elections in Côte d’Ivoire killed approximately 3,000 (Bekoe, 2012). Kenya’s 2007 election is an extreme instance of elec- LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 91

toral violence in a restored democracy: roughly 350,000 citizens were displaced and over 1,000 killed in the violent repurcussions that followed the presidential contest. A peaceful campaign just five years earlier that was largely deemed free and fair by international observers presaged broad acceptance of the 2007 electoral process. However, the eruption of violence following the announcement of the results took many by surprise. On December 30, Kenya’s Electoral Commission de- clared that the incumbent, Mwai Kibaki, had beaten Raila Odinga by over 200,000 votes. This official result ran counter to pre-election surveys and partial tallies from December 28 and 29, which had Odinga leading. More- over, Odinga’s party won ninety-nine parliamentary seats (relative to the forty-three won by Kibaki’s party). For the presidential and parliamentary results to diverge so sharply, many Kenyans would have to have voted split tickets — a behavior that voters rarely reported in post- election surveys (Dercon and Gutiérrez-Romero, 2012). International observers echoed Odinga’s concerns, ques- tioning the credibility of the vote tallies. In the hours after the results were announced, Odinga supporters reacted violently; conflict was reported in five of Kenya’s eight provinces and targeted Kibaki’s Kikuyu coethnics. This one-sided violence quickly gave way to re- venge attacks, with criminal gangs targeting Odinga’s sup- porters in Kenya’s central Rift Valley — a region that ex- perienced over half of all reported deaths. Uhuru Kenyatta and William Ruto (then adversaries; they would later be elected Kenya’s president and deputy president in 2013) were both charged with crimes against humanity for their alleged roles on opposing sides of the conflict; charges against Kenyatta were dropped in December 2014. Two months after the election, on February 28, a power-sharing arrangement (brokered by the late UN secretary-general 92 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Kofi Annan) was announced that installed Odinga in the newly created office of prime minister. This violence not only imposed a heavy human cost, but also crippled the Kenyan economy: tea and flower exports plummeted, tourism dried up, and manufacturing was reduced by roughly a third in January 2008. This episode of electoral violence helps illustrate both an im- portant class of low-level conflict as well as the reinforc- ing qualities of Africa’s lag: manipulated elections incite widespread violence, which in turn hampers economic development. Salafist Attacks Islamic fundamentalist movements originating in the Middle East have spread to Africa, and African states have not had the capacity to cauterize the bloodshed and de- struction caused by these groups. In sub-Saharan Africa, these attacks have hit Burkina Faso, Côte d’Ivoire, Mali, Niger, Somalia, Kenya, and especially Nigeria. In the Sa- hel, the United States Africa Command has been working closely with local armies and regional organizations to isolate and degrade these threats. In October 2017 one of its patrols was ambushed in Niger, near the Malian bor- der, by jihadists associated with al-Qaida in the Islamic Maghreb. Several Green Berets were murdered. Here we look at a homegrown Salafist insurgency in Nigeria, but also active in Chad, Niger, and northern Cameroon, called Boko Haram (in Hausa, “Western education is for- bidden”). Boko Haram, like other Salafi organizations, adheres to a literal interpretation of Islamic texts. The group, how- ever, represents a violent fringe within Northern Nigeria’s Salafi community that seeks to install a pure Islamic so- ciety in Nigeria and neighboring states. It has aligned its views with groups outside the region, denouncing Western governments and professing a right to violently impose LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 93

their strict interpretation of Islamic law (Thurston, 2016, 9). According to Thurston (2016), Boko Haram emerged from competition among Salafist groups in Northern Nige- ria. With Nigeria’s return to democracy in 1999, there was a debate in the North about the proper role of in politics. Boko Haram staked out one extreme in this ideo- logical conflict, arguing that Northern states’ codes fell short and, thus, failed to safeguard public morality from western influences and rapid social changes (10).4 4 This origin story departs from several common — but, Since its founding in 2002, Boko Haram has killed Thurston argues, misleading — 15,000, abducted innocent schoolchildren, and displaced narratives about the group’s millions from their homes. President Goodluck Jonathan, rise: poverty (which is rampant throughout Nigeria); political even after declaring a state of emergency in 2002, failed in marginalization (Boko Haram his attempts to contain the group with military action and emerged and continues to oper- ate under a Northern president); technical support from Western powers. His own military or simply the diffusion of al- failing him, President Jonathan lent state support to civil- Qaida (an organization that the ian vigilantes (the Civilian Joint Task Force, C-JTF), who Boko Haram rarely referenced at its founding) (7). have used this power to also abuse innocent Muslims with- out fear of punishment.5 With the public disgusted over 5 Abuses by the state and its al- the failure to eliminate this curse, Jonathan lost reelection lies are documented in Amnesty International, (2015). against former president and army general Mohammed Buhari, who promised to wipe out the Salafist insurgency. However, in the early months of Buhari’s term, Boko Haram continued to cause havoc in northeastern Nigeria, using horrific tactics, such as deploying young girls as suicide bombers to mosques. The African Union and the United States Africa Command are working with Nige- rian authorities to eliminate this terrible plague, but again, a weak state has been unable to protect the security of millions of vulnerable Nigerian citizens. 3 Civil Wars in Post-Independence Africa Large-scale wars fought between insurgent militias and the state are alarmingly high. We classify those that reach a death toll of at least 1,000 as civil wars. Between 1960 94 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

and 2010, there have been forty-three civil wars in Africa with an estimated 6.64 million killed (figure 4.3). These include both combatants (on both sides of the conflict) and the large number of civilians who died while being in harm’s way, or from disease and as refugees were escaping from the violence.

SSA Figure 4.3 6 Cumulative Deaths from Civil Wars

Rest of 4 World

2 Cumulative Civil War Deaths (Millions) Civil War Cumulative

0 1960 1970 1980 1990 1999

Although onsets of civil war in Africa have been rela- tively constant over the decades, the nature of these wars has changed. As Reno (2011) illustrates, while past con- flicts focused on liberation, more recent civil wars emerge from competition among warlords over the rents from office. Anticolonial Wars During the early European occupation of sub-Saharan Africa, indigenous groups fought against colonial en- croachment. The Ashanti (in today’s Ghana) fought con- tinuously against British occupation in the nineteenth LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 95

century, with three major wars. The so-called Mad Mul- lah of fought a twenty-one-year insurgency against the British from 1899 through 1920 when his forts were finally bombed by British aircraft during World War I. The Maji Maji rebellion (1905-07) in today’s Tanzania fought against attempts by German imperialists to extract value from their possession. However, by the end of World War I, African colonial states had largely established an imperial peace. (The Mau Mau rebellion in Kenya — a largely Kikuyu move- ment to retake the European-occupied highlands — being a notable exception.) Even when nationalist movements arose, they were not violently repressed; in fact, most African states received independence without fighting an- ticolonial Wars. French colonies faced little resistance from the metropole: failed and bloody campaigns to re- tain Vietnam and Algeria exhausted the French public and armed forces, sapping any will to resist the independence movements in sub-Saharan Africa. But there were exceptions in (today’s Zim- babwe), (today’s Namibia), and South Africa. These insurgencies opposed apartheid and mi- nority rule by white settler populations and their descen- dants. There were also independence wars fought against a resolute and nondemocratic Portuguese colonial state in Guinea-Bissau, Angola, and Mozambique. These violent transitions to independence led by African insurgent armies had several common features. First, the insurgent armies were constituted mostly of educated young men who saw low glass ceilings in the colonial administration. These ceilings applied to all Africans, and, thus, the campaigns unified different ethnic and linguistic groups. Second, the insurgent armies did not have access to the arms and technologies of the imperial forces; they needed 96 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

external support against modern armies. In South Africa, the African National Congress, the preeminent party de- manding freedom from apartheid, never established a “liberated zone” or even engaged the South African army in direct combat. It relied instead on “a loose coalition of grassroots activist groups” supported by foreign govern- ments (such as Mozambique after it gained independence) that provided a degree of cover for the insurgent forces (Reno, 2011, 116). In Rhodesia, insurgents trained and regrouped in relative safety in independent Zambia and Mozambique. Third (and relatedly), insurgents seeking independence needed to present a united national front to maintain ex- ternal support, as Western powers were less likely to support a single revolutionary faction than a united in- dependence movement. In the Rhodesia war, presidents (of Zambia) and Julius Nyerere (of Tan- zania) jailed insurgents who did not abide by the unity ac- cords of the two cooperating insurgent armies: the ZAPU (the army of , mostly manned by the Nde- bele population) and ZANU (the army of , mostly manned by the Shona population). In South West Africa, the nationalist Ovambo People’s Organization (OPO) transformed itself into the South West African People’s Organization (SWAPO) to show national unity and thereby win foreign support. Unfortunately, this unity did not always survive independence, as is apparent in the post-independence violent conflict between ZANU and ZAPU in Zimbabwe. Post-Independence Violent Breakdowns in Unity Throughout the postcolonial world, a country’s suscep- tibility to a civil war is at its height in the first few years of independence. This is because minority groups in an inde- pendent state fear that newly empowered groups will treat them unfairly. Fearing marginalization, the best time to LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 97

seek separation is right away, when the new state is weak. Of course, the leaders of the new state will promise fair treatment, but this promise is not credible — these same leaders can renege on protections for minority groups once they have the power to squash separatist campaigns. Fearon (1998) identifies this inability of newly installed presidents to assuage the fears of minority populations as a “commitment problem.” As we noted above, this so-called commitment prob- lem did not manifest itself right away in newly indepen- dent African states. In many cases, colonial armies re- mained in country (through the institution of secondment) protecting the newly installed governments. However, in what are now Angola, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Mozambique, Nigeria, Sudan, and Zimbabwe, civil wars broke out between minority populations and the inheritors of the colonial state. Here we look at two of the more brutal wars, those of Biafra against Nigeria and RENAMO against FRELIMO in Mozambique. Nigeria

This war, in which the Eastern Region of Nigeria at- tempted to secede and declared itself the Republic of Bi- afra, claimed a million lives through combat and famine. A poignant portrayal of the human suffering — albeit a partisan view of the sources of the war — is Chimamanda Ngozi Adichie’s novel Half of a Yellow Sun. While one can dispute aspects of Adichie’s history, the brutality she portrays is irrefutable:

Starvation was a Nigerian weapon of war. Starvation broke Biafra and brought Biafra fame and made Biafra last as long as it did. Starvation made the people of the world take notice and sparked protests and demon- strations in London and Moscow and Czechoslovakia. Starvation made Zambia and Tanzania and Ivory Coast and Gabon recognize Biafra, starvation brought Africa into Nixon’s American campaign and made parents all 98 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

over the world tell their children to eat up. Starvation propelled aid organizations to sneak-fly food into Biafra at night since both sides could not agree on routes. Star- vation aided the careers of photographers. And starvation made the International Red Cross call Biafra its gravest emergency since the Second World War. (Adichie, 2006, 296-297)

The strategy of the Nigerian government to abet mass starvation in a region it claimed to still rule illustrates the immense human suffering that conflict and misrule inflict on citizens. Returning to the origins of the war, readers might recall Lord Lugard’s three-region scheme to knit the different political cultures of the Hausa-Fulani, the Yoruba, and the Igbo into a coherent national unit. Several factors led the Eastern Region (the future Biafra) to defect from this tortured union. First, the East was already losing out to the West in the race for education and, thus, in the competition for remu- nerative civil service jobs that opened with the colonial exit. The West was rich in cocoa (and export proceeds covered the costs of universal primary education), while the East was relatively impoverished given the low prices for its palm products. Having its own national govern- ment would therefore serve the interests of Igbo youth in the race for civil service sinecures. Second, in January 1966, the North and West were enraged by what they saw as an “Igbo coup.” As we described in the previous chapter, General Ironsi’s as- cension, particularly following a coup that claimed no Igbo casualties, was seen in the North and West as the beginning of an Igbo-led dictatorship. In response, Igbo trading communities in the North (in Kano’s sabon garis or neighborhoods of internal migrants) were massacred, sending Igbos a clear message that they were unwelcome outside their own region. The counter-coup that July, in LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 99

which General Ironsi was assassinated, hammered that message home. Third, massive deposits of oil had been discovered in the Bight of Biafra, in the South South Zone, a non- Igbo portion of the Eastern Region. But by a quirk of constitutional fate, mineral rents were to be shared by all regions; unlike taxes on cocoa exports (which accrued to the the West), oil revenues would go directly to the central government. Worse still for the East, Ironsi’s successor, General Gowon, divided the country into twelve new states, and did it in such a way as to disconnect the Igbo majority of the Eastern Region from the oil zones. If the former Eastern Region became a country — a newly independent Biafra — the Igbo plurality would control the future oil revenues. Colonel Odumegwu Ojukwu articulated the East’s de- mands for greater autonomy, and the central government, led by Gowon, agreed to a conciliation conference to be held in a neutral site, in Aburi, Ghana. While the regional military governors were all friends from the British Royal Military Academy Sandhurst (and called each other by their pet names), their interests were irreconcilable. The federal forces were growing stronger and, thus, Ojukwu could not wait to see if Gowon would treat the Igbo- dominated states fairly. If Ojukwu was going to secede, it was best to move early. Moreover, he had a promise from Chief Awolowo that if the East seceded, the West would quickly follow and announce its own state called the Oduduwa Republic. Alas, for the East, Awolowo turned coat. He was appointed minister of finance by Gowon, and he created a new currency that impoverished all Biafrans (who could not transfer their savings denomi- nated in the newly defunct Nigerian currency). With both incentives and the potential for future oil resources, Ojukwu announced secession and moved his army into the zone around Benin — an area between 100 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

the East and West — to confront federal troops, thereby sparking a three-year civil war that resulted in devastating loss of life. FRELIMO and RENAMO in Mozambique

The leader of FRELIMO (Frente de Libertação de Moçambique), Eduardo Mondlane, shared several char- acteristics with the charismatic founders we highlighted in chapter 1. He was educated abroad, receiving a PhD in the US. He also did not represent the country’s largest ethnic group. In fact, Mondlane spent most of his young life abroad and was considered an assimilado due to Por- tuguese and African roots. Nonetheless, Mondlane pre- sented a united military front against ’s colonial armies. Like other anticolonial rebels in nearby Zimbabwe, FRELIMO relied on international support, both the safe haven provided by neighboring Tanzania as well as the support of international aid agencies and the Kennedy administration. Yet, unlike our other founders, Mondlane was never offered the chance to govern; he was assassi- nated by a bomb hidden in a book. He was succeeded by Somara Moisés Machel, who became Mozambique’s first president. Portugal experienced its own democratically inspired coup in 1974, and with this regime change in the metropole, counterinsurgency operations ceased in the colony. FRELIMO inherited control in 1975. But despite the international acclaim accorded to FRELIMO for its commitment to social and economic development and Mondlane’s rigorous commitment to honest government, the young government faced a vigorous challenge from RENAMO (Resistencia Nacional Moçambicana). RENAMO was originally sponsored by the (white- only) Rhodesian government, and later by the apartheid South African government. The Rhodesians resented LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 101

FRELIMO for providing safe haven to their insurgents; the South Africans similarly feared that Mozambique could shelter anti-apartheid activities. Other Western gov- ernments, as part of their anticommunist foreign policy, also provided early support to RENAMO. But RENAMO was not a front for entirely foreign in- terests. The group rallied support domestically from two principal groups: first, traditional elites (particularly from further north) alienated by FRELIMO’s attempts to reor- ganize society through “communal villages” (relocation to government-designed communities organized around co- operative agriculture); and second, urban business classes threatened by FRELIMO’s Marxist inclinations. Com- bining its foreign and domestic support (and running a lucrative protection racket), RENAMO mounted a serious challenge to the state. The civil war (which we discuss in greater detail in chapter 15) destroyed Mozambique’s infrastructure and killed 200,000 noncombatants in the fighting and ensuing famine. The anticolonial struggles, except those in Rhodesia and those against the Portuguese, were largely peaceful, but the unfinished business of colonial separation (in the Democratic Republic of the Congo, in Nigeria, in Zim- babwe, and in Mozambique) had bloody implications. In all these cases, the counterinsurgents lost their wars, but the violence suffered by the affected populations was enormous. Reform (“Second-Liberation”) Rebels The corruption and authoritarianism we described in chapter 3 motivated insurgent campaigns for a “second liberation,” to use Reno’s phrase. ’s National Resistance Movement in Uganda and ’s Tigrean People’s Liberation Front in Ethiopia are the classic success stories. Paul Kagame’s Rwandan Patriotic Front in Rwanda and John Garang’s leadership in 102 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

the Sudan People’s Liberation Army in Sudan also share many qualities of second-liberation rebellions. Kagame’s forces were victorious, leading him to the presidency. Garang, in line with the US-sponsored Comprehensive Peace Agreement, became the first vice president of Su- dan, but he died in a plane crash a mere few weeks after assuming that office. Unlike the liberation campaigns against colonial pow- ers, these movements had minimal and inconsistent West- ern backing. First, the Cold War was ending and, with it, developed countries’ intense interest in the internal af- fairs of sub-Saharan states. Second, these reform-minded rebellions came on the heels of antidemocratic campaigns in the region. Colonel Muammar Qaddafi of Libya sup- ported rebels in Chad, Liberia, and Sierra Leone; South Africa’s apartheid government contributed to RENAMO’s campaign in Mozambique. Genuine reformists got lost in this maelstrom of insurgencies. Lacking external backers, second-liberation rebels found few safe havens. The Somali National Movement (based in former British Somaliland) and Sudan Peo- ple’s Liberation Army (based in today’s South Sudan) got kicked out of Ethiopia, and the Rwandan Patriotic Front (Tutsi emigres based in Uganda) faced anti-immigrant hostility. Without international funding or shelter, these reform rebels needed to win support from their fellow citizens in the diaspora and, more importantly, in coun- try. Sympathetic villagers could provide provisions and cover to rebels battling state armies. To cultivate this local support, these second-liberation rebels shifted their tactics, engaging in less looting and violence toward local populations (J. Weinstein, 2007).

