Anchor Savings Bank, Fsb

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Anchor Savings Bank, Fsb In the United States Court of Federal Claims No. 95-39 C (Filed: March 14, 2008) ANCHOR SAVINGS BANK, FSB, Winstar-Related Case; Plaintiff, Foreseeability; Causation; Measure of Damages; Risk v. Assessment; Lost Profits; Mortgage-Backed Securities; Bank Branches THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, Defendant. Edwin L. Fountain, Jones Day, Washington, D.C., attorney of record for plaintiff, with whom were George T. Manning, C. Thomas Long, Joseph J. Migas, Adrian Wager-Zito, Debra L. Satinoff and Geoffrey S. Irwin. Patrick T. Murphy and Tarek Sawi, United States Department of Justice, Commercial Litigation Branch, Civil Division, Washington, D.C., with whom were Colleen Hanrahan, Brian J. Mizoguchi, John Todor, Ed Sullivan, Richard Evans, Luke Levasseur, Mark Pittman and Delisa Sanchez. OPINION AND ORDER Block, Judge. I. INTRODUCTION This case is one of the last of the Winstar-related progeny facing this court. It involves a series of contracts in which the government promised to allow the plaintiff, Anchor Savings Bank, FSB (“Anchor”) to account for “supervisory goodwill” as a capital asset that would count toward Anchor’s regulatory capital requirement and be amortized over a 25-to-40 year period. The contracts accompanied Anchor’s acquisition in the 1980s of four failing financial institutions, at the behest and under the supervision of federal thrift regulators. The government hoped those “supervisory” acquisitions would prevent its contingent deposit insurance liability from maturing. Following a change in thrift regulatory policy, however, the 1989 Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery and Enforcement Act (“FIRREA”) disallowed substantially all of Anchor’s supervisory goodwill as a capital asset. As a consequence, Anchor immediately became a severely under-capitalized financial institution and was forced to make radical operational changes to avoid being seized and liquidated by its regulators. In a series of earlier opinions, this court concluded that FIRREA breached the government’s supervisory goodwill contracts with Anchor. The issue of damages, alone, remains. Before trial, this court noted that the tales that the parties crafted harken back to Charles Dickens’ A TALE OF TWO CITIES. Anchor portrayed its business and operations in the period leading up to the breach as the proverbial “best of times,” with the bank poised for extraordinary success, but the government countered with a more pessimistic approach, challenging Anchor’s performance as a quintessential “worst of times” in which Anchor was headed towards failure. See Anchor Sav. Bank, FSB v. United States, 59 Fed. Cl. 126, 128 (2003) (summary judgment decision). At the time, the court was in no position to weigh those arguments against one another and decide which version—the best of times, or the worst of times—was more credible. Following an almost month-long trial, it is now more clear what is the real story in play. The extremist arguments proffered by both parties have given way to a truth that lies somewhat in the middle—it was neither the Dickensian “best” of times nor the “worst.” It was, however, a time of remarkable change and innovation in both the savings and loan industry and its progeny, the mortgage-banking industry. Anchor appears to have been one of the institutions most prepared to respond to that change, as its management had deliberately positioned the bank to be a leading player in the evolving mortgage-banking industry. As that industry began to rely more heavily upon thrifts as intermediaries between borrowers and the secondary mortgage market’s capital supply, Anchor was ready to be an industry leader. The abrupt disallowance of most of Anchor’s supervisory goodwill as regulatory capital was a near-fatal blow. It forced Anchor to fundamentally alter its business plan and, in so doing, to sacrifice substantial long-term profits in favor of one-time gains from the sale of assets to prop up the suddenly failing, capital-starved institution. In the aftermath of FIRREA, Anchor’s management was forced to operate the business in a defensive posture that could best be described as triage, with a singular focus on preventing the thrift from falling into receivership and maintaining a stripped- down platform from which a profitable enterprise might someday re-emerge, like a phoenix from its ashes. After the breach, Anchor shrank by more than $1 billion in assets in just two years. It sold geographically diverse branch deposits in a depressed market and abandoned a twenty-year-old plan of geographic expansion and diversification. Anchor also sold a profitable subsidiary that was the leading private player in the secondary mortgage market. This subsidiary was poised for explosive, long-term growth precisely when Anchor was forced to sell it. Indeed, in just the first two years after Anchor sold its subsidiary, the subsidiary earned pre-tax income nearly equaling the entire forced- sale price; in only three years, its after-tax, net income exceeded the sale price. See PX 971 (demonstrative summarizing RFC financials, PX 258–265). On January 13, 1995, Anchor sued the United States for breach of contract, alleging that the provisions of FIRREA and its implementing regulations that disallowed the inclusion of supervisory goodwill as regulatory capital contradicted the terms of Anchor’s contracts for each of its supervisory - 2 - mergers during the 1980s. According to Anchor, the breach left Anchor in a crippled, undercapitalized position that caused considerable losses and harm. In a series of opinions and orders, this court previously concluded that, consistent with the Supreme Court’s decision in Winstar, the United States did in fact breach four contracts with Anchor corresponding to its supervised acquisitions of the Peachtree, Crisp, Sun, and Suburban savings and loan institutions. Anchor, 59 Fed. Cl. at 130–32. Liability established, the government moved for summary judgment on whether Anchor sustained or could prove any compensable damages and the viability of some of Anchor’s proffered damages theories. In a September 29, 2003 opinion, this court granted those portions of the motion addressing Anchor’s restitution theory of recovery, but concluded that Anchor’s expectation and “wounded bank” theories of recovery were legally viable and that genuine issues of fact remained. The government’s motion was therefore denied with respect to the expectation and “wounded bank” damages. Between June 13 and July 20, 2005, the court conducted a trial in Washington, D.C. on the remaining damage issues. This opinion, then, is all about damages. It is about lost profits (a type of “expectation damages”) as a viable measure of damages in the Winstar context. It is about how the doctrines of “foreseeablity” and “certainty” are applied in the lost profit context. It is about the economics of what is of value and exactly how that value is created. And once economic value is determined, it is about what constitutes harm to that economic value in order for a plaintiff to recover under a lost profits theory. The problem thereafter, of course—for both Anchor and other Winstar litigants—is how to quantify that harm in the form of damages. How might the court best account for harm suffered long ago, and apply the appropriate rule of damages law? As the following makes clear, there was indeed harm suffered here. The opinion below constitutes the court’s findings of fact in this case after weighing all the evidence proffered by the parties in light of the relevant context inexorably resulting from the history and the economics of the times, both exceedingly crucial because of the need to determine what factors are “foreseeable” as a matter of law in determining damages. Nevertheless, what is particularly essential are the actions of the main protagonists since “the actions of men,” as John Locke opined, generally constitute “the best interpreters of their thoughts.”1 These findings make up the body of the opinion. The skeleton of that body is the law as applied by the court. Thus the conclusions of law that the court renders serve as another level of context in which to view the facts of this case. In toto, it is the proper interpretation of relevant damages law, and especially that law as it has evolved through other Winstar cases, that the court must apply. 1 The Quotations Page, http://www.quotationspage.com/quote/8002.html. See also Paul Samuelson, A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumers’ Behaviour, ECONOMICA 5:61–71 (1938) (pioneering the concept of “revealed preference,” the theory that consumers’ actions and purchasing decisions, not their statements, are a superior guide to their actual preferences). - 3 - Due to the length of this opinion, the court provides the following table of contents: TOPIC PAGE II. BACKGROUND 6 A. The Plight of the Savings and Loan Industry in the 1970s and 1980s: The 7 Problem of Risk Reduction in a Heavily Regulated Business Model B. The Federal Government Responds to the Industry's Problems: Risk Reduction 12 through Deregulation and Encouraging Thrifts To Become More “Bank-Like” 1. Accounting Forebearances 12 2. Asset Deregulation 15 C. Market Responses: A Primer on the Secondary Mortgage Market 16 D. The Tale of Anchor Savings Bank before the Thrift Crisis 24 E. Anchor’s Expansion 25 F. The Supervisory Mergers that Anchor Used To Grow: Benefits, Costs and 30 Promises G. Anchor’s Performance in the 1980s and the Acute Impact of Anchor's 34 Acquisitions H. Anchor’s Long-Term Business Plans in 1985–87 37 I. Anchor Acquires Residential Funding Corporation 38 J. The Arrival of James Large As CEO and His Vision of a More Efficient Bank 42 K. FIRREA and Its Sudden Impact on Anchor's Capital Compliance and Operations 48 L. The Capital Plan and Anchor’s Efforts To Stave Off Foreclosure: The Sale of the 50 Branch Network and RFC 1.