A Case of a Successful Second Liberation: Museveni, the NRA, and Uganda

Idi Amin’s military dictatorship was a human disas- LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 103

ter. Amin’s regime killed between 100,000 and 500,000 Ugandans; he also deported 80,000 individuals of Asian, largely Indian, descent. This loss of life and the expropri- ation of the Asian business class destroyed the economy. Amin’s brutality alienated civilians and spurred a mutiny in 1978. Some of the defecting soldiers fled to neighbor- ing Tanzania, where Amin stalked them, invading Tanza- nia. Amin’s army was unable to hold ground against the Tanzanians, who forced Amin to retreat and eventually abdicate power and flee Uganda. The first post-Amin governments were weak and short- lived; after eight years of Amin’s reign, his immediate successor served for less than seventy days. When elec- tions were held in 1980, Milton Obote reassumed power, relying on his close relations with the military. Yoweri Museveni, who had contested the election, charged that the polls had been rigged and launched a rebellion. He organized a militia called the National Resistance Army (NRA) from a coterie of his former classmates at the University of Dar es Salaam, his ethnic kin from the Banyankole group, and Ugandan volunteers trained in the FRELIMO insurgency who had been stationed in Dar es Salaam. They created a base in a part of the country close to the capital (the Luwero Triangle) and slowly built up support from the countryside. Their mission was bol- stered when the military overthrew Obote, and the newly installed officers sought to make a deal with Museveni. In December 1985 the government and insurgents, under sponsorship of Kenyan president , agreed on a peace formula that would give Museveni the role of deputy chairman of the ruling Military Council. However, Museveni never laid down his arms and overthrew the military government the following month upon returning to Uganda (Girod, 2015, 102). In 1986, Museveni was sworn in as president. Save for a lingering but brutal in- surgency in Uganda’s northwest — the Lord’s Resistance 104 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Army — Museveni’s rule achieved a degree of peace in Uganda not fully experienced since the colonial era. Museveni’s victory, like that of most other reform rebels,6 brought greater stability. Yet, like the first gener- 6 South Sudan’s John Garang ation of liberators, these leaders began to see themselves died in a plane crash before as- suming office. as irreplaceable bastions of their fragile states. Both Mu- seveni and Kagame have amended their constitutions to enable extended terms. As of late 2018, Museveni had served for thirty-two years; Kagame, for sixteen years. In Ethiopia’s parliamentary system, there were no term limits, so Zenawi’s seventeen years as prime minister — a post he held until his death — did not require constitu- tional reengineering. Nonetheless, given his repression of opposition politicians and human rights abuses, he is not remembered as a committed democrat. These second-liberation rebels who attained power may not have brought democracy and the rule of law; but, well connected and indebted to the local populations that supported them, they brought heretofore unfulfilled security to their populations. Warlord Rebels If the few second-generation leaders ultimately gained international support, rebels of the next generation were seen as abominations. European and American progres- sives who stood with the anticolonial and, often, Marxist rebels could not abide those who Reno refers to as “war- lord” leaders (Reno, 1999). Consider Prince Yormie Johnson of Liberia, one of the rebels seeking to replace Samuel Doe.7 In Stephen 7 As a master sergeant in the Ellis’s chilling opening chapter of The Mask of Anarchy, Liberian Army, Doe overthrew , the leader of we see little resemblance to the charismatic founders of the oligarchic regime of the chapter 1. In a drunken state, and his True Whig Party, descendants of the American slaves who had lackeys visited the presidential headquarters and brutal- resettled in Liberia. ized Doe to the point of excising his heart and consuming it (Ellis, 2006). These leaders did not unify citizens by LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 105

articulating a common future; rather, they cannibalized the state, attempting to destroy or dismantle any person or organization that could pose a threat (including their own bureaucracies). (They built the “shadow states” that we described in chapter 3.) Besides Liberia, warlord leaders terrorized civilian populations in Democratic Republic of the Congo, Sierra Leone, Côte d’Ivoire, Guinea-Bissau, and Somalia, where several warlords competed for control over the presidential palace after the dictator, Maxamad Siyaad Barre, was overthrown in 1991. These warlord leaders typically succeeded the person- alistic regimes of earlier coup-victors, such as Samuel Doe or of the Democratic Republic of the Congo.8 And unlike the first- or second-generation 8 Mobutu also employed many liberationists (often with Marxist pretensions), these war- of the strategies that Reno as- sociates with warlord politi- lords professed no ideology, master plan, or even re- cians: hollowing out govern- formist agenda. These were often former members of ment agencies, concentrating power, and ruling not through the dictator’s inner circle (Prince Johnson and Charles a social contract with citizens, Taylor in Liberia are examples) who defected to seize a but rather through deals with larger share of the official and illicitly generated revenues militias. flowing to the ruler. They commanded (intentionally) fragmented security forces, bands of militias or foreign mercenaries whose continued loyalty came at a fee (and, thus, could also be bought by a higher bidder). Where rulers could not pay cash, that fee took the form of lib- erties to tax (read: pillage) certain towns or villages: in Liberia, Lidow (2016) finds that under- or unpaid com- manders preyed on local populations. Perhaps unsurprisingly, these rebel leaders (unlike Mu- seveni or Kagame) did not provide stability. Their frag- mented and fickle security forces could not decisively defeat insurgents, who were able to mount campaigns using cheap imports of light arms. Moreover, these lead- ers did not enjoy the support of a major power. Thus, resolving these long-term and violent stalemates between governments and insurgents fell to the United Nations, 106 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

with the Security Council for a short period of time get- ting Russian consent to peacekeeping operations under the leadership of Boutros Boutros-Ghali and Kofi Annan — a subject we return to in chapter 15.

Case Study of Warlord Politics in Somalia

Maxamed Siyaad Barre is an example of a first- generation coup leader: a general in the Somali army who took the reins of power (with Soviet help) after the overthrow of the democratically elected, but highly cor- rupt, government of President Abdirashid Ali Sharmarke in 1969. Both Siyaad and Sharmarke were from the for- mer Italian colony of Somalia and from the Darood clan family, albeit from different sub-clans. Somalia had deep political divisions, despite its cul- tural homogeneity; nearly all citizens spoke the same language and subscribed to . The Darood favored a united Somalia comprising the North (Soma- liland) and South, the Somali majority zones of Ethiopia (called the Ogaadeen), the Northeast Region of Kenya, and the French Territory of Afars and Issas (today’s Dji- bouti). In this Greater Somalia, the Darood would be the largest ethnic group. Non-Darood northerners thus stood to lose influence with unification and nearly derailed the initial joining of Somalia and Somaliland in 1960.9 9 The majority clan family in the north was the Isaaq; in the Siyaad seized upon neighboring Ethiopia’s civil war south, the largest group was the (which would bring Mengistu to power) to realize his Hawiye. vision of a unified Somali nation. Using Soviet military materiel, Siyaad sent his own army to provide support for the Western Somali Liberation Front in Ethiopia’s Ogaadeen region in 1977. There was early success, but then Somalia’s Soviet patrons switched sides, seeing an alliance with Mengistu as a bigger Cold War prize. The Somalis were quickly routed, and the blame game began. The Isaaq generals were dubbed as traitors, and Siyaad LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 107

ordered the bombing of Isaaq-dominated Hargeisa, the capital of former British Somaliland. Siyaad survived this chaos using brilliant clan arith- metic and brutal tactics. He faced three clan-based armies, all attempting to seize power in Mogadishu: the army of the Isaaq (the SNM), the army of the Hawiye (the USC), and the army of the Majertayn Daroods, a rival to Siyaad’s Mareexaan Daroods (the SSDF). To hold off these forces, Siyaad rented out the Soviet-built air base in Berbera (the port city of the North) to the Americans for their recently created Rapid Deployment Force. This arrange- ment yielded around $40 million a year in US foreign military assistance. Siyaad used this political budget to purge potential rivals among military commanders and arm disaffected sub-clans within rival clans. By buying allegiances and fomenting rivalries, Siyaad maintained a tenuous hold on power for more than a decade. In 1991, Siyaad was finally forced from power by a loose collection of rival groups. This power vacuum sucked would-be successors into a conflict among war- lords that eventually motivated UN peacekeeping opera- tions. With Siyaad fleeing by tank to Kenya, the USC army reached the presidential palace before other insurgent groups and, thus, laid claim to leadership. A Hawiye businessman, Ali Mahdi (sub-clan Abgal), was sworn in as Somalia’s president with logistical help from the remnants of the Italian embassy staff that remained amid the siege of Mogadishu.10 Yet, Maxamed Farraax Aidiid, 10 In their role as UN trustees of from the Hawiye sub-clan Habr Gedir, had commanded Somalia post World War II, the Italians relied heavily on Abgal the USC army south of the capital and felt that he should support and favored them with be president as the clan’s leading military commander. He government and business deals. brought his troops up to Mogadishu (capturing a delivery of currency printed abroad) and initiated an intra-Hawiye war for Mogadishu. The Issaq-led SNM, refusing to abide by peace talks, returned to former British Somaliland 108 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

in the north and built an unrecognized government in a relatively peaceful region. Yet, the south devolved into an ungoverned and conflict-ridden region: the fractionalized militias recruited young boys willy-nilly from all clans to man roadblocks and engage in kidnapping, piracy, and extortion to main- tain control over neighborhoods or ports. The anarchy pro- vided opportunities for Salafist operatives to recruit. Ex- tortion rather than nation building was the modus operandi for this generation of warlords qua political leaders. Various institutions have tried to bring stable gov- ernment to Somalia: UNOSOM (and other acronymed organizations sponsored by the UN Security Council), the Transitional Federal Government (TFG, set up from Nairobi, with North European diplomatic support), the Islamic Courts Union (basically a Habr Gedir counter to the Majertayn dominance in the TFG), the Ethiopian army encouraged by the United States to help bring order to the country, al-Shabaab (a rump group of the defeated Islamic Courts Union), and the African Union Mission to Somalia (AMISOM). As will be analyzed in chapter 15, AMISOM has had moderate success in displacing al-Shabaab, but the civil war (technically) continues, and the warlords re- main decisive in resisting the restoration of a nation-state. 4 The Relationship Between Coups and Insurgencies In our discussion we have treated coups and civil wars as distinct syndromes plaguing sub-Saharan states in the generation after independence. Yet, as Roessler (2016) argues, coups and civil wars are both consequences of the same strategic problem facing leaders. Recall de Waal’s political business manager (PBM), who uses the spoils of office to build a loyal base of support and line his or her own pockets. These PBMs LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 109

face a difficult problem: they can co-opt other political elites, showering them with cabinet positions or other sinecures in an effort to buy loyalty. Alternatively, they can exclude (or even purge) other elites. The first choice invites coups: ministers and military commanders can more easily organize and execute coups from within the palace or cabinet room. Thus, with every ministerial appointment, the PBM cannot be sure whether he or she is buying an ally or empowering a rival. But, the second choice, excluding elites, can provoke external challenges. The surest way to “coup-proof” is for the PBM to surround himself with a palace guard and powerful ministers (in defense and treasury most essen- tially) made up of ethnic kin. Yet, in this effort to prevent coups, the PBM provokes insurgencies. Elites that are excluded from the PBM’s coalition invest in militias, in- creasing the long-term risk of an ethno-regional rebellion. Moreover, by focusing security resources on preventing palace coups, the PBM diverts attention from managing peripheral insurgencies. In short, the PBM’s dilemma is that actions that reduce the short-term risk of internal challenges raise the long-term risk of civil war. The genocidal campaign in Sudan against the Darfuri rebellion illustrates this Faustian trade-off. In the 1990s, Sudan’s president Omar al-Bashir had many Darfuris in his inner circle, and these regime loyalists stood with their president against ethnic kin to forestall an insurgency. However, Hassan al-Turabi, al-Bashir’s co-conspirator who helped bring him into power and served as the sec- retary general of the Islamic Movement, had his eyes on the presidency, and he built up a network of supporters in Darfur. Fearing a coup by al-Turabi and his Darfuri allies, al-Bashir broke ties with those Darfuris in the corridors of power. But by coup-proofing his regime, he effectively in- centivized Darfuris to return to their home territories and 110 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

provide support for the devastating rebellion that ensued (see Roessler, 2016). Thus, the outcomes are linked. Coup-proofing facili- tates insurgency, as it not only enrages an excluded ethnic group but also weakens the army’s counterinsurgency ca- pability due to expenditures for the palace guard. Worse, lack of local knowledge in the terrain of the excluded groups leads the emasculated national army toward in- discriminate violence, inflaming the population that the rebels seek to mobilize. Thus Roessler’s key findings (fig- ure 4.4): excluded groups (left) are more likely to rebel; groups included in government (right) are more likely to mount a successful coup.

● Pr(Rebellion) Pr(Successful Coup) Figure 4.4 Trade-off Between Coups and 0.020 Insurgency (Roessler, 2016)

0.015 ●

0.010 Probability

0.005

0.000

Excluded Group Included Group

Group status is lagged by one year.

5 Conclusion There has been an evolution in the types of conflicts waged in independent Africa; wars have become increas- ingly brutal and state-destroying. There is a logic to many LAG IN SOCIAL ORDER 111

of these civil wars: elites cannot credibly commit their loyalty to rulers; once inside the halls of power, ministers have an incentive to mount a palace coup. In response, rulers have an incentive to recruit and heavily invest in palace guards comprising their ethnic kin. Unfortunately, this coup-proofing response pushes excluded elites into insurgent action. As reported by Fearon and Laitin (2003), the funda- mental problem of civil war is weak states in which lead- ers, to protect themselves from their own populations, are less able to protect their populations from rapacious insurgents. Fearon and Laitin point out that weak states rarely have information about their own populations for monitoring purposes.11 The solution must be capable 11 Alas, as we know from Jer- states that can protect their populations. But this leads to ven (2014), African states lack reliable national statistics. the question as to why African states are “weak”? Why do we have civil wars that do not make states, but rather destroy them? These are questions that remain on our agenda and are the foundation for part II and part III of this book.

17. References

Abernethy, David B. The Political Dilemma of Popular Education: An African Case. Stanford University Press, 1969.

Abernethy, David B. Bureaucratic Growth and Economic Stagnation in Sub-Saharan Africa. In Commins, Stephen K., editor, Africa’s Development Challenges and the World Bank: Hard Questions, Costly Choices. Lynne Rienner, 1988.

Acemoglu, Daron. Theory, General Equilibrium, and Political Economy in Development Economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(3):17–32, 2010.

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A. Why Nations Fail. Crown Business, 2013.

Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A. The Colonial Origins of Com- parative Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5): 1369–1401, 2001.

Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A. An African Success Story: Botswana. In Rodrik, Dani, editor, In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth, 80–119. Princeton University Press, 2003.

Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A. Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth. In Aghion, Philippe, and Durlauf, Steven N., editors, Handbook of Economic Growth, volume 1, 385–472. Elsevier, 2005.