Recommended publications
  • One Cheer for Credit Rating Agencies: How the Mark-To-Market Accounting Debate Highlights the Case for Rating-Dependent Capital Regulation
    South Carolina Law Review Volume 60 Issue 3 Article 8 Spring 2009 One Cheer for Credit Rating Agencies: How the Mark-to-Market Accounting Debate Highlights the Case for Rating-Dependent Capital Regulation John P. Hunt Berkeley Center for Law Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarcommons.sc.edu/sclr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation John Patrick Hunt, One Cheer for Credit Rating Agencies: How the Mark-to-Market Accounting Debate Highlights the Case for Rating-Dependent Capital Regulation, 60 S. C. L. Rev. 749 (2009). This Symposium Paper is brought to you by the Law Reviews and Journals at Scholar Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in South Carolina Law Review by an authorized editor of Scholar Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Hunt: One Cheer for Credit Rating Agencies: How the Mark-to-Market Acco ONE CHEER FOR CREDIT RATING AGENCIES: How THE MARK-TO-MARKET ACCOUNTING DEBATE HIGHLIGHTS THE CASE FOR RATING-DEPENDENT CAPITAL REGULATION JOHN PATRICK HUNT INJ. TRO D UCTIO N .......................................................................................... 750 11. MARK-TO-MARKET FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING INTHE 2007-2008 C RISIS .......................................................................... 752 A. Fair Value, or Mark-to-Market FinancialAccounting Rules ............ 752 B. The Attack on Mark-to-Market Accounting and Its Effects ................ 757 C. Mark-to-Market Accounting Critics Have Failedto M ake Their Case ....................................................... 759 1. Accounting Rules Generally Do Not "Require" M arking to M arket .................................................... 759 2. Market Marks GenerallyAre Not Binding and Do Not Require ForcedSelling ............................................ 760 3. Accounting Losses Did Not Cause Any of the Major Firm Failures in the Crisis.............................
    [Show full text]
  • Cumulative Or Discrete Numbers: Should Bloomberg Measure the Bailout? Teaching Note
    Cumulative or Discrete Numbers: Should Bloomberg Measure the Bailout? Teaching Note Case Summary Financial reporting presents formidable challenges for journalists. To begin with, the journalist must have a solid grasp of the mathematically complex products and practices of modern finance, as well as an understanding of the greater economic environment at the national and international level. Furthermore, the stories—which by nature are full of numbers—must be palatable for readers. Thus it often falls on journalists to decide how best to present the figures so that the story is not only factually correct but also easy for readers to digest. This case focuses on Bloomberg News as it covered one such story: the Federal Reserve’s bailout of major banks during the financial crisis of 2007-10. As big banks struggled to keep themselves afloat after incurring huge losses in bundled subprime mortgages, the Federal Reserve created several emergency lending programs for banks. However, key details such as borrowers’ names, amount borrowed and collateral were not disclosed. Such lack of transparency prompted reporters at Bloomberg News to file a Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) request in May 2008. The Fed stonewalled Bloomberg’s FOIA request, claiming that such information could undermine the effectiveness of the emergency program, because the market could interpret the loans as signs of grave financial trouble. Undaunted, Bloomberg took the issue to court in November 2008 and prevailed. Moreover, the 2010 Dodd-Frank Act on financial oversight also required that the Fed release more information about its lending. This confluence of circumstances led the Fed in late 2010 to release information sought by Bloomberg and other media outlets.