Achebe, Chinua. Things Fall Apart. Anchor Books, 1959.

Adedeji, John L. The Legacy of J. J. Rawlings in Ghanian Politics, 1979-2000. African Studies Quarterly, 5(2):1–27, 2001.

Adichie, Chimamanda Ngozi. Half of a Yellow Sun. Alfred A. Knopf, 2006.

Adida, Claire L.; Laitin, David D., and Valfort, Marie-Anne. Why Muslim Integration Fails in Christian-Heritage Societies. Harvard University Press, 2016.

Afigbo, Adiele Eberechukwu. The Warrant Chiefs: Indirect Rule in Southeastern Nigeria, 1891-1929. Cambridge University Press, 1972. 352 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Ake, Claude. Democratization of Disempowerment in Africa. Malthouse Press, 1994.

Ake, Claude. Rethinking African Democracy. In Diamond, Larry, and Plattner, Marc F., editors, The Global Divergence of Democracies, 63–75. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 2001.

Albaugh, Ericka A. State-Building and Multilingual Education in Africa. Cambridge University Press, 2014.

Albouy, David Y. The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Investigation of the Settler Mortality Data. NBER Working Paper, 2008. http://www.nber.org/ papers/w14130.

Alden, Chris. The UN and the Resolution of Conflict in Mozambique. Journal of Modern African Studies, 33(1):103–128, 1995.

Alesina, Alberto; Easterly, William, and Matuszeski, Janina. Artificial States. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(2):246–277, 2011.

Alesina, Alberto, and La Ferrara, Eliana. Ethnic Diversity and Economic Performance. Journal of Economic Literature, 43:1–50, 2005.

Allen, Christopher. Benin. Pinter, 1989.

Amnesty International. Stars on Their Shoulders. Blood on Their Hands: War Crimes Com- mitted by the Nigerian Military. May 2015.

Annan, Kofi. The Question of Intervention: Statements by the Secretary-General. United Nations Department of Public Information, 1999.

Appiah, Kwame Anthony. In My Father’s House: Africa in the Philosophy of Culture. Oxford University Press, 1992.

Apter, David Ernest. Ghana in Transition. Princeton University Press, 2015.

Arriola, Leonardo R. Multi-Ethnic Coalitions in Africa. Cambridge University Press, 2012.

Asiwaju, Anthony Ijaola. Partitioned Africans: Ethnic Relations Across Africa’s International Boundaries, 1884-1984. C. Hurst, 1985.

Asunka, Joseph; Brierley, Sarah; Golden, Miriam; Kramon, Eric, and Ofosu, George. Electoral Fraud or Violence: The Effect of Observers on Party Manipulation Strategies. British Journal of Political Science, 1–23, 2017.

Autesserre, Séverine. Peaceland: Conflict Resolution and the Everyday Politics of International Intervention. Cambridge University Press, 2014.

AVERT. HIV and AIDS in Sub-Saharan Africa: Regional Overview. May 2015. REFERENCES 353

Awolowo, Chief Obafemi. Awo: The Autobiography of Chief Obafemi Awolowo. Cambridge University Press, 1960.

Azikiwe, Nnamdi. Zik: A Selection from the Speeches of Nnamdi Azikiwe. Cambridge University Press, 1961.

Banerjee, Abhijit, and Duflo, Esther. Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. PublicAffairs, 2012.

Banerjee, Abhijit; Duflo, Esther; Goldberg, Nathanael; Karlan, Dean; Osei, Robert; Parienté, William; Shapiro, Jeremy; Thuysbaert, Bram, and Udry, Chris. A Multifaceted Program Causes Lasting Progress for the Very Poor: Evidence from Six Countries. Science, 348 (6236):1260799–1260799, 2015.

Barbag-Stoll, Anna. Social and Linguistic History of Nigerian Pidgin English: As Spoken by the Yoruba with Special Reference to the English Derived Lexicon. Stauffenberg Verlag, 1983.

Basset, Thomas J. The Uncaptured Corvée: Cotton in Côte d’Ivoire, 1912–1946. In Isaacman, Allen F., and Roberts, Richard, editors, Cotton, Colonialism, and Social History in Sub- Saharan Africa. Heinemann, 1995.

Bates, Robert H. Unions, Parties and Political Development: A Study of Mineworkers in Zambia. Yale University Press, 1971.

Bates, Robert H. Markets and States in Tropical Africa: The Political Basis of Agricultural Policies. University of California Press, 1981.

Bates, Robert H., and Block, Steven A. Revisiting African Agriculture: Institutional Change and Productivity Growth. Journal of Politics, 75(2):372–384, 2013.

BBC News. Ebola: Mapping the Outbreak. BBC News, January 14, 2016. https://www. bbc.com/news/world-africa-28755033.

Bekoe, Dorina A. Introduction: The Scope, Nature, and Pattern of Electoral Violence in Sub-Saharan Africa. In Bekoe, Dorina A, editor, Voting in Fear: Electoral Violence in Sub-Saharan Africa. United States Institute of Peace, 2012.

Bender, Gerald J. Angola Under the Portuguese: The Myth and the Reality. University of California Press, 1978.

Benn, Margaux. Newly Elected Central African Republic Leader Faces Hard Realities. Times, February 21, 2016.

Berg, Elliot J. Socialism and Economic Development in Tropical Africa. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 78(4):549–573, 1964. 354 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Berman, Bruce J., and Lonsdale, John M. Crises of Accumulation, Coercion and the Colonial State: the Development of the Labor Control System in Kenya, 1919–1929. Canadian Journal of African Studies/La Revue canadienne des études africaines, 14(1):55–81, 1980.

Bernal, Victoria. Forced Labour and Migration. In Isacman, Allen F., and Roberts, Richard, editors, Cotton, Colonialism and Social History in Sub-Saharan Africa. Heinemann, 1995.

Bienen, Henry. Tanzania: Party Transformation and Economic Development. Princeton University Press, 1970.

Blattman, Christopher, and Annan, Jeannie. Can Employment Reduce Lawlessness and Rebellion? A Field Experiment with High-Risk Men in a Fragile State. American Political Science Review, 110(1):1–85, 2016.

Bloom, David E., and Sachs, Jeffrey D. Geography, Demography, and Economic Growth in Africa. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1998(2):207, 1998.

Bold, Tessa; Kimenyi, Mwangi; Mwabu, Germano; Ng’ang’a, Alice, and Sandefur, Justin. Scaling Up What Works: Experimental Evidence on External Validity in Kenyan Education. CGD Working Paper, March 2013. http://www.cgdev.org/sites/default/ files/Sandefur-et-al-Scaling-Up-What-Works.pdf.

Boone, Catherine. Political Topographies of the African State. Cambridge University Press, October 2003.

Boone, Catherine. Property and Political Order in Africa: Land Rights and the Structure of Politics. Cambridge University Press, 2014.

Bourdieu, Pierre. Language and Symbolic Power. Cambridge University Press, 1991.

Boutros-Ghali, Boutros. An Agenda for Peace. United Nations, Technical Report A/47/477, June 1992.

Bowen, Sarah. Language Barriers in Access to Health Care. Health Canada Ottawa, 2001.

Bratton, Michael, and van de Walle, Nicolas. Popular Protest and Political Reform in Africa. Comparative Politics, 24(4):419–442, 1992.

Bratton, Michael, and van de Walle, Nicolas. Neopatrimonial Regimes and Political Transitions in Africa. World Politics, 46(4):453–489, 1994.

Brooks, Andrew. Colonial Militaries and Coups. PSE Working Papers, 2016.

Brooks, Murrell L. Coffee, Liberalization, and Democratic Development in Tanzania: A Study in the Politics of Agriculture and Development in Transitional States. ProQuest Dissertations and Theses, 2007. REFERENCES 355

Bruton, Henry J. A Reconsideration of Import Substitution. Journal of Economic Literature, 36:903–936, 1998.

Burgess, Robin; Jedwab, Remi; Miguel, Edward; Morjaria, Ameet, and Padró i Miquel, Gerard. The Value of Democracy: Evidence from Road Building in Kenya. American Economic Review, 105(6):1817–1851, 2015.

Callaghy, Thomas M. The State as Lame Leviathan: The Patrimonial Administrative State in Africa. In Ergas, Zaki, editor, The African State in Transition, 87–116. Springer, 1987.

Callaghy, Thomas M. Lost Between State and Market: the Politics of Economic Adjustment in Ghana, Zambia, and Nigeria. In Nelson, Joan M, editor, Economic Crisis and Policy Choice The Politics of Adjustment in Less Developed Countries, 257–270. Princeton University Press, 1990.

Callaghy, Thomas M., and Ravenhill, John. Hemmed In: Responses to Africa’s Economic Decline. Columbia University Press, 1993.

Callen, Michael, and Long, James D. Institutional Corruption and Election Fraud: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Afghanistan. American Economic Review, 105(1):354–381, 2014.

Campante, Filipe, and Yanagizawa-Drott, David. Does Religion Affect Economic Growth and Happiness? Evidence from Ramadan. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(2):1–45, 2015.

Cederman, Lars-Erik; Wimmer, Andreas, and Min, Brian. Why Do Ethnic Groups Rebel? New Data and Analysis. World Politics, 62:87–119, 2010.

Césaire, Aimé; Berger, J.; Bostock, A., and de Francia, P. Return to My Native Land. Steerforth Press, 1939/2014.

Chanock, Martin. A Peculiar Sharpness: An Essay on Property in the History of Customary Law in Colonial Africa. Journal of African History, 32(1):65–88, 1991.

Chingono, Mark F. The State, Violence and Development: The Political Economy of War in Mozambique, 1975-1992. Avebury, 1996.

Chin’ono, Hopewell, and Onishi, Norimitsu. In Zimbabwe, Mugabe’s Birthday Is Rife with Political Jockeying. New York Times, February 29, 2016.

Christensen, Darin. Concession Stands: How Foreign Investment in Mining Incites Protest in Africa. International Organization, forthcoming.

Christensen, Darin; Dube, Oeindrila; Haushofer, Johannes; Siddiqi, Bilal, and Voors, Maarten. Healthcare Delivery during Crises: Experimental Evidence from Sierra Leone’s Ebola Outbreak. Working Paper, September 2018a. 356 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Christensen, Darin; Hartman, Alexandra C, and Samii, Cyrus. Property Rights, Investment, and Land Grabs: An Institutional Natural Experiment in Liberia. Working Paper, September 2018b. https://darinchristensen.com/files/liberia-tenure.pdf.

Christensen, Darin. The Geography of Repression in Africa. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 62(7):1517–1543, 2018.

Clark, John. Petro-Politics in Congo. Journal of Democracy, 8(3):62–76, 1997.

Clemens, Michael A., and Demombynes, Gabriel. When Does Rigorous Impact Evaluation Make a Difference? The Case of Millennium Villages. CGD Work- ing Paper, October 2010. http://www.cgdev.org/sites/default/files/ 1424496_file_Clemens_Demombynes_Evaluation_FINAL.pdf.

Cohen, Jessica, and Dupas, Pascaline. Free Distribution or Cost-Sharing? Evidence from a Randomized Malaria Prevention Experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(1): 1–45, 2010.

Collier, Paul, and Gunning, Jan Willem. Why Has Africa Grown Slowly? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(3):3–22, 1999.

Collier, Paul, and Hoeffler, Anke. Greed and Grievance in Civil War. Oxford Economic Papers, 56(4):563–595, 2004.

Collier, Paul, and Vicente, Pedro C. Violence, Bribery, and Fraud: The Political Economy of Elections in Sub-Saharan Africa. Public Choice, 153(1):117–147, 2011.

Cooper, Frederick. Decolonization and African Society: The Labor Question in French and British Africa. Cambridge University Press, 1996.

Couttenier, Mathieu, and Soubeyran, Raphael. Drought and Civil War in Sub-Saharan Africa. Economic Journal, 124(575):201–244, 2013.

Crabb, Cecil Van Meter. The Elephants and the Grass: A Study of Nonalignment. Praeger, 1965.

Dale, Richard. Botswana’s Search for Autonomy in Southern Africa. Greenwood, 1995.

Davidson, Basil. The African Slave Trade. James Currey, 1961.

Dell, Melissa. The Persistent Effects of Peru’s Mining Mita. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 78(6):1863–1903, 2010.

Dell, Melissa; Jones, Benjamin F., and Olken, Benjamin A. Temperature Shocks and Economic Growth: Evidence from the Last Half Century. American Economic Journal: Macroeco- nomics, 4(3):66–95, 2012. REFERENCES 357

Dercon, Stefan, and Gutiérrez-Romero, Roxana. Triggers and Characteristics of the 2007 Kenyan Electoral Violence. World Development, 40(4):731–744, 2012.

Devarajan, Shantayanan, and Fengler, Wolfgang. Africa’s Economic Boom: Why the Pessimists and the Optimists Are Both Right. Foreign Affairs, 92:68, May/June 2013. https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/west- africa/2013-04-03/africas-economic-boom. de Waal, Alex. Tragedy in Darfur. Boston Review, October 2004. de Waal, Alex. The Real Politics of the Horn of Africa. John Wiley & Sons, 2015.

Diamond, Larry. Is the Third Wave of Democratization Over? An Empirical Assessment. Work- ing Paper, February 1997. https://www3.nd.edu/~kellogg/publications/ workingpapers/WPS/236.pdf.

Doyle, Michael W., and Sambanis, Nicholas. International Peacebuilding: A Theoretical and Qantitative Analysis. American Political Science Review, 94(4):779–801, 2000.

Doyle, Michael W., and Sambanis, Nicholas. Making War and Building Peace: United Nations Peace Operations. Princeton University Press, 2006.

Dreher, Axel; Fuchs, Andreas; Hodler, Roland; Parks, Bradley C.; Raschky, Paul A., and Tierney, Michael. Aid on Demand: African Leaders and the Geography of China’s Foreign Assistance. AidData Working Paper, Octo- ber 2016. http://aiddata.org/sites/default/files/inline/wp3_- _revised_working_paper_series_dreher_et_al_2016_october.pdf.

Dreher, Axel, and Schneider, Friedrich. Corruption and the Shadow Economy: An Empirical Analysis. Public Choice, 144(1-2):215–238, 2009.

Dubois, W. E. B, . To the Nations of the World. Address to the Pan-African Congress, London 1900. Cosigned by Walters, Alexander; and Brown, Henry B. and Williams, H. Sylvester.

Dunning, Thad. Conditioning the Effects of Aid: Cold War politics, Donor Credibility, and Democracy in Africa. International Organization, 58(2):409–423, 2004.

East, Roger, and Thomas, Richard. Profiles of People in Power: The World’s Government Leaders. Taylor & Francis, 2003.

Easterly, William. The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists’ Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics. MIT Press, 2002.

Easterly, William. The White Man’s Burden: Why the West’s Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done So Much Ill and So Little Good. Penguin, 2006.

Easterly, William, and Levine, Ross. Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4):1203–1250, 1997. 358 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Eboussi Boulaga, Fabien. Les conférences nationales en Afrique noire: une affaire à suivre. Éd. Karthala, 1993.

Ekeh, Peter P. Colonialism and the Two Publics in Africa: A Theoretical Statement. Compara- tive Studies in Society and History, 17(1):91–112, 1975.

Ellis, Stephen. The Mask of Anarchy: The Destruction of Liberia and the Religious Dimension of an African Civil War, Updated Edition. NYU Press, 2006.

Emerson, Rupert. From Empire to Nation: The Rise to Self-Assertion of Asian and African peoples. Harvard University Press, 1960.

Engerman, Stanley L., and Sokoloff, Kenneth L. Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development Among New World Economics. NBER Working Paper, 1–55, October 2002. http://www.nber.org/papers/w9259.

Englebert, Pierre, and Hummel, Rebecca. Let’s Stick Together: Understanding Africa’s Secessionist Deficit. African Affairs, 104(416):399–427, 2005.

Enikolopov, Ruben; Korovkin, Vasily; Petrova, Maria; Sonin, Konstantin, and Zakharov, Alexei. Field Experiment Estimate of Electoral Fraud in Russian Parliamentary Elections. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110(2):448–452, 2013.

Ensminger, Jean. Changing Property Rights: Reconciling Formal and Informal Reights to Land in Africa. In Drobak, John N., and Nye, John V. C., editors, The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, 165–196. Academic Press, 1997.

Evans-Pritchard, E. E. The Nuer. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1940.

Everett, Glyn, and Wilks, Alex. The World Bank’s Genuine Savings Indicator: A Useful Measure of Sustainability. Bretton Woods Project, October 1999.