    [Show full text]
  • How Should Bloomberg Measure the Bailout?
    CSJ----13--- -0051.0 Cumulative or Discrete Numbers: How Should Bloomberg Measure the Bailout? From summer 2007 to June 2009, US financial markets flirted with disaster. The housing market had collapsed and, because many major financial institutions were heavily invested in mortgages, they lost hundreds of billions of dollars. The economy went into recession in December 2007 and contracted a full 5.1 percent in 18 months. Millions lost their jobs; other millions lost their homes. At the height of the crisis, experts and ordinary citizens alike wondered whether the nation’s banking system would survive. The US Federal Reserve System, the nation’s central bank, stepped in with a variety of programs to stabilize the banks. While the public knew that the “Fed,” as it was called, was taking action, the agency released few details about individual transactions. At Bloomberg News, investigative reporter Mark Pittman became convinced that banks were using Fed loans to disguise financial weakness. In May 2008, he filed a Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) request with the Fed to learn how much it had loaned each bank, and on what terms.1 When after six months the Fed failed to respond, Bloomberg L.P. (the parent company) in November 2008 filed a lawsuit to obtain detailed records about its massive lending activities. Over the next two years, the two parties fought a legal battle. Bloomberg won at both the district and appeals court levels, but the Fed or its proxy continued to appeal the decision until, in March 2011, the Supreme Court refused to hear the case.
    [Show full text]
  • Fordham Journal of Corporate & Financial
    Fordham Journal of Corporate & Financial Law Volume 15 Issue 1 Article 7 2010 Backdoor Bailout Disclosure: Must The Federal Reserve Disclose The Identities Of Its Borrowers Under The Freedom Of Information Act? Alexander Sellinger Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/jcfl Recommended Citation Alexander Sellinger, Backdoor Bailout Disclosure: Must The Federal Reserve Disclose The Identities Of Its Borrowers Under The Freedom Of Information Act?, 15 Fordham J. Corp. & Fin. L. 259 (2009). Available at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/jcfl/vol15/iss1/7 This Note is brought to you for free and open access by FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. It has been accepted for inclusion in Fordham Journal of Corporate & Financial Law by an authorized editor of FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Backdoor Bailout Disclosure: Must The Federal Reserve Disclose The Identities Of Its Borrowers Under The Freedom Of Information Act? Cover Page Footnote J.D. Candidate, 2010, Fordham University School of Law; B.A., 2007 University of Virginia. The author is deeply indebted to Prof. Caroline Gentile for her guidance, insight and patience with this Note. He is also grateful for the hard work, honest feedback, and input of fellow members of the Journal of Corporate & Financial Law, especially Noe Burgos, Nicole Conner and Gary Varnavides. This note is available in Fordham Journal of Corporate & Financial Law: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/jcfl/vol15/iss1/ 7 NOTES BACKDOOR BAILOUT DISCLOSURE: MUST THE FEDERAL RESERVE DISCLOSE THE IDENTITIES OF ITS BORROWERS UNDER THE FREEDOM OF INFORMATION ACT? Alexander Sellinger* I.