Fall, Aïssatou. Understanding the Casamance Conflict: A Background. KAIPTC Monograph, December 2010.

Faris, Stephan. The Real Roots of Darfur. The Atlantic, 299(3), April 2007. https://www.theatlantic.com/magazine/archive/2007/04/ the-real-roots-of-darfur/305701/.

Fearon, James D. Commitment Problems and the Spread of Ethnic Conflict. In Lake, David A., and Rothchild, Donald, editors, The International Spread of Ethnic Conflict Fear, Diffusion, and Escalation. Princeton University Press, 1998.

Fearon, James D. The Bad Borders Meme. January 2011. http://themonkeycage. org/2011/01/the_bad_borders_meme/.

Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D. Explaining Interethnic Cooperation. American Political Science Review, 90(4):715–735, 1996. REFERENCES 359

Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D. Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War. American Political Science Review, 97(1):75–90, 2003.

Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D. Neotrusteeship and the Problem of Weak States. International security, 28(4):5–43, 2004.

Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D. Civil War Termination. PSE Working Papers, 2007.

Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D. How Persistent Is Armed Conflict? Work- ing Paper, March 2013. https://web.stanford.edu/group/fearon- research/cgi-bin/wordpress/wp-content/uploads/2013/10/ persistenceofarmedconflict.pdf.

Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D. Does Contemporary Armed Conflict Have “Deep His- torical Roots”? PSE Working Papers, 2014. http://leitner.yale.edu/sites/ default/files/files/persistenceofarmedconflict3.pdf.

Ferguson, Charles A. Diglossia. Word, 15(2):325–340, 1959.

Finnegan, William. A Complicated War: The Harrowing of Mozambique. University of California Press, 1992.

First, Ruth. The Barrel of a Gun: Political Power in Africa and the Coup d’État. Penguin, 1970.

Foccart, Jacques. Journal de l’Elysée. Fayard, 2001.

Forson, Barnabas. Code-Switching in Akan-English Bilingualism. PhD thesis, University of California, Los Angeles, 1979.

Fortna, Page. Does Peacekeeping Keep Peace? International Intervention and the Duration of Peace After Civil War. International Studies Quarterly, 48(2):269–292, 2004.

Fosu, Augustin Kwasi. Anti-Growth Syndromes in Africa: A Synthesis of the Case Studies. In Ndulu, Benno J.; O’Connell, Stephen A.; Bates, Robert H.; Collier, Paul, and Soludo, Chukwuma C., editors, The Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960-2000, 137–172. Cambridge University Press, 2008.

Franck, Raphaël, and Rainer, Ilia. Does the Leader’s Ethnicity Matter? Ethnic Favoritism, Education, and Health in Sub-Saharan Africa. American Political Science Review, 106(2): 294–325, 2012.

Gebreeyesus, Mulu. Industrial Policy and Development in Ethiopia: Evolution and Present Experimentation. Africa Growth Initiative, 2016.

Geertz, Clifford. The Interpretation of Cultures: Selected Essays. Basic Books, 1973. 360 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Gennaioli, Nicola, and Rainer, Ilia. The Modern Impact of Precolonial Centralization in Africa. Journal of Economic Growth, 12:185–234, 2007.

Gerschenkron, Alexander. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Belknap Press, 1962.

Gettleman, Jeffrey. Home of Congo Presidential Challenger Is Surrounded by Police. New York Times, May 5, 2016.

Gilligan, Michael J.; Mvukiyehe, Eric N., and Samii, Cyrus. Reintegrating Rebels into Civilian Life: Quasi-Experimental Evidence from Burundi. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(4): 598–626, 2013.

Girod, Desha. Explaining Post-conflict Reconstruction. Oxford University Press, 2015.

Glaeser, Edward L.; La Porta, Rafael; Lopez-de Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. Do Institutions Cause Growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3):271–303, 2004.

Goldstein, Markus, and Udry, Chris. The Profits of Power: Land Rights and Agricultural Investment in Ghana. Journal of Political Economy, 116(6):981–1022, 2008.

Goldstein, Markus; Houngbedji, Kenneth; Kondylis, Florence; O’Sullivan, Michael, and Selod, Harris. Formalizing Rural Land Rights in West Africa: Evidence from a Randomized Impact Evaluation in Benin. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 1–56, October 2015.

Gollin, Douglas; Jedwab, Remi, and Vollrath, Dietrich. Urbanization with and Without Industrialization. Journal of Economic Growth, 21:35–70, 2016.

Good, Charles M. Pioneer Medical Missions in Colonial Africa. Social Science & Medicine, 32(1):1–10, 1991.

Groningen Growth and Development Centre. The Maddison Project. 2013. https://www. rug.nl/ggdc/historicaldevelopment/maddison/?lang=en.

Grundy, Kenneth W. Conflicting Images of the Military in Africa. East African Publishing House, 1968.

Guiso, Luigi; Sapienza, Paola, and Zingales, Luigi. Does Culture Affect Economic Outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2):23–48, 2006.

Gunning, Jan Willem. Shocks, Risk, and African Growth. In Ndulu, Benno J.; O’Connell, Stephen A.; Bates, Robert H.; Collier, Paul, and Soludo, Chukwuma C., editors, The Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960-2000, 297–314. Cambridge University Press, 2008.

Gunther, John. Inside Africa. Harper New York, 1955. REFERENCES 361

Haber, Stephen, and Menaldo, Victor. Do Natural Resources Fuel Authoritarianism? A Reappraisal of the Resource Curse. American Political Science Review, 105(1):882–897, 2011.

Habyarimana, James; Humphreys, Macartan; Posner, Daniel N., and Weinstein, Jeremy M. Coethnicity: Diversity and the Dilemmas of Collective Action (The Russell Sage Foundation Series on Trust). Russell Sage Foundation, August 2009.

Habyarimana, James, and Jack, William. Heckle and Chide: Results of a Randomized Road Safety Intervention in Kenya. CGD Working Pa- per, April 2009. http://www.cgdev.org/sites/default/files/ 1421541_file_Habyarimana_Jack_Heckle_FINAL.pdf.

Hansch, Steven; Lillibridge, Scott; Egeland, Grace; Teller, Charles, and Toole, Michael. Lives Lost, Lives Saved: Excess Mortality and the Impact of Health Interventions in the Somalia Emergency. Technical report, Refugee Policy Group, Center for Policy Analysis and Research on Refugee Issues, November 1994.

Heaton, Laura M.; Bouey, Paul D.; Fu, Joe; Stover, John; Fowler, Timothy B.; Lyerla, Rob, and Mahy, Mary. Estimating the Impact of the US President’s Emergency Plan for AIDS Relief on HIV Treatment and Prevention Programmes in Africa. Sexually Transmitted Infections, 91(8):615–620, 2015.

Henderson, Julia J. The Challenge of World-wide Social Conditions. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 1:1–14, 1960.

Hendrix, Cullen S., and Noland, Marcus. Confronting the Curse: The Economics and Geopolotics of Natural Resource Governance. Peterson Institute for International Eco- nomics, 2013.

Herbst, Jeffrey. States and Power in Africa. Princeton University Press, 2000.

Herbst, Jeffrey, and Mills, Greg. The Invisible State. Foreign Policy, June 24, 2013.

Higgins, Christina, and Norton, Bonny. Language and HIV/Aids. Multilingual Matters, 2009.

Hinshaw, Drew, and Tumanjong, Emmanuel. Congo’s President Wins Third Term. Wall Street Journal, March 24, 2016.

Hochschild, Adam. King Leopold’s Ghost: A Story of Greed, Terror, and Heroism in Colonial Africa. Houghton Mifflin Harcourt, 1999.

Hochschild, Adam. In the Heart of Darkness. New York Review of Books, October 2005.

Hostland, Douglas, and Giugale, Marcelo M. Africa’s Macroeconomic Story. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, October 2013. http://www-wds.worldbank. org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2013/10/03/ 000158349_20131003125106/Rendered/PDF/WPS6635.pdf. 362 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Hruby, Aubrey, and Bright, Jake. Why China’s Role in Africa Isn’t as Dominant as You Think. December 2015. https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/monkey-cage/ wp/2015/12/04/why-chinas-role-in-africa-isnt-as-important- as-you-think/.

Hsiang, Solomon M.; Burke, Marshal, and Miguel, Edward. Quantifying the Influence of Climate on Human Conflict. Science, 341(6151):1235367–1235367, 2013.

Hume, Tim; Halasz, Stephanie, and Tanku, Tapang Ivo. U.S. Ambassador Samantha Power’s Motorcade Hits, Kills Boy in Cameroon. April 19, 2016. http://www.cnn.com/ 2016/04/19/africa/cameroon-power-motorcade-death/index.html.

Humphreys, Macartan. What Has Been Learned from the Deworming Replications: A Nonparti- san View. August 2015. http://www.columbia.edu/~mh2245/w/worms.html.

Humphreys, Macartan, and Weinstein, Jeremy M. Demobilization and Reintegration. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 51(4):531–567, 2007.

Humphreys, Macartan, and Weinstein, Jeremy M. Policing Politicians: Citizen Empow- erment and Potlitical Accountability in Uganda—Preliminary Analysis. IGC Work- ing Paper, March 2012. http://www.theigc.org/sites/default/files/ Humphreys%20and%20Weinstein%20March%202013.pdf.

Huntington, Samuel P. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. University of Oklahoma Press, 1991.

Huntington, Samuel P. The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order. Penguin, 1997.

Hussein, Karim; Sumberg, James, and Seddon, David. Increasing Violent Conflict Between Herders and Farmers in Africa: Claims and Evidence. Development Policy Review, 17: 397–418, 1999.

Hyde, Susan D. The Observer Effect in International Politics: Evidence from a Natural Experiment. World Politics, 60(1):37–63, 2007.

Hyde, Susan D. Experimenting in Democracy Promotion: International Observers and the 2004 Presidential Elections in Indonesia. Perspectives on Politics, 8(2):511–527, 2010.

Hyde, Susan D., and Marinov, Nikolay. Which Elections Can Be Lost? Political Analysis, 20 (2):191–201, 2012.

Hyden, Göran. Beyond Ujamaa in Tanzania: Underdevelopment and an Uncaptured Peasantry. University of California Press, 1980.

Ichino, Nahomi, and Schündeln, Matthias. Deterring or Displacing Electoral Irregularities? Spillover Effects of Observers in a Randomized Field Experiment in Ghana. Journal of Politics, 74(1):292–307, 2012. REFERENCES 363

Igue, Mamoud Akanni, and N’Oueni, Raphael Windali. The Politics of Language in Benin. In Fardon, Richard, and Furniss, Graham, editors, African Languages, Development and the State, 55–61. Taylor & Francis, 1994.

Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Fifth Assessment Report: What’s in It for Africa. Technical report, 2014.

IRIN News. Briefing: DDR in eastern DRC—Try, Try Again. IRIN News, March 4, 2014.

Isaacman, Allen F., and Isaacman, Barbara. Mozambique: From Colonialism to Revolution, 1900-1982. Westview Press, 1983.

ISS. Côte d’Ivoire: Which Challenges Remain in the Peacebuilding Process? Technical report, July 2015.

Izama, Melina Platas. The Religious Roots of Inequality in Africa. PhD thesis, Stanford University, June 2016.

Jackman, Robert W. The Predictability of Coups D’etat: A Model with African Data. American Political Science Review, 72(4):1262–1275, 1978.

Jackson, Robert H., and Rosberg, Carl G. Why Africa’s Weak States Persist: The Empirical and the Juridicial in Statehood. World Politics, 35(1):1–24, 1982.

Jensen, Nathan, and Wantchekon, Leonard. Resource Wealth and Political Regimes in Africa. Comparative Political Studies, 37(7):816–841, 2004.

Jerven, Morten. Poor Numbers and What to Do About Them. The Lancet, 383(9917):594–595, 2014.

Jett, Dennis. Lessons Unlearned — Or Why Mozambique’s Successful Peacekeeping Operation Might Not Be Replicated Elsewhere. Journal of Humanitarian Assistance, January 1995.

Jett, Dennis. Why Peacekeeping Fails. Palgrave Macmillan US, 2000.

Johnson, Carol A. Conferences of independent African states. International Organization, 16 (2):426–429, 1962.

Joseph, Richard A. Democracy and Prebendal Politics in Nigeria: The Rise and Fall of the Second Republic. African Studies Series 56, Cambridge University Press, 1987.

Joseph, Richard A. Prebendalism and Dysfunctionality in Nigeria. AFRICAPLUS, July 2013.

Kariuki, Peninah; Abraha, Fitsum, and Obuseng, Sennye. Botswana (OECD Development Centre: African Economic Outlook, 2014). 2014. http: //www.africaneconomicoutlook.org/fileadmin/uploads/aeo/2014/ PDF/CN_Long_EN/Botswana_EN.pdf. 364 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Kasara, Kimuli. Tax Me if You Can: Ethnic Geography, Democracy, and the Taxation of Agriculture in Africa. American Political Science Review, 101(1):159–172, 2007.

Kasfir, Nelson. Are African Peasants Self-Sufficient? Development and Change, 17(2): 335–357, 1986.

Kayirangwa, E.; Hanson, J.; Munyakazi, L., and Kabeja, A. Current Trends in Rwanda’s HIV/AIDS Epidemic. Sexually Transmitted Infections, 82(suppl. 1):i27–i31, 2006.

Keita, Madeira. Le parti unique en Afrique. Présence Africaine, 30:3–24, 1960.

Kennedy, John F. Imperialism—The Enemy of Freedom. July 1957.

Kenyatta, Jomo. Facing Mount Kenya: The Tribal Life of the Gikuyu. Harvill Secker, 1938.

Kishi, Roudabeh, and Raleigh, Clionadh. When China Gives Aid to African Governments, They Become More Violent. Washington Post, December 2, 2015.

Kramon, Eric, and Posner, Daniel N. Who Benefits from Distributive Politics? How the Outcome One Studies Affects the Answer One Gets. Perspectives on Politics, 11(2): 461–474, 2013.

Kron, Josh. As Uganda Votes, Polling Stations Open Hours Late and a Candidate Is Arrested. New York Times, February 19, 2016.

Kudamatsu, Masayuki. Ethnic Favoritism: Micro Evidence from Guinea. PSE Working Papers, 1–32, July 2007.

Kudamatsu, Masayuki. Has Democratization Reduced Infant Mortality in Sub-Saharan Africa? Evidence from Micro Data. Journal of the European Economic Association, 10(6):1294– 1317, 2012.

Kuwali, Dan, and Viljoen, Frans. Africa and the Responsibility to Protect: Article 4(h) of the African Union Constitutive Act. Taylor & Francis, 2013.

Laitin, David D. Politics, Language, and Thought: The Somali Experience. University of Chicago Press, 1977.

Laitin, David D. The Ogaadeen Question and Changes in Somali Identity. State Versus Ethnic Claims: An African Policy Dilemmas, 331–349, 1983.

Laitin, David D. Hegemony and Religious Conflict: British Imperial Control and Political Cleavages in Yorubaland. In Evans, Peter B.; Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, and Skocpol, Theda, editors, Bringing the State Back In. Cambridge University Press, 1986a.

Laitin, David D. Hegemony and Culture: Politics and Change Among the Yoruba. University of Chicago Press, 1986b. REFERENCES 365

Laitin, David D. Language Repertoires and State Construction in Africa. Cambridge University Press, 1992.

Laitin, David D. The Tower of Babel as a Coordination Device: Political Linguistics in Ghana. American Political Science Review, 88(3):622–634, 1994.

Laitin, David D. Somalia: Civil War and International Intervention. In Walter, Barbara F., and Snyder, Jack L., editors, Civil Wars, Insecurity, and Intervention. Columbia University Press, 1999.

Laitin, David D., and Ramachandran, Rajesh. Language Policy and Human Development. American Political Science Review, 110(3):457–480, 2016.

Laitin, David D., and Samatar, Said S. Somalia: Nation in Search of a State. Westview Press, 1987.

Laitin, David D.; Ramachandran, Rajesh, and Walter, S. L. Language of Instruction and Student Learning: Evidence from an Experimental Program in Cameroon. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 2019.

Lawry, Steven; Samii, Cyrus; Hall, Ruth; Leopold, Aaron; Hornby, Donna, and Mtero, Farai. The Impact of Land Property Rights Iinterventions on Investment and Agricultural Productivity in Developing Countries: A Systematic Review. Campbell Systematic Reviews, January 2014.