    [Show full text]
  • Rating Risk After the Subprime Mortgage Crisis: a User Fee Approach for Rating Agency Accountability
    GW Law Faculty Publications & Other Works Faculty Scholarship 2008 Rating Risk after the Subprime Mortgage Crisis: A User Fee Approach for Rating Agency Accountability Jeffrey Manns George Washington University Law School, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.gwu.edu/faculty_publications Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Jeffrey Manns, Rating Risk after the Subprime Mortgage Crisis: A User Fee Approach for Rating Agency Accountability, 87 N.C. L. Rev. 1011 (2009). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in GW Law Faculty Publications & Other Works by an authorized administrator of Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. RATING RISK AFTER THE SUBPRIME MORTGAGE CRISIS: A USER FEE APPROACH FOR RATING AGENCY ACCOUNTABILITY* JEFFREY MANNS** This Article argues that an absence of accountability and interconnections of interest between rating agencies and their debt-issuer clients fostered a system of lax ratings that provided false assurances on the risks posed by subprime mortgage- backed securities and collateralized debt obligations. It lays out an innovative, yet practical pathway for reform by suggesting how debt purchasers—the primary beneficiaries of ratings—may bear both the burdens and benefits of rating agency accountability by financing ratings through a Securities and Exchange Commission (“SEC”)-administered user fee system in exchange for enforceable rights. The SEC user fee system would require rating agencies both to bid for the right to rate debt issues and to assume certification and mandatory reporting duties to creditors.
    [Show full text]
  • Top Cop Or Regulatory Flop? the SEC at 75
    University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law 2009 Top Cop or Regulatory Flop? The SEC at 75 Jill E. Fisch University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Administrative Law Commons, Banking and Finance Law Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Corporate Finance Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Political Economy Commons, and the Securities Law Commons Repository Citation Fisch, Jill E., "Top Cop or Regulatory Flop? The SEC at 75" (2009). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law. 265. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/265 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. FISCH_BOOK 5/13/2009 5:50 PM TOP COP OR REGULATORY FLOP? THE SEC AT 75 Jill E. Fisch* I. INTRODUCTION OHN Coffee and Hillary Sale’s article, Redesigning the SEC: J Does the Treasury Have a Better Idea?,1 was written for a sym- posium celebrating the seventy-fifth birthday of the Securities and Exchange Commission. The celebration came at a most inoppor- tune time. The market developments of October 2008―developments that took place contemporaneous with the live presentations at the conference―reflected the most severe capital market decline since the Great Depression. Over the course of a few weeks, several of the country’s largest financial institutions suffered critical or near-critical crises, requiring the injection of unprecedented bailout funds.
    [Show full text]
  • Administrative Tracking/Processing File for Each FOIA Request & Appeal
    Description of document: Contents of the administrative tracking/processing file for each FOIA request and each FOIA Appeal received at the Federal Reserve Board from Bloomberg News Service during calendar years 2007 and 2008 Requested date: 18-November-2008 Released date: 19-February-2009 Update: 17-January-2009 Posted date: 21-February-2009 Updated 08-April-2009 Date/date range of documents: 26-August-2007 - 12-December-2008 Update: 27-September-2007 – 18-November-2008 Source of document: Freedom of Information Office Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 20th & Constitution Avenue NW Washington, DC 20551 Note: The update consists of an additional 65 pages of email messages which have been appended to the end of this file The governmentattic.org web site (“the site”) is noncommercial and free to the public. The site and materials made available on the site, such as this file, are for reference only. The governmentattic.org web site and its principals have made every effort to make this information as complete and as accurate as possible, however, there may be mistakes and omissions, both typographical and in content. The governmentattic.org web site and its principals shall have neither liability nor responsibility to any person or entity with respect to any loss or damage caused, or alleged to have been caused, directly or indirectly, by the information provided on the governmentattic.org web site or in this file A. B. Goodman Law Firm, Ltd. 20GB APR -4 AB 10: 19 Attorney & Counselor at Law •......... :.! ..•. i .. GOODM~r:SO;'.:,:I'( 4t'• ", 'riNveMi&ilialtd.13Cficrc Pt.