Lee, Melissa M. The International Politics of Incomplete Sovereignty: How Hostile Neighbors Weaken the State. International Organization, 72(2):283–315, 2018.

Lee, Melissa M., and Izama, Melina Platas. Aid Externalities: Evidence from PEPFAR in Africa. World Development, 67(C):281–294, 2015.

Lefkow, Leslie. Darfur in flames: Atrocities in western Sudan, volume 15. Human Rights Watch, 2004.

Leonard, David K. African Successes: Four Public Managers of Kenyan Rural Development. University of California Press, 1991.

Levely, Ian. Measuring Intermediate Outcomes of Liberia’s DDRR Program. IES Work- ing Paper, 2012. http://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/83399/1/ 684815257.pdf.

Leys, Colin. Underdevelopment in Kenya: The Political Economy of Neo-colonialism, 1964- 1971. University of California Press, 1975.

Lidow, Nicholai H. Violent Order: Understanding Rebel Governance Through Liberia’s Civil War. Cambridge University Press, 2016. 366 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Lieberman, Evan S. Boundaries of Contagion: How Ethnic Politics Have Shaped Government Responses to AIDS. Princeton University Press, 2009.

Likaka, Osumaka. Rural Society and Cotton in Colonial Zaire. University of Wisconsin Press, 1997.

Lo, Nathan C.; Lowe, Anita, and Bendavid, Eran. Abstinence Funding Was Not Associated with Reductions in HIV Risk Behavior in Sub-Saharan Africa. Health Affairs, 35(5): 856–863, 2016.

Londregan, John B., and Poole, Keith T. Poverty, the Coup Trap, and the Seizure of Executive Power. World Politics, 42(2):151–183, 1990.

Lowes, Sara, and Montero, Eduardo. Blood Rubber: The Effects of La- bor Coercion on Institutions and Culture in the DRC. PSE Working Papers, April 2016. http://cega.berkeley.edu/assets/miscellaneous_files/ Lowes_Montero_Paper.pdf.

Lujala, Päivi; Gleditsch, Nils P., and Gilmore, Elisabeth. A Diamond Curse? Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49(4):538–562, 2005.

Lumumba, Patrice. The Truth about a Monstrous Crime of the Colonialists. Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House, 1961. Transcription by Thomas Schmidt. https://www.marxists.org/subject/africa/lumumba/1960/ 06/independence.htm.

Mamdani, Mahmood. When Victims Become Killers: Colonialism, Nativism, and the Genocide in Rwanda. Princeton University Press, 2001.

Mandela, Nelson. The Struggle Is My Life. Popular Prakashan, 1990.

Manning, Patrick. Slavery and African Life: Occidental, Oriental, and African Slave Trades. Cambridge University Press, 1990.

Mathers, Colin D., and Loncar, Dejan. Projections of Global Mortality and Burden of Disease from 2002 to 2030. PLOS Med, 3(11):e442, 2006.

Mazrui, Alamin M., and Mazrui, Ali A. The Power of Babel: Language and Governance in the African Experience. University of Chicago Press, 1998.

Mbemap, Mamouda, and Salhi, Kamal. Franco-Ivorian Discourse and Counter-Discourse Legitimisation and Dissent. In Salhi, Kamal, editor, Francophone Studies: Discourse and Identity, 43–84. Elm Bank, 2000.

McCauley, John F. Africa’s New Big Man Rule? Pentecostalism and Patronage in Ghana. African Affairs, 112(446):1, 2013. REFERENCES 367

McCord, Gordon; Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Woo, Wing Thye. Understanding African Poverty: Beyond the Washington Consensus to the Millennium Development Goals Approach. In Joost, Jan and Akkerman, Age, editors, Africa in the World Economy, 23–45. Forum on Debt and Development (FONDAD), 2005.

McGowan, Pat, and Johnson, Thomas H. African Military Coups d’Etat and Underdevelopment: A Quantitative Historical Analysis. Journal of Modern African Studies, 22(4):633–666, 1984.

Michalopoulos, Stelios. The Origins of Ethnolinguistic Diversity. American Economic Review, 102(4):1508–1539, 2012.

Michalopoulos, Stelios, and Papaioannou, Elias. Divide and Rule or the Rule of the Di- vided? Evidence from Africa. NBER Working Paper, 2011. http://www.nber.org/ papers/w17184.

Michalopoulos, Stelios; Naghavi, Alireza, and Prarolo, Giovanni. Trade and Geography in the Origins and Spread of Islam. NBER Working Paper, October 2012. https://drive. google.com/file/d/0BxWDMJmuSXi1RHpfX0xEOEFMSzg/edit?pref= 2&pli=1&usp=embed_facebook.

Miguel, Edward. Tribe or Nation? Nation Building and Public Goods in Kenya versus Tanzania. World Politics, 56:328–362, 2004.

Miguel, Edward, and Kremer, Michael. Worms: Identifying Impacts on Education and Health in the Presence of Treatment Externalities. Econometrica, 72(1):159–217, 2004.

Minority Rights Group International. The Chaos in Darfur. International Crisis Group, Briefing, no. 110, April 2015.

Mistry, Percy S. Reasons for Sub-Saharan Africa’s Development Deficit That the Commission for Africa Did Not Consider. African Affairs, 104(417):665–678, 2005.

Mitchell, Robert C.; Morrison, Donald G., and Paden, John N. Black Africa: A Comparative Handbook. Springer, 1989.

Mkandawire, Thandika. Thinking About Developmental States in Africa. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 25:289–313, 2001.

Monga, Célestin. Post-Macroeconomics: Reflections on the Crisis and Strategic Directions Ahead. World Bank Policy Research Paper, 2009.

Monga, Célestin, and Lin, Justin Yifu. The Oxford Handbook of Africa and Economics: Policies and Practices. 2 vols. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2015. 368 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

MONUSCO. Strengthening the Rule of Law and Protection of Civilians in the Democratic Republic of the Congo, September 11, 2018. https://monusco.unmissions. org/en/strengthening-rule-law-and-protection-civilians- democratic-republic-congo.

Moore, Gerald, and Beier, Ulli. Modern poetry from Africa. Penguin, 1963.

Morgan, Glenda. Violence in Mozambique: Towards an Understanding of Renamo. Journal of Modern African Studies, 28(4):603–619, 1990.

Moss, Todd; Pettersson, Gunilla, and van de Walle, Nicolas. An Aid-Institutions Paradox? A Review Essay on Aid Dependency and State Building in Sub-Saharan Africa. CGD Working Paper, January 2006.

Munro, William A. Power, Peasants and Political Development: Reconsidering State Construc- tion in Africa. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 38(1):112–148, 1996.

Ndiaye, Mansour. State control and Poor Economic Growth Performance in Senegal. In Ndulu, Benno J.; O’Connell, Stephen A.; Bates, Robert H.; Collier, Paul, and Soludo, Chukwuma C., editors, The Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960-2000, 401–425. Cambridge University Press, 2008.

Ndulu, Benno J., and O’Connell, Stephen A. Policy plus: African Growth Performance, 1960-2000. In Ndulu, Benno J.; O’Connell, Stephen A.; Bates, Robert H.; Collier, Paul, and Soludo, Chukwuma C., editors, The Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960-2000, 3–75. Cambridge University Press, 2008.

Ndulu, Benno J.; O’Connell, Stephen A.; Bates, Robert H.; Collier, Paul, and Soludo, Chuk- wuma C. The Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960-2000. Cambridge University Press, 2008.

Nkrumah, Kwame. The Eleventh Party Congress. July 1962.

Nkrumah, Kwame. Consciencism. NYU Press, 1970.

Nock, Arthur Darby. Conversion: The Old and the New in Religion from Alexander the Great to Augustine of Hippo. Oxford University Press, 1933.

North, Douglass C. Economic Performance Through Time. OxCarre Research Paper, Decem- ber 1993.

North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R. Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England. Journal of Economic History, 49(4):803–832, 1989.

Nugent, Paul. Africa Since Independence: A Comparative History. Palgrave Macmillan, 2004. REFERENCES 369

Nunn, Nathan. The Long-Term Effects of Africa’s Slave Trades. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(1):139–176, 2008.

Nunn, Nathan, and Qian, Nancy. Aiding Conflict: The Impact of US Food Aid on Civil War. American Economic Review, 104(6):1630–1666, 2014.

Nunn, Nathan, and Wantchekon, Leonard. The Slave Trade and the Origins of Mistrust in Africa. American Economic Review, 101(7):3221–3252, 2011.

Nussbaum, Martha C. The Central Capabilities. In Creating Capabilities: The Human Development Approach, 17–45. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 2011.

Nyerere, Julius K. Education for Liberation: President Nyerere’s Speech to the Dag Ham- marskjold Seminar on Education, Dar Es Salaam, May 1974. Institute of Adult Education, 1976.

Olson, Mancur. Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development. American Political Science Review, 87(3):567–576, 1993.

Omondi, George. The New Assault on Presidential Term Limits in Africa: Fo- cus on Burundi. African Leadership Centre, September 2015. http://www. africanleadershipcentre.org/index.php/2014-10-22-15-44-06/ alc - newsletters / sept - 2015 - issue / 385 - the - new - assault - on - presidential-term-limits-in-africa-focus-on-burundi.

Onishi, Norimitsu. Nigeria’s Booming Film Industry Redefines African Life. New York Times, February 18, 2016.

Orogun, Paul Sunday. State Building and State Destruction: A Comparative Study of Five African Kingdoms from the Thirteenth to the Nineteenth Century. PhD thesis, University of California, 1987.

Ploeg, Frederick van der. Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing? Journal of Economic Literature, 49(2):366–420, 2011.

Posner, Daniel N., and Young, Daniel J. Term Limits: Leadership, Political Competition and the Transfer of Power. In Cheeseman, Nic, editor, Institutions and Democracy in Africa: How the Rules of the Game Shape Political Developments, 260–278. Cambridge University Press, 2018.

Powell, Jonathan M. Determinants of the Attempting and Outcome of Coups D’état. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 56(6):1017–1040, 2012.

Powell, Jonthan M., and Thyne, Clayton L. Global Instances of Coups from 1950 to 2010: A New Dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 48(2):249–259, 2011. 370 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Price, Robert M. Society and Bureaucracy in Contemporary Ghana. University of California Press, 1975.

Prunier, Gérard. The Rwanda Crisis: History of a Genocide. Columbia University Press, 1995.

Przeworski, Adam. Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge University Press, 1991.

Putnam, Robert D. E Pluribus Unum: Diversity and Community in the Twenty-First Century the 2006 Johan Skytte Prize Lecture. Scandinavian Political Studies, 30(2):137–174, 2007.

Qian, Nancy. Making Progress on Foreign Aid. Annual Review of Economics, 7(1):277–308, 2015.

Radelet, Steven C. Emerging Africa: How 17 Countries Are Leading the Way. Center for Global Development, 2010.

Raleigh, Clionadh; Linke, Andrew, and Dowd, Caitriona. Armed Conflict Location and Event Data Project (ACLED) Codebook 3. 1–19, January 2014.

Ranger, Terence O. Godly Medicine: The Ambiguities of Medical Mission in Southeast Tanzania, 1900-1945. Social Science & Medicine. Part B: Medical Anthropology, 15(3): 261–277, 1981.

Reid, Richard J. Warfare in African History. Cambridge University Press, 2012.

Reno, William. Corruption and State Politics in Sierra Leone. Cambridge University Press, 1995.

Reno, William. Warlord Politics and African States. Lynne Rienner, 1999.

Reno, William. Warfare in Independent Africa. Cambridge University Press, 2011.

Riddell, Roger. The Future of the Manufacturing Sector in Sub-Saharan Africa. Hemmed in: Responses to Africa’s Economic Decline. Columbia University, 215–247, 1993.

Robertson, Charles. The Fastest Billion: The Story Behind Africa’s Economic Revolution. BookBaby, 2012.

Robinson, Pearl T. The National Conference Phenomenon in Francophone Africa. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 36(3):575–610, 1994.

Robinson, Ronald Edward, and Gallagher, John. Africa and the Victorians: The Official Mind of Imperialism. Macmillan, 1966.

Rodrik, Dani. Globalization, Social Conflict, and Economic Growth. Prebish Lecture at UNCTAD, December 1997. REFERENCES 371

Rodrik, Dani. Goodbye Washington Consensus, Hello Washington Confusion? A Review of the World Bank’s “Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform ”. Journal of Economic Literature, 44(4):973–987, 2006.

Rodrik, Dani. The Manufacturing Imperative. Al Jazeera, August 10, 2011.

Rodrik, Dani. An African Growth Miracle? Journal of African Economies, 27(1):10–27, 2016a.

Rodrik, Dani. Premature Deindustrialization. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(1):1–33, 2016b.

Roessler, Philip. Ethnic Politics and State Power in Africa. Cambridge University Press, 2016.

Ross, Aaron, and Nyemba, Benoit. Congo Police Kill at Least Four in Raid on Separatist Cult. Reuters, February 14, 2017.

Ross, Michael L. The Oil Curse: How Petroleum Wealth Shapes the Development of Nations. Princeton University Press, 2012.

Ross, Michael L. What Have We Learned about the Resource Curse? Annual Review of Political Science, 18(1):239–259, 2015.

Rostow, Walt W. The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge University Press, 1991.

Rotberg, Robert I. Failed States in a World of Terror. Foreign Affairs, 127–140, July/August 2002.

Ruble, Kayla. Gambians Push for Change With Unprecedented Protests Ahead of Presi- dential Elections. VICE News, April 2016. https://news.vice.com/article/ gambians-push-for-change-with-unprecedented-protests-ahead- of-presidential-elections.

Sachs, Jeffrey D. The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities for Our Time. Penguin, 2006.

Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Warner, Andrew M. Economic Convergence and Economic Policies. NBER Working Paper, February 1995. http://www.nber.org/papers/w5039. pdf.

Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Warner, Andrew M. Natural Resources and Economic Development. European Economic Review, 45(4-6):827–838, 2001.

Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, and Subramanian, Arvind. Addressing the Natural Resource Curse: Al Illustation from Nigeria. NBER Working Paper, June 2003. http://www.nber.org/ papers/w9804.

Salehyan, Idean, and Linebarger, Christopher. Elections and Social Conflict in Africa. CCAPS Research Brief, 1–8, February 2013. 372 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Samoff, Joel. Populist Initiatives and Local Government in Tanzania. Journal of Developing Areas, 24(1):1–18, October 1989.

Saro-Wiwa, Ken. Sozaboy: A Novel in Rotten English. Longman, 1994.

Schraeder, Peter J. Understanding the “Third Wave” of democratization in Africa. Journal of Politics, 57(4):1160–1168, 1995.

Scott, James C. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed. Yale University Press, 1999.

Scott, James C. Against the Grain: A Deep History of the Earliest States. Yale University Press, 2017.

Sen, Amartya. Development as Freedom. Oxford University Press, 2001.

Senghor, Léopold S. Nation et voie africaine du socialisme. Présence Africaine, 1961.

Sengupta, Somini. In South Sudan, Mass Killings, Rapes and the Limits of U.S. Diplomacy. New York Times, January 18, 2017.

Sigmund, Paul E. The Ideologies of the Developing Nations. Praeger, 1963.

Smith, Daniel Jordan. A Culture of Corruption: Everyday Deception and Popular Discontent in Nigeria. Princeton University Press, 2010.

Soyinka, Wole. Aké: The Years of Childhood. Arrow, 1983.

Spiro, Herbert J. New Constitutional Forms in Africa. World Politics, 13(1):69–76, 1960.

Stasavage, David. Democracy and Education Spending in Africa. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2):343–358, 2005.

Stearns, Jason; Verweijen, Judith, and Baaz, Maria Eriksson. The National Army and Armed Groups in the Eastern Congo: Untangling the Gordian Knot of Insecurity. Rift Valley Institute Usalama Project, 1–96, October 2013.

Steinberg, Jonny. Midlands. Jonathan Ball Publishers, 2002.

Steinberg, Jonny. A Man of Good Hope. Knopf Doubleday, 2015.

Stone, Randall W. The Political Economy of IMF Lending in Africa. American Political Science Review, 98(4):577–591, 2004.

Straus, Scott. Wars Do End! Changing Patterns of Political Violence in Sub-Saharan Africa. African Affairs, 111(443):179–201, 2012.

The Economist Data Team. Death on the Roads. Economist, October 2015. https://www. economist.com/graphic-detail/2015/10/22/death-on-the-roads. REFERENCES 373

The PRS Group. International Country Risk Guide Methodology, 1–17, 2011.

The Tablet. The Sandhurst Way in Africa. The Tablet, page 3, January 1972.

The World Bank. Africa’s Pulse. Technical report, April 2014.

Thiong’o, Ngugi wa. A Grain of Wheat. Pearson Education, 1967.

Thiong’o, Ngugi wa. Murogi˜ wa Kagogo. East African Educational Publishers, 2004.

Thomas, Noel. Coffee Smuggling in Kagera Region. The Citizen, November 30, 2014.

Thurston, Alex. “The Disease is Unbelief”: Boko Haram’s Religious and Political Worldview. The Brookings Project on U.S. Relations with the Islamic World, January 2016.

Tignor, Robert L. W. Arthur Lewis and the Birth of Development Economics. Princeton University Press, 2006.

Tilly, Charles. Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 990-1990. Wiley-Blackwell, 1990.

Timeline of the SARS outbreak. Technical report, 2016. https://en.wikipedia.org/ wiki/Timeline_of_the_SARS_outbreak, downloaded October 23, 2018.

Touré, Ahmed Sékou. Afrika and Imperialism. Jihad Pub. Co., 1973.

Translators without Borders. Translators without Borders Releases Impact Study on Ebola Information. translatorswithoutborders.org, July 2015.

Tsai, Lily; Blair, Robert, and Morse, Benjamin. Patterns of Trust and Compliance in the Fight Against Ebola: Results from a Population-Based Survey of Monrovia, Liberia . IGC Economic Impacts of Ebola Bulletin, April 2015.

Tsassa, Célestin, and Yamb, Benjamin. Croissance off-shore au Congo et économie rentière. In Ndulu, Benno J.; O’Connell, Stephen A.; Bates, Robert H.; Collier, Paul, and Soludo, Chukwuma C., editors, The Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960-2000, 197–236. Cambridge University Press, 2008.

UNAIDS. AIDS by the Numbers 2015. 2015.

Underwood, Carol; Serlemitsos, Elizabeth, and Macwangi, Mubiana. Health Communication in Multilingual Contexts: A Study of Reading Preferences, Practices, and Proficiencies Among Literate Adults in Zambia. Journal of Health Communication, 12(4):317–337, 2007.

United Nations Department of Peacekeeping Operations. MONUSCO Background. https: //peacekeeping.un.org/mission/past/monuc/background.shtml, n.d. 374 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

United Nations Department of Peacekeeping Operations. DDR in Peace Operations: A Retrospective. Technical report, September 2010.

UWEZO. Are Our Children Learning? Literacy and Numeracy Across East Africa. Technical report, 2014.

Vail, Leroy. The Creation of Tribalism in Southern Africa. University of California Press, 1989.

Vail, Leroy, and White, Landeg. Tribalism in the Political History of Malawi. In The Creation of Tribalism in Southern Africa, 151–192. University of California Press, 1989. van de Walle, Nicolas. The Politics of Nonreform in Cameroon. In Callaghy, Thomas M., and Ravenhill, John, editors, Hemmed in Responses to Africa’s Economic Decline, 357–397. Columbia University Press, 1993. van de Walle, Nicolas. African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979-1999. Cambridge University Press, 2001.

Vansina, Jan. The Children of Woot: A History of the Kuba Peoples. University of Wisconsin Press, 1978.

Voegele, Juergen. A More Accurate Pulse on Sustainability. World Bank, June 2013. http:// www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2013/06/05/accurate-pulse- sustainability.

Vreeland, James Raymond, and Dreher, Axel. The Political Economy of the United Nations Security Council: Money and Influence. Cambridge University Press, 2014.

Wallerstein, Immanuel Maurice. Africa: The Politics of Unity: An Analysis of a Contemporary Social Movement. Random House, 1967.

Walter, Barbara F. The Critical Carrier to Civil War Settlement. International Organization, 51(3):335–364, 1997.

Waterbury, John. The Long Gestation and Brief Triumph of Import-Substituting Industrializa- tion. World Development, 27(2):323–341, 1999.

Weber, Max; Gerth, Hans Heinrich, and Mills, Charles Wright. From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology. Translated, Edited, and with an Introd. by HH Gerth and C. Wright Mills. Oxford University Press, 1946.

Weinstein, Brian. The Civic Tongue: Political Consequences of Language Choices. Longman, 1982.

Weinstein, Jeremy M. Autonomous Recovery and International Intervention in Comparative Perspective. SSRN Electronic Journal, 2005. REFERENCES 375

Weinstein, Jeremy M. Inside Rebellion: The Politics of Insurgent Violence. Cambridge University Press, 2007.

Woodberry, Robert D. The Missionary Roots of Liberal Democracy. American Political Science Review, 106(2):244–274, 2012.

World Health Organization. Road Traffic Deaths — Data by Country. Global Health Observa- tory Data Repository, 2014.

Yanagizawa-Drott, David. Propaganda and Conflict: Evidence from the Rwandan Genocide. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(4):1947–1994, 2014.

Young, Crawford. Politics in Congo: Decolonization and Independence. Princeton University Press, 1965.

Young, Crawford. Ideology and Development in Africa. Yale University Press, 1982.

Young, Crawford. The African Colonial State in Comparative Perspective. Yale University Press, 1994.

Young, Crawford. The Postcolonial State in Africa: Fifty Years of Independence, 1960–2010. University of Wisconsin Press, 2012.

Zegeye, Abebe, and Ishemo, Shubi. Forced Labour and Migration: Patterns of Movement Within Africa. Hans Zell, 1989.

Zolberg, Aristide R. Creating Political Order: The Party-States of West Africa. University of Chicago Press, 1966.

Zolberg, Aristide R. Moments of Madness. Politics & Society, 2(2):183–207, 1972.

18. Index of Authors

Abernethy, D. B. 160, 199 Baaz, M. E. 339 Abraha, F. 300 Banerjee, A. 310, 311 Acemoglu, D. 5, 127, 128, 132, 134–137, Barbag-Stoll, A. 218 155, 301, 311, 312, 315 Basset, T. J. 146 Adedeji, J. L. 279 Bates, R. H. 249, 299, 305 Adichie, C. N. 98 Beier, U. 206 Adida, C. L. 157 Bekoe, D. A. 90 Afigbo, A. E. 56 Bendavid, E. 45 Ake, C. 262, 294 Bender, G. J. 133 Albaugh, E. A. 207 Benn, M. 292 Albouy, D. Y. 132 Berg, E. J. 242, 243, 245 Alden, C. 328, 329 Berman, B. J. 144 Alesina, A. 125, 168, 169 Bernal, V. 146 Allen, C. 63 Bienen, H. 51, 52 Annan, J. 340 Blair, R. 46 Annan, K. 324 Blattman, C. 340 Appiah, K. A. 226 Block, S. A. 305 Apter, D. E. 58 Bloom, D. E. 126 Arriola, L. R. 287 Bold, T. 311 Asiwaju, A. I. 165 Boone, C. 90, 130 Asunka, J. 281 Bouey, P. D. 44 Autesserre, S. 338 Bourdieu, P. 221 Awolowo, C. O. 27 Boutros-Ghali, B. 323 Azikiwe, N. 27 Bowen, S. 210 Bratton, M. 49, 273 378 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Brierley, S. 281 Dreher, A. 71, 262, 304 Bright, J. 303, 304 Dube, O. 45 Brooks, A. 62 Dubois, W. E. B 226 Brooks, M. L. 251 Duflo, E. 310, 311 Bruton, H. J. 261 Dunning, T. 262 Burgess, R. 305 Dupas, P. 311 Burke, M. 115, 318 East, R. 64 Callaghy, T. M. 83, 187, 251, 257, 258 Easterly, W. 1, 8, 125, 131, 168, 169, 253, Callen, M. 281 254, 257, 260, 261 Campante, F. 156 Eboussi Boulaga, F. 273 Cederman, L.-E. 76 Egeland, G. 331 Chanock, M. 149 Ekeh, P. P. 200, 347 Chingono, M. F. 327 Ellis, S. 104 Chin’ono, H. 293 Emerson, R. 15 Christensen, D. 45, 128, 149, 301 Engerman, S. L. 132 Christensen, t. 249 Englebert, P. 183 Clark, J. 128 Enikolopov, R. 281 Clemens, M. A. 260 Ensminger, J. 148, 150 Cohen, J. 311 Evans-Pritchard, E. E. 196 Collier, P. 7, 77, 115, 128, 263, 299 Everett, G. 309 Cooper, F. 143–145 Couttenier, M. 115 Fall, A. 176 Crabb, C. V. M. 227 Faris, S. 89 Fearon, J. D. 84, 86, 97, 111, 171, 182, 184, Dale, R. 246 236, 237, 317, 319, 320, 335 Davidson, B. 137 Fengler, W. 37, 212 Dell, M. 126, 148 Ferguson, C. A. 219 Demombynes, G. 260 Finnegan, W. 327, 328 Dercon, S. 91 First, R. 54 Devarajan, S. 37, 212 Foccart, J. 273 de Waal, A. 72, 74, 89, 273, 288, 347 Forson, B. 219 Diamond, L. 269, 294 Fortna, V. P. 325 Dowd, C. 88 Fosu, A. K. 259 Doyle, M. W. 321, 324, 325, 332, 333 Fowler, T. B. 44 INDEX OF AUTHORS 379

Franck, R. 75 Hartman, A. C. 149 Fu, J. 44 Haushofer, J. 45 Fuchs, A. 304 Heaton, L. M. 44 Henderson, J. J. 33 Gallagher, J. 166, 189, 192 Hendrix, C. S. 304 Gebreeyesus, M. 307, 313 Herbst, J. 115, 118, 124, 130, 134, 143, 173, Geertz, C. 57 301 Gennaioli, N. 141 Higgins, C. 210 Gerschenkron, A. 314 Hinshaw, D. 292 Gerth, H. H. 69 Hochschild, A. 135, 136, 160 Gettleman, J. 293 Hodler, R. 304 Gilligan, M. J. 340 Hoeffler, A. 128 Gilmore, E. 128 Hornby, D. 148 Girod, D. 103 Hostland, D. 298 Giugale, M. M. 298 Houngbedji, K. 148 Glaeser, E. L. 132, 312 Hruby, A. 303, 304 Gleditsch, N. P. 128 Hsiang, S. M. 115, 318 Goldberg, N. 311 Hume, T. 39 Golden, M. 281 Hummel, R. 183 Goldstein, M. 148 Humphreys, M. 39, 78, 79, 217, 340 Gollin, D. 143 Huntington, S. P. 161, 269 Good, C. M. 159, 160 Hussein, K. 90 Grundy, K. W. 54 Hyde, S. D. 77, 281 Guiso, L. 155, 156 Hyden, G. 247, 248 Gunning, J. W. 7, 115, 122, 263 Gunther, J. 18 Ichino, N. 281 Gutiérrez-Romero, R. 91 Igue, M. A. 63 Isaacman, A. F. 327 Haber, S. 128 Isaacman, B. 327 Habyarimana, J. 217 Ishemo, S. 145, 147 Habyarimana, p. 39 Izama, M. P. 45, 162 Halasz, S. 39 Hall, R. 148 Jack, W. 39 Hansch, S. 331 Jackman, R. W. 55 Hanson, J. 43, 44 Jackson, R. H. 225 380 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Jedwab, R. 143, 305 Lee, M. M. 45, 124 Jensen, N. 128 Lefkow, L. 89 Jerven, M. 111 Leonard, D. K. 245, 246 Jett, D. 328–330 Leopold, A. 148 Johnson, C. A. 227 Levely, I. 340 Johnson, S. 5, 127, 128, 132, 155, 301, 312, Levine, R. 8, 125 315 Leys, C. 248, 249 Johnson, T. H. 55 Lidow, N. H. 105 Jones, B. F. 126 Lieberman, E. S. 40, 42, 43 Joseph, R. A. 69, 70 Likaka, O. 146 Lillibridge, S. 331 Kabeja, A. 43, 44 Lin, J. Y. 313 Kariuki, P. 300 Linebarger, C. 90 Karlan, D. 311 Linke, A. 88 Kasara, K. 75 Lo, N. C. 45 Kasfir, N. 247 Loncar, D. 39 Kayirangwa, E. 43, 44 Londregan, J. B. 55 Keita, M. 51 Long, J. D. 281 Kennedy, J. F. 15 Lonsdale, J. M. 144 Kimenyi, M. 311 Lopez-de Silanes, F. 132, 312 Kishi, R. 304 Lowe, A. 45 Kondylis, F. 148 Lowes, S. 147 Korovkin, V. 281 Lujala, P. 128 Kramon, E. 75, 281 Lumumba, P. 26 Kremer, M. 39 Lyerla, R. 44 Kron, J. 285 Kudamatsu, M. 75, 304 Kuwali, D. 342 Macwangi, M. 210 Mahy, M. 44 Mamdani, M. 198 La Ferrara, E. 125 Mandela, N. 16 La Porta, R. 132, 312 Manning, P. 142, 143 Laitin, D. D. 84, 86, 111, 157, 171, 181, 190, 198, 208, 209, 213, 214, 216, 220–222, Marinov, N. 77 236, 237, 317, 319, 320, 330, 335 Mathers, C. D. 39 Lawry, S. 148 Matuszeski, J. 168, 169 INDEX OF AUTHORS 381

Mazrui, A. A. 220 Nock, A. D. 158 Mazrui, A. M. 220 Noland, M. 304 Mbemap, M. 246 North, D. C. 131, 155 McCauley, J. F. 164 Norton, B. 210 McCord, G. 259 N’Oueni, R. W. 63 McGowan, P. 55 Nugent, P. 273 Menaldo, V. 128 Nunn, N. 138, 141, 142, 262, 301 Michalopoulos, S. 124, 156, 167, 170, 171 Nussbaum, M. C. 35 Miguel, E. 39, 115, 217, 305, 318 Nyemba, B. 293 Mills, C. W. 69 Nyerere, J. K. 185 Mills, G. 134 Min, B. 76 Obuseng, S. 300 Mistry, P. S. 260 O’Connell, S. A. 9, 299 Mitchell, R. C. 16 Ofosu, G. 281 Mkandawire, T. 7 Olken, B. A. 126 Monga, C. 312, 313 Olson, M. 192 Montero, E. 147 Omondi, G. 284 Moore, G. 206 Onishi, N. 219, 293 Morgan, G. 327, 328 Orogun, P. S. 188 Morjaria, A. 305 Osei, R. 311 Morrison, D. G. 16 O’Sullivan, M. 148 Morse, B. 46 Paden, J. N. 16 Moss, T. 262 Padró i Miquel, G. 305 Mtero, F. 148 Papaioannou, E. 167, 170, 171 Munro, W. A. 148 Parienté, W. 311 Munyakazi, L. 43, 44 Parks, B. C. 304 Mvukiyehe, E. N. 340 Petrova, M. 281 Mwabu, G. 311 Pettersson, G. 262 Ploeg, F. v. d. 127 Naghavi, A. 156 Poole, K. T. 55 Ndiaye, M. 255, 258 Posner, D. N. 75, 217, 286 Ndulu, B. J. 9, 299 Powell, J. M. 55 Ng’ang’a, A. 311 Prarolo, G. 156 Nkrumah, K. 18, 52 Price, R. M. 246 382 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Prunier, G. 333 Samatar, S. S. 181 Przeworski, A. 287 Sambanis, N. 321, 324, 325, 332, 333 Putnam, R. D. 125 Samii, C. 148, 149, 340 Samoff, J. 247 Qian, N. 261, 262 Sandefur, J. 311 Sapienza, P. 155, 156 Radelet, S. C. 267 Saro-Wiwa, K. 219 Rainer, I. 75, 141 Schneider, F. 71 Raleigh, C. 88, 304 Schraeder, P. J. 269, 294 Ramachandran, R. 208, 209, 213, 221 Schündeln, M. 281 Ranger, T. O. 160 Scott, J. C. 221, 247 Raschky, P. A. 304 Seddon, D. 90 Ravenhill, J. 258 Selod, H. 148 Reid, R. J. 187, 190, 192 Sen, A. 35 Reno, W. 70–72, 94, 96, 104, 249 Senghor, L. S. 51 Riddell, R. 306 Sengupta, S. 324 Robertson, C. 8 Serlemitsos, E. 210 Robinson, J. A. 5, 127, 128, 132, 134–137, Shapiro, J. 311 155, 301, 312, 315 Shleifer, A. 132, 312 Robinson, P. T. 273 Siddiqi, B. 45 Robinson, R. E. 166, 189, 192 Sigmund, P. E. 51 Rodrik, D. 255, 256, 258, 297, 298, 302, 305, Smith, D. J. 67, 81 307, 308 Sokoloff, K. L. 132 Roessler, P. 84, 89, 108–110, 123, 235, 344 Soludo, C. C. 299 Rosberg, C. G. 225 Sonin, K. 281 Ross, A. 293 Soubeyran, R. 115 Ross, M. L. 127 Spiro, H. J. 28 Rostow, W. W. 241 Stasavage, D. 305 Rotberg, R. I. 85 Stearns, J. 339 Ruble, K. 293 Steinberg, J. 272 Stone, R. W. 262 Sachs, J. D. 33, 126, 127, 129, 130, 259, 261 Stover, J. 44 Sala-i-Martin, X. 127 Straus, S. 90 Salehyan, I. 90 Subramanian, A. 127 Salhi, K. 246 INDEX OF AUTHORS 383