    [Show full text]
  • Rakoff III 11312
    Copyright Martin Armstrong All Rights Reserved January 13th, 2012 RAKOFF v SEC –III (Mark This One is For You) As much as New York hates my guts and has done everything in their power to silence me, the twist of fate has developed where I now have largest readership in the financial industry on a global scale. So it seems that even my arch-enemies tune in just to see what I and pointing out next. Exposing this major confrontation between Judge Rakoff and the SEC and telling people to vote with their own money, has actually created a bit of a stir. Now even Bloomberg News has been forced to come out of the closet – no small task for a media organization that is part of the well-entrenched New York establishment. When Wall Street Sins, SEC Needs to Extract Confessions: View 2012-01-13 00:00:00.6 GMT By the Editors Jan. 13 (Bloomberg) -- The Securities and Exchange Commission last week said it will no longer allow individuals or companies, when settling civil lawsuits, to “neither admit nor deny” wrongdoing if they have been separately convicted in a parallel criminal case. At first glance, it seems the SEC is doing something highly commendable. But there is much less than meets the eye here. The SEC should make further changes to put real meaning behind its attempt at reform, which affects only a small fraction of SEC cases. The SEC’s enforcement chief, Robert Khuzami, says the change “eliminates language that may be construed as inconsistent with admissions or findings that have already been made in criminal cases.” This makes sense, since criminal cases require a higher standard of proof than civil ones.
    [Show full text]
  • Top Cop Or Regulatory Flop? the Sec at 75
    FISCH_BOOK 5/13/2009 5:50 PM TOP COP OR REGULATORY FLOP? THE SEC AT 75 Jill E. Fisch* I. INTRODUCTION OHN Coffee and Hillary Sale’s article, Redesigning the SEC: J Does the Treasury Have a Better Idea?,1 was written for a sym- posium celebrating the seventy-fifth birthday of the Securities and Exchange Commission. The celebration came at a most inoppor- tune time. The market developments of October 2008―developments that took place contemporaneous with the live presentations at the conference―reflected the most severe capital market decline since the Great Depression. Over the course of a few weeks, several of the country’s largest financial institutions suffered critical or near-critical crises, requiring the injection of unprecedented bailout funds. In a single week in October, 2008, the Dow Jones Industrial Average fell by more than 20%.2 In a one-year period, the Dow Jones Wilshire 5000, reflecting most U.S. publicly traded stocks, lost $8.4 trillion in value.3 More significantly, although the SEC has long been “the crown jewel of the financial regulatory infrastructure,”4 recent develop- ments have called that characterization into question. The SEC has been the target of relentless criticism ranging from claims that it mishandled derivatives regulation, oversight of securities firms, and market risk, to assertions of delays and blunders and possible in- * Professor of Law, University of Pennsylvania Law School. 1 95 Va. L. Rev. 707 (2009). 2 E.S. Browning & Annelena Lobb, Market’s 7-Day Rout Leaves U.S. Reeling: Stocks in a Slow-Motion Crash as Dow Drops Another 679 Points; After Year of De- clines, Investors Lose $8.4 Trillion of Wealth, Wall St.
    [Show full text]
  • X PUBLIC EMPLOYEES’ RETIREMENT : SYSTEM of MISSISSIPPI, Individually and : on Behalf of All Others Similarly Situated, : : Plaintiff, : : V
    U NITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - x PUBLIC EMPLOYEES’ RETIREMENT : SYSTEM OF MISSISSIPPI, Individually and : On Behalf of All Others Similarly Situated, : : Plaintiff, : : v. : No. 09-CV-1110 (HB) : (Dispositive Motion) GOLDMAN SACHS GROUP, INC., : GOLDMAN SACHS MORTGAGE : COMPANY, GS MORTGAGE SECURITIES : CORP., GOLDMAN, SACHS & CO., INC., : MCGRAW-HILL COMPANIES, INC., : MOODY’S INVESTORS SERVICE, INC., : FITCH INC., DANIEL L. SPARKS, MARK : WEISS, JONATHAN S. SOBEL, GSAA : HOME EQUITY TRUST 2006-2, GSAA : HOME EQUITY TRUST 2006-3 and : GSAMP TRUST 2006-S2, : : Defendants. : - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - x MEMORANDUM OF LAW IN SUPPORT OF THE GOLDMAN SACHS DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS THE SECOND AMENDED COMPLAINT Richard H. Klapper Michael T. Tomaino, Jr. Patrice A. Rouse Harsh N. Trivedi SULLIVAN & CROMWELL LLP 125 Broad Street New York, New York 10004 Telephone: (212) 558-4000 Facsimile: (212) 558-3588 Counsel for Defendants The Goldman Sachs Group, Inc., Goldman, Sachs & Co., Goldman Sachs Mortgage Company, GS Mortgage Securities Corp., Jonathan S. Sobel, Daniel L. Sparks and Mark Weiss November 2, 2009 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page PRELIMINARY STATEMENT ..................................................................................................... 