Sumberg, J. 90 Vollrath, D. 143 Voors, M. 45 Tanku, T. I. 39 Vreeland, J. R. 262 Teller, C. 331 Thiong’o, N. w. 133 Wallerstein, I. M. 230 Thomas, N. 251 Walter, B. F. 320 Thomas, R. 64 Walter, S. L. 213 Thurston, A. 93 Wantchekon, L. 128, 138, 141, 142 Thuysbaert, B. 311 Warner, A. M. 33, 127, 129, 130 Thyne, C. L. 55 Waterbury, J. 254 Tierney, M. 304 Weber, M. 69 Tignor, R. L. 52 Weingast, B. R. 155 Tilly, C. 233 Weinstein, B. 221 Toole, M. 331 Weinstein, J. M. 78, 79, 102, 217, 237, 340 Touré, A. S. 25 White, L. 197 Tsai, L. 46 Wilks, A. 309 Tsassa, C. 209, 258 Wimmer, A. 76 Tumanjong, E. 292 Woo, W. T. 259 Woodberry, R. D. 155, 159, 160 Udry, C. 148, 311 Underwood, C. 210 Yamb, B. 209, 258 Vail, L. 197, 198 Yanagizawa-Drott, D. 121, 156 Valfort, M.-A. 157 Young, C. 1, 2, 64, 165, 187, 197 van de Walle, N. 49, 68, 256–258, 262, 273 Young, D. J. 286 Vansina, J. 222 Verweijen, J. 339 Zakharov, A. 281 Vicente, P. C. 77 Zegeye, A. 145, 147 Viljoen, F. 342 Zingales, L. 155, 156 Voegele, J. 309 Zolberg, A. R. 2, 49, 52, 288, 345

19. General Index

A Ahidjo, Ahmadou, 229, 231 Abacha, Sani, 285 Ahmed, Abiy, 237 Abgal, 107 Aidiid, Maxamed Farraax, 107, 334 Abiola, Moshood, 285 Ajello, Aldo, 330, 331 Acheampong, Ignatius Kutu, 59, 64, 65 Akan, 65, 211, 222, 224 Achebe, Chinua, 155, 158, 165 Akintola, Samuel Ladoke, 58 Acholi, 60, 61 Akuffo, Frederick W. K., 65 Action Group, 27 Akufo-Addo, Nana, 281 ADOL, see Average Distance from al-Bashir, Omar, 109 Official Language al-Qaida, 92, 93 AERC, see African Economic Research al-Shabaab, 108, 264 Consortium Algeria, 14, 15, 54, 62, 95, 231 Afars, 106, 173, 181 All-African Peoples’ Conference, 229 AfDB, see African Development Bank Amadou, Cheiffou, 277 African Development Bank, 264, 314 Amin, Idi, 61, 62, 102, 103, 287 African Economic Research Consortium, ANC, see African National Congress 8, 211, 261, 301 Angola, 32, 33, 37, 38, 70, 95, 97, 115, African National Congress, 42, 96, 274, 136, 141, 163, 232, 236, 237, 286, 329 319, 322, 331, 332, 338, 340 African Peace and Security Architecture, Ankrah, Joseph, 59, 64, 65 344, 345 Annan, Kofi, 92, 106, 325 African Socialism, 207, 243–253, 329 anticolonial Wars, 94–96 African Union, 3, 22, 93, 108, 232, 321, Anya Nya, 180 340, 343–345, 349 apartheid, 15, 42, 71, 95, 96, 100–102, as security guarantor, 343–345 232, 244, 272–274, 328, 330 African Union Mission to Somalia, 108 Arabs, 89, 118, 179 Afrifa, A. A., 64, 65 Arden-Clarke, Charles Noble, 17 Afro-Asian Peoples’ Solidarity , 283 Conference, 229 Arusha Declaration, 20 Aguiyi-Ironsi, Johnson Thomas Ashanti, 65, 94, 193 Umunnakwe, 58, 98, 99, 284 Ashanti Empire, 143, 190 386 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Average Distance from Official Language, Botswana Democratic Party, 303 210, 211 Boutros-Ghali, Boutros, 106, 325, 333 Awolowo, Obafemi, 27, 57, 58, 99 Brazil, 41, 42 as charismatic founder, 27–28 Brazzaville Group, 231 Azawad People’s Movement, 185 Britain, 13, 14, 17, 18, 20, 22, 25, 55, 57, Azikiwe, Nnamdi, 27, 57, 284 58, 60, 61, 94, 95, 99, 102, 107, 139, as charismatic founder, 27–28 146, 148, 151, 157, 167, 169, 177, 179–183, 187, 191, 192, 195–198, B 208, 220, 221, 230, 232–234, 244, Babangida, Ibrahim, 285 247, 273, 278–280, 284, 325, 333 Baganda, 60–62, 193 Buhari, Mohammed, 93, 285, 286 Balewa, Abubakar Tafawa, 57, 58, 284 Bukharin, Nikolai, 252 Banda, Hastings, 245, 279 bula matari, 189, 195 Banda, Joyce, 279 Burke, Edmund, 18 Banyoro, 60, 61 Burkina Faso, 24, 55, 62, 92, 119, 141, Barre, Maxamad Siyaad, 105–107, 184, 147, 208, 259, 286, 288, 289 208, 218, 234, 333 Burundi, 55, 62, 116, 119, 163, 261, 286, BDP, see Botswana Democratic Party 289, 294, 303, 317, 321, 335, 340, Belgium, 25, 26, 137, 138, 148, 167, 168, 342, 345 174–176, 195–197, 199, 201, 230, Bush, George H. W., 333 335, 336 Bush, George W., 44 Belkiri, Alain, 248 Busia, Kofi, 39, 64 Bello, Sir Ahmadu, 58 Beni, 45 C Benin, 55, 62–64, 75, 99, 119, 150, 170, Côte d’Ivoire, 52, 59, 90, 92, 105, 190, 193, 275–278, 294, 296 146–148, 163, 196, 231, 245, 246, coups in, 63–64 248, 253, 282, 299, 308, 326, 340, Benin Empire, 190 341, 343, 345 Berlin Conference, 167–171, 173–177, Cameroon, 39, 92, 214, 225, 229, 231, 181, 182, 184–187, 234 259, 260, 286, 308 effects on development, 170–174 Cape Verde, 67, 294 Besigye, Kizza, 287 Casablanca Group, 231 Biafra, 97–99, 173, 185, 239, 284 Casamance, 130, 173, 177–179, 185 Biya, Paul, 259, 286 Catholic, 17, 20, 23, 25, 60, 65, 156–161, Black Hawk Down, 334 165, 177, 254 Boko Haram, 92, 93, 239 CDC, see Centers for Disease Control and Bongo, Omar, 278, 286, 289 Prevention Bosnia, 323 Centers for Disease Control and Botswana, 4, 31, 40, 67, 78, 119, 128, Prevention, 46 133, 136, 141, 164, 245, 248, 289, Central African Federation, 230, 278 294, 302–304, 308, 311, 316, 329 Central African Republic, 119, 293, 294, economic miracle in, 302–305 317, 326, 340 GENERAL INDEX 387

Chad, 84, 85, 92, 102, 117, 237, 264, 286, Congo, Republic of, 55, 116, 119, 128, 338 136, 211, 286, 294 charisma, 13–29, 49, 66 Congress Party (India), 13 Chewa, 170 Convention People’s Party, 17, 51, 52 Chiluba, Frederick, 279, 282, 283 corruption, 6, 46, 52, 55, 61, 63, 66–74, China, 32, 33, 37, 38, 46, 297, 299, 300, 78, 80, 81, 101, 128, 202, 254, 281, 305, 306, 325, 328 284, 294, 304, 349 Chirac, Jacques, 275 corvée, see forced labor Chissano, Joaquim, 331 coup proofing, 109–111 coups d’état, 49, 52–55, 58, 62, 63, 74, 83, civil wars, 71, 83, 84, 86, 87, 93, 94, 96, 108, 109, 124, 225, 280, 281, 284, 97, 100, 101, 106, 108, 109, 111, 346 121, 123, 124, 126, 136, 173–174, CPP, see Convention People’s Party 179, 181, 185, 191, 196, 225, 236–241, 284, 294, 319–323, 327, 328, 330, 332, 333, 335, 336, 340, D 342, 343, 346, 350 Dahomey, see Benin termination of, 321–322 Dahomey Empire, 143, 190 climate change, 320 Danquah, J. B., 17, 50 Darfur, 72, 88, 89, 109, 264, 326, 345 Clinton, Bill, 334, 335 war in, 88–89 Cold War, 25, 102, 106, 229, 237, Darood, 106 263–265, 267, 279, 321, 322, 324, DDR, see disarmament, demobilization 325, 327, 330, 346, 350 and reintegration Common Man’s Charter, 61 democracy, 2, 3, 6, 9, 31, 51–53, 55, 59, Commonwealth of Independent States, 64, 66, 78, 81, 91, 93, 104, 157, 160, 323 162, 163, 165, 166, 271–273, Comoros, 34, 53, 62, 294, 345 275–281, 284, 286, 289, 290, 293, Compaoré, Blaise, 289 296, 297, 307, 316, 338, 348, 350 Congo (Kinshasa), see Congo, Africa’s lag in, 49–81 Democratic Republic of the Democratic Alliance, 42, 274 Congo Free State, 26, 137, 162, 168, 228 Democratic Forces for the Liberation of Congo, Democratic Republic of the, Rwanda, 339 25–27, 45, 53, 62, 69, 71, 88, 97, Democratic Party (Uganda), 60 101, 105, 116, 119, 135, 136, 149, demography, 121 163, 185, 208, 220, 224, 236, 237, Denmark, 139 264, 276, 286, 288, 295, 299, 319, Dhlakama, Alfonso, 331 321, 323, 324, 326, 337–341, 345 difficult political geography, 115–117 as difficult political geography, diglossia, 221 116–117 Dinka, 198, 239 institutionalized brutality in, 135–138 Diouf, Abdou, 276 Katanga secession in, 174–177 disarmament, demobilization, and PKO in, 337–340 reintegration, 340–343, 346 388 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Djibouti, 72, 106, 170, 181, 182, 233, 345 Entente Cordiale, 169 Doe, Samuel, 62, 70, 71, 104, 105, 251 Equatorial Guinea, 119, 286, 300 Dos Santos, José Eduardo, 70 Eritrea, 72, 119, 182, 183, 237, 308, 346 DRC, see Congo, Democratic Republic of Ethiopia, 44, 72, 101, 102, 104, 106, 116, the 119, 141, 163, 169, 170, 181–184, Dubai, 314 192, 231, 233–237, 299, 308, 313, Dubois, W. E. B., 228 315, 316, 321, 332, 333, 345 ethnic diversity, 124–127 E ethnic power sharing, 76–77 Ebola, 45–47, 212, 300 ethnolinguistic fractionalization, 124–127, ECOMOG, see Economic Community of 199, 226 West African States Monitoring Evans-Pritchard, E. E., 198 Group Ewe, 65 Economic Community of West African Eyadéma, Gnassingbé, 54, 278, 286, 344 States, 321, 336, 344, 345 Economic Community of West African F States Monitoring Group, 71, 336, Fabian Society, 244 337 favorable political geography, 119 Economic Orthodoxies forced labor, 137, 145–150, 195 African Socialism, 244–253 Forces Armées de la République financing gap, 253–256 Démocratique du Congo, 339 foreign aid, 263–265 foreign aid, 15, 36, 44, 180, 214, 245, import substitution industrialization, 254–256, 263–265, 267, 291, 306, 253–254, 256–258 308 Millennium Project, 261–263 France, 13, 14, 23–25, 51, 54, 95, 106, new structural economics, 314–317 138, 139, 146, 148, 167, 169, 177, policy experimentation, 312–313 178, 181, 182, 193, 195–197, 209, Washington Consensus, 254–255, 211, 214, 216, 220, 221, 224, 225, 258–261, 267, 308, 314, 316 228, 229, 231, 245, 248, 260, 272, education, 9, 20, 24, 28, 31, 34–36, 38, 275–278, 294, 325, 330, 336, 340, 41, 43, 48, 57, 72, 75, 76, 92, 98, 345 128, 134, 143, 149, 157, 160–162, FRELIMO, see Mozambique Liberation 165, 196, 203, 208, 209, 211, 213, Front 214, 217, 220, 224, 249, 250, 255, French Community, 25, 229–231 261, 263, 307, 317, 346 Africa’s lag in, 34–37 G Egbas, 170 Gabon, 97, 119, 136, 276, 278, 286, 289 Egbe Omo Oduduwa, 27 Gambia, 119, 130, 163, 164, 177, 178, Egypt, 14, 169, 179, 333 288, 293–295, 345 Eisenhower, Dwight D., 14 Garang, John, 101, 102, 104 electoral violence, 57, 88, 90–92 genuine savings, 311–312 ELF, see ethnolinguistic fractionalization geography, 115–131 GENERAL INDEX 389

Georgia, 323 Hutu, 43, 120, 201, 264, 335, 336, 339 Germany, 167, 169, 228, 271, 316, 329 Ghana, 17–19, 50–52, 55, 59, 62–66, 78, I 94, 99, 140, 141, 150, 208, 211, 212, Igbo, 27, 56–58, 98, 99, 155, 165, 173, 229, 230, 245, 248, 253, 259, 266, 185, 220 280, 281, 283, 290, 294, 311, 313 ILO, see International Labour coups in, 58–60, 64–66 Organization Gizenga, Antoine, 177 IMF, see International Monetary Fund see Gold Coast, Ghana import substitution industrialization, Gordon, Sir Charles, 179 253–254, 256–259, 309 Gowon, Yakubu (Jack), 58, 99, 284 income, 31–34, 39, 47, 48, 77, 121, 127, Grunitsky, Nicholas, 54 128, 133, 135, 136, 142, 147, 150, Guèye, Lamine, 50 171, 191, 195, 211, 264, 265, 299, Guatemala, 323 301, 303, 305, 323, 342, 343 Guinea, 24–25, 45, 46, 51, 59, 170, 229, Africa’s lag in, 31–34 230, 246, 247, 290 India, 13, 15, 39, 182, 271, 299, 313, 321 Guinea-Bissau, 95, 105, 179, 232, 293, indirect rule, 8, 56, 151, 195, 200, 202 294 Indonesia, 14, 15, 229, 283, 321 Gunther, John, 18, 19 Inkatha Freedom Party, 42 International Labour Organization, 147 H International Monetary Fund, 73, 253, Habr Gedir, 107, 108 254, 258–260, 264, 292 Habyarimana, Jevénal, 120, 121, 335, 336 irredentism, 173, 181, 233 Hammarskjöld, Dag, 1 Isaaq, 106, 107, 173, 184 Hausa, 27, 56–58, 92, 193 ISI, see import substitution Hausa-Fulani, 98 industrialization Hawiye, 106, 107, 333 Islam, 93, 106, 157, 159, 160, 163, 165, health, 21, 28, 31, 33, 37–48, 57, 72, 183, 193 74–76, 139, 149, 161, 162, 165, 203, effects on development, 163–165 211–213, 224, 226, 250, 261, 302, Islamic Courts Union, 108 306, 307, 348 , 271 Africa’s lag in, 37–47 Issas, 106, 170, 181 heavily indebted poor countries, 254 Issoufou, Mahamadou, 294 hinterland political geography, 117–118 HIV/AIDS, 37, 40–45, 302 Italy, 106, 107, 167, 181–183, 216, 233, 234, 271, 330 Honduras, 313 Hong Kong, 46, 302 Houphouët-Boigny, Félix, 148, 231, 245, J 248 Japan, 271, 314, 316 human development, 31, 47, 48, 135, 207, Johnson, Prince, 104, 105, 284, 289 211 Jonathan, Goodluck, 93, 285 Africa’s lag in, 31–48 Joolas, 130, 159, 178, 185 390 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

K Kuba Kingdom, 224 Kérékou, Mathieu, 62–64, 275, 276 Kabaka Yekka, 60 L Kabila, Joseph, 136, 286, 288, 295 Langi, 60, 61 Kabila, Laurent Désiré, 185, 338 Latitude, 124–127, 157 Kagame, Paul, 42, 43, 101, 102, 104, 105, Leopold II, 26, 135, 137 286, 316, 336 Lesotho, 4, 40, 119, 141, 163, 293, 294, Kakwa, 61, 171, 172 317 KANU, see Kenyan African National Lewis, I. M., 198 Union Lewis, W. Arthur, 52 Kasai, 116, 173, 175, 177 Liberia, 45, 46, 62, 70, 71, 102, 104, 105, Kasavubu, Joseph, 26, 27, 175, 177, 230, 119, 170, 193, 251, 289, 294, 314, 231 326, 340, 342 Katanga, 26, 27, 116, 173–177, 295, 323, Libya, 62, 102, 237, 343 324 Limann, Hilla, 65 Katumbi, Moise, 295 linguistic innovations, 220–221 KAU, see Kenya African Union linguistic relativity hypothesis, 216 Kaunda, Kenneth, 96, 251, 260, 278, 279 Lord Salisbury, 169 Kennedy, John Fitzgerald, 14, 100 Lord’s Resistance Army, 104, 339 Kenya, 8, 21–23, 32, 33, 36, 38, 39, 44, LRA, see Lord’s Resistance Army 60, 70, 75, 78, 90–92, 95, 106, 107, Lubas, 175, 176 148, 181–183, 202, 212, 216, 219, Lugard, Lord Frederick, 56, 98, 200 220, 229, 230, 233, 234, 247, 253, Lumumba, Patrice, 25–27, 29, 175–177, 265, 280, 290, 292–294, 296, 301, 230, 231, 324 308, 311, 332, 345 as charismatic founder, 25–27 Kenya African Union, 22 Lundas, 176 Kenyan African National Union, 23 Kenyatta, Jomo, 21, 22, 60, 247, 248 as charismatic founder, 21–23 M Kenyatta, Uhuru, 91, 292, 293, 296 Machar, Riek, 239 Khama, Seretse, 245, 304 Machel, Somora Moisés, 100, 331 Kibaki, Mwai, 91, 293 Macmillan, Harold, 15, 273 Kiir, Salva, 239 Madagascar, 182 Kikuyu, 21, 22, 91, 95, 209, 210, 247, Maga, Hubert, 63 248, 290, 292, 293 Mahdi, Ali, 107 Kinyarwanda, 119 Majertayn, 107, 108 Kivu Province, 116, 185, 237, 338 Maji Maji rebellion, 95 Kom, 214, 215, 225 Malaria, 37, 126, 129, 303, 306, 313 Kongo Empire, 143, 190 Malawi, 75, 170, 199, 202, 230, 245, 278, Koroma, Ernest Bai, 76, 343, 344 279, 294 Kouandété, Maurice, 63 Malaysia, 46 Kpelle, 170 Mali, 24, 51, 75, 90, 92, 117, 163, 185, GENERAL INDEX 391

208, 230, 233, 276, 278, 294, 326, Mozambique Liberation Front, 97, 100, 345 101, 103, 328–331 Malinowski, Bronisław, 22 Mozambique resistance movement, 97, Mandela, Nelson, 16, 42, 43, 244, 273, 100–102, 329–332 274 Mugabe, Robert, 96, 280, 295, 306 Mandinke, 193 Murdock, George, 170 Mareexaan, 107 Murtala Mohammed, 284 Marx, Karl, 244 Museveni, Yoweri, 42, 101–105, 286–288 Masire, Quett, 304 Mussolini, Benito, 271 Mau Mau, 22, 95, 183 Mutesa I, 193 Mauritania, 117, 118, 163, 231, 344 Mutharika, Peter, 279 as hinterland political geography, Mwanawasa, Levy, 279, 290 117–118 Mauritius, 34, 67, 164, 211, 294 N Mbasogo, Teodoro Obiang Nguema, 286 Négritude, 23, 31, 207, 224 Mbeki, Thabo, 42, 43 Nairay, Guy, 248 Mboya, Tom, 247 Namibia, 40, 67, 95, 116, 163, 232, 286, Menelik II, 169, 182, 234 294, 338 Mengistu, Haile Mariam, 106, 333 Nasser, Gamal Abdel, 14 Mills, John, 281 national conferences, 275–278 missionaries, 155, 161, 162, 165, 200 National Council of Nigeria and the effects on development, 158–162 Cameroon, 28, 284 Mitterrand, François, 275, 277 National Party (South Africa), 273, 274 MNC, see Mouvement National National Rainbow Coalition, 293 Congolais National Resistance Army, 102, 103 Mobutu Sese Seko, 70, 72, 105, 177, 185, Nationalist and Integrationist Front, 339 208, 324, 338 natural resources, 127–129 Moi, Daniel Arap, 103, 209, 290, 292, NCNC, see National Council of Nigeria 293 and the Cameroon Moldova, 323 neocolonial, 196, 207–226 Momoh, Joseph, 70 neopatrimonialism, 68 Mondlane, Eduardo, 100 Netherlands, 129, 139, 157, 273 Morocco, 62, 117, 169, 322 Ngug˜ ˜i wa Thiong’o, 209 Mossi, 147, 208 Ngilu, Charity, 293 Mouvement des Forces Démocratique de Ngoni, 194, 199 Casamance, 179 Nguesso, Denis Sassou, 128 Mouvement National Congolais, 25 Niger, 2, 92, 117, 185, 276, 277, 288, 293, Mozambique, 40, 44, 95–97, 100–102, 294 116, 149, 161, 170, 232, 328–332, Nigeria, 27–29, 32, 33, 37, 38, 45, 46, 339, 340 55–58, 61, 66, 67, 70, 72, 78, 90, 92, civil war in, 100–101 93, 97, 101, 116, 119, 128, 141, 155, PKO in, 328–332 159, 162, 163, 170, 185, 190, 193, 392 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

196, 200, 202, 238, 251, 284, 286, rise and fall of, 190–192 289, 296, 308 civil war in, 97–100 P coups in, 55–58 PAFMECA, see Pan-African Freedom democratic backsliding in, 283–286 Movement of East and Central Nkomo, Joshua, 96, 280 Africa Nkrumah, Kwame, 17, 50–52, 58, 59, Pan-African Congress, 228, 233 208, 244, 245, 253, 266, 280 Pan-African Freedom Movement of East as charismatic founder, 17–19 and Central Africa, 230 Nkurunziza, Pierre, 286, 289 Pan-Africanism, 31, 227, 228, 233 North Atlantic Treaty Organization, 323 Paris Club, 254 Northern People’s Congress, 58 PBM, see political business manager NRA, see National Resistance Army Peacekeeping Operations, 240, 321–340 Ntaryamira, Cyprien, 335 PEPFAR, see President’s Emergency Plan Nuer, 198 for AIDS Relief Nujoma, Sam, 286 Peru, 150, 313 Nyachae, Simeon, 247, 248 Peul, 23, 117, 208 Nyerere, Julius, 19–21, 24, 29, 51, 52, 96, PNDC, see Provisional National Defense 187, 208, 219, 223, 244, 250, 265, Council 266 political business manager, 73, 77, 108, as charismatic founder, 19–21 109, 290, 293 Polity, 53, 197, 272, 279, 281, 296 O Portugal, 95, 100, 101, 136, 139, 149, Oakley, Robert, 334 161, 167, 179, 196, 208, 220, 232, OAU, see Organization of African Unity 271, 304, 328–331, 347 Obasanjo, Olesegun, 284, 285 Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper, 258, Obote, Milton, 60–62, 103, 287 259 Odinga, Raila, 91, 92, 296 prebendalism, 69–70, 74, 75, 80 Ogaadeen, 106, 183, 233–236, 332, 333 President’s Emergency Plan for AIDS Ogoni, 221, 285 Relief, 44–45 Ojukwu, Odumegwu, 99 Protestant, 25, 60, 156–158, 160–162, 165 Olympio, Sylvanus, 53, 54 Provisional National Defense Council, Ondimba, Ali Bondo, 289 281 Operation Turquoise, 336 public goods, 70, 74–76, 80, 124, 125, OPO, see Ovambo People’s Organization 134, 145, 150, 152, 160, 162, 165, Organization of African Unity, 187, 227, 171, 194, 218–220, 225, 226, 282, 232–238, 240, 320, 321, 329, 343, 320, 323 344, 346, 349 Oromos, 173, 233 Q Ousmane, Mahamane, 277 Qaddafi, Muammar, 102 Ovambo People’s Organization, 96 Oyo Empire, 143, 189, 190 R GENERAL INDEX 393

Réunion, 67 Shagari, Shehu, 284, 285 Ramaphosa, Cyril, 274 Shaka, 192–194 Rawlings, Jerry, 62, 65, 66, 78, 259, 281, Sharmarke, Abdirashid Ali, 106 283 Shona, 96, 280, 329 RENAMO, see Mozambique Resistance Shonekan, Ernest, 285 Movement Sierra Leone, 45, 46, 70, 71, 76, 102, 105, Rhodesia, see Zimbabwe 119, 134, 208, 221, 263, 294, 299, RPF, see Rwandan Patriotic Front 300, 336, 337, 340, 341, 343 Ruto, William, 91 PKO in, 336–337 Rwanda, 42–44, 67, 101, 116, 119–121, Singapore, 46, 302, 314 123, 141, 200, 201, 237, 286, 315, Sirleaf, Ellen Johnson, 289 316, 335, 336, 338 Sirte Declaration, 343 as favorable political geography, slavery, 3, 46, 136, 139–145, 147, 152, 119–121 153, 165, 191, 227, 303, 346 PKO in, 335–336 Soglo, Christophe, 63 Rwandan Patriotic Front, 101, 102, 120, Soglo, Nicéphore, 276 336, 337 Sokoto Caliphate, 193 Somali National Movement, 102 S Somali Youth League, 183 Saïbou, Ali, 277 Somalia, 8, 28, 72, 84, 85, 92, 95, 102, SACMEQ, see Southern and Eastern 105–107, 116, 163, 170, 173, Africa Consortium for Monitoring 181–184, 198, 208, 233–236, 239, Educational Quality 264, 321, 332–335, 345 Salafi, 88, 92, 93, 108 irredentism in, 181–184 Salafist attacks, 92–93 PKO in, 108, 332–335 Sall, Macky, 276 test of linguistic relativity hypothesis in, Sankara, Thomas, 62, 208 216–218 Saro-Wiwa, Ken, 221, 285 warlord politics in, 106–108 SARS, 46, 47 South Africa, 15, 40–44, 67, 71, 90, 95, Sassou Nguesso, Denis, 128, 286, 294 96, 102, 164, 230, 232, 236, Savimbi, Jonas, 322, 332 272–275, 281, 294, 296, 308, Selassie, Haile, 183, 231, 233, 234 328–330 Senegal, 23–24, 50, 51, 75, 90, 116–118, addressing HIV/AIDS in, 40–44 159, 163, 177–179, 185, 193, 207, South Korea, 32, 33, 37, 302 233, 260, 276, 277, 294 South Sudan, 102, 104, 179–181, 198, Casamance in, 177–179 239, 311, 326, 346 Senghor, Léopold, 23, 24, 29, 50, 177, South West Africa, see Namibia 207, 208, 244, 276 South West African People’s as charismatic founder, 23–24 Organization, 96 Serer, 23, 159, 177 Southern and Eastern Africa Consortium Seychelles, 34 for Monitoring Educational Quality, shadow state, 70–72, 80 36, 213, 214 394 AFRICAN STATES SINCE INDEPENDENCE

Soviet Union, 25, 27, 87, 176, 184, 229, Touadéra, Faustin Archange, 294 230, 237, 240, 244, 252, 262, 271, Touré, Sékou, 24, 29, 51, 244 283, 323–326, 328, 330 as charismatic founder, 24–25 Spain, 271, 324 True Whig Party, 104 Ssuuna II, 193 Tshombe, Moïshe, 175–177, 324 Stalin, Joseph, 244, 252 Tsvangirai, Morgan, 280, 292 Sudan, 61, 72, 84, 85, 88, 89, 97, 102, Tswana, 303 109, 116, 119, 148, 169, 171, Tuareg, 173, 278 179–181, 198, 340 Tumbuka, 199, 200 South Sudan secession in, 179–181 Tunisia, 62 war in Darfur, 88–89 Turi, Samori, 193 Sudan People’s Liberation Army, 102 Turkana, 90 Suez Canal, 14, 179 Tutsi, 43, 102, 120, 201, 261, 335, 339 Sukarno, 14, 17, 229 Swahili, 20, 208, 210–213, 218, 219, 223, 225 U SWAPO, see South West African People’s Uganda, 36, 42, 44, 55, 60, 61, 70, 79, Organization 101–104, 116, 120, 171, 180, 193, Swaziland, 40, 119, 141 202, 230, 233, 237, 253, 286–288, Switzerland, 314 321, 335, 338, 345 coups in, 60–62 T PKO in, 335 Taiwan, 46, 302 Second Liberation War in, 102–104 Tanganyika, see Tanzania Ugandan People’s Congress, 60 Tanganyikan African National Union, 20, Ukraine, 326 51, 52 UN Operation in the Congo, 324 TANU, see Tanganyikan African National UNESCO, 36 Union UNIDO, see United Nations Industrial Tanzania, 4, 19–21, 36, 51, 95–97, 100, Development Organization 103, 116, 149, 162, 163, 187, 193, Union of Congolese Patriots, 339 202, 208, 219–221, 225, 230, 233, Union Progressiste Sénégalaise, 50 249, 250, 253, 255, 259, 265, 266, United Nations, 1, 39, 40, 73, 80, 81, 105, 280, 335 107, 108, 120, 121, 127, 176, 177, ujamaa villages in, 249, 266 183, 187, 227, 229–232, 234, Taylor, Charles, 70, 71, 90, 105 238–240, 243, 255, 257, 264, 275, Temne, 76 321–328, 330–340, 344–347, 350 Thailand, 8, 124, 265 United Nations Industrial Development Tigrean People’s Liberation Front, 101 Organization, 314 Tippu Tip, 193 United Nations Security Council, 73, 106, Togo, 53, 54, 90, 119, 163, 170, 261, 276, 108, 264, 321, 323–326, 330, 333, 278, 286, 337, 344 335, 337–339, 344, 350 Tolbert, William, 104 United States, 15, 16, 27, 28, 39, 93, 108, GENERAL INDEX 395

127, 211, 229, 233, 238, 239, 244, World Health Organization, 37, 43, 46, 47 264, 294, 301, 324–326, 334 UNSC, see United Nations Security Council Y UPC, see Ugandan People’s Congress Yar-Adua, Shehu, 285 Upper Volta, see Burkina Faso Yoruba, 27, 28, 56–58, 98, 170, 190, 191, Uthman dan Fodio, 193 200, 220, 285

V Z Vietnam, 14, 15, 46, 95, 310, 335 Zaire, see Congo, Democratic Republic of the W Zambia, 40, 75, 96, 97, 170, 230, 251, Wade, Abdoulaye, 276 253, 260, 278, 279, 282, 283, 290, Wahid, Abdel, 72 293, 294, 300, 308 Wamalwa, Michael Kijana, 293 ZANU, see Zimbabwe African National Weber, Max, 16, 49, 69, 70, 136, 156–158 Union West African pilot, 28 Western Somali Liberation Front, 106, ZAPU, see Zimbabwe African People’s 184, 234, 333 Union WHO, see World Health Organization Zenawi, Meles, 101, 104 Williams, Henry Sylvester, 228 Zimbabwe, 40, 78, 90, 95–97, 100, 101, Wine, Bobi, 287 119, 230, 232, 278, 280, 290, 292, Wolof, 23, 177, 178 295, 303, 308, 328, 329, 338, 344 World Bank, 1, 73, 118, 243, 253–255, Zimbabwe African National Union, 96 258–261, 276, 300, 311, 314, 340, Zimbabwe African People’s Union, 96 347 Zuma, Jacob, 42, 274