1 ALLEGATIONS OF THE SECOND AMENDED COMPLAINT ................................................ 4 A. The Parties and Claims ..........................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Mortgages Loan Payments
    HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS LEGAL AND ECONOMIC ISSUES IN LITIGATION ARISING FROM THE 2007-2008 CREDIT CRISIS Jennifer E. Bethel Allen Ferrell Gang Hu October 23, 2008 Discussion Paper 02/2008 Revised 10/2008 Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138 This paper can be downloaded without charge from: The Harvard John M. Olin Discussion Paper Series: http://www.law.harvard.edu/programs/olin_center/ The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://papers.ssrn.com/ This paper is also a discussion paper of the John M. Olin Center’s Program on Corporate Governance. LEGAL AND ECONOMIC ISSUES IN LITIGATION ARISING FROM THE 2007-2008 CREDIT CRISIS Jennifer E. Bethel* Allen Ferrell** Gang Hu*** ABSTRACT This paper explores the economic and legal causes and consequences of the 2007-2008 credit crisis. We provide basic descriptive statistics and institutional details on the mortgage origination process, mortgage-backed securities (MBS), and collateralized debt obligations (CDOs). We examine a number of aspects of these markets, including the identity of MBS and CDO sponsors, CDO trustees, CDO liquidations, MBS insured and registered amounts, the evolution of MBS tranche structure over time, mortgage originations, underwriting quality of mortgage originations, and writedowns of the commercial and investment banks. In light of this discussion, the paper then addresses questions as to whether these difficulties might have been foreseen, and some of the main legal issues that will play an important role in the extensive litigation (summarized in the paper) that is underway, including the Rule 10b-5 class actions that have already been filed against the banks, pending ERISA litigation, the causes-of-action available to MBS and CDO purchasers, and litigation against the rating agencies.
    [Show full text]
  • Bloomberg Printer-Friendly Page
    Bloomberg Printer-Friendly Page http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20670001&sid=an3k2rZMNgDw U.S. Pledges Top $7.7 Trillion to Ease Frozen Credit (Update2) Share | Email | Print | A A A By Mark Pittman and Bob Ivry Nov. 24 (Bloomberg) -- The U.S. government is prepared to provide more than $7.76 trillion on behalf of American taxpayers after guaranteeing $306 billion of Citigroup Inc. debt yesterday. The pledges, amounting to half the value of everything produced in the nation last year, are intended to rescue the financial system after the credit markets seized up 15 months ago. The unprecedented pledge of funds includes $3.18 trillion already tapped by financial institutions in the biggest response to an economic emergency since the New Deal of the 1930s, according to data compiled by Bloomberg. The commitment dwarfs the plan approved by lawmakers, the Treasury Department’s $700 billion Troubled Asset Relief Program. Federal Reserve lending last week was 1,900 times the weekly average for the three years before the crisis. When Congress approved the TARP on Oct. 3, Fed Chairman Ben S. Bernanke and Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson acknowledged the need for transparency and oversight. Now, as regulators commit far more money while refusing to disclose loan recipients or reveal the collateral they are taking in return, some Congress members are calling for the Fed to be reined in. “Whether it’s lending or spending, it’s tax dollars that are going out the window and we end up holding collateral we don’t know anything about,” said Congressman Scott Garrett, a New Jersey Republican who serves on the House Financial Services Committee.
    [Show full text]