Chapter 1: Pp. 1–22 1. in Entangled Objects, Nicholas Thomas Even Has

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Chapter 1: Pp. 1–22 1. in Entangled Objects, Nicholas Thomas Even Has Notes Chapter 1: pp. 1–22 1. In Entangled Objects, Nicholas Thomas even has a section called “value: a surplus of theories” (1991:30), though in it, he really cites only three. 2. Or at least, the more this is the case, the more chance there is that its pre- dictions are accurate. 3. I might note in passing that this simplified presentation might seem like something of a straw man; most accomplished economists are considerably more subtle. But in fact, anyone who has taken introductory courses in, say, rational choice theory is likely to have found themselves face to face with precisely these sorts of arguments. 4. Similarly, power is often defined as the ability to influence other people’s ac- tions, which is again, not very similar to private property. 5. These have often been referred to in anthropological literature as “utilitarian approaches,” a phrase made famous by Marshall Sahlins (1976). I’ve decided to use the term “economistic,” because the meaning is more self-evident, and there’s no danger of confusion with the specific nineteenth century doctrines. 6. Though it must be admitted that many of the economistically minded will try to take it as far as they can. Even the slightest reflection demonstrates that the mere fact that humans are biologically disposed to want food and sex means little in itself; after all, we can all think of forms of culinary or sexual experience that others crave, the infliction of which we would consider the direst punishment. 7. This seems to be a very crude popular version of the thought of nineteenth- century social thinker Herbert Spencer, whose work in scholarly circles is, oddly, considered utterly discredited. 8. Another way to imagine this would be to say each language begins with the complete color spectrum, and chops it up arbitrarily, assigning a word to each division. This is sometimes referred to as “slicing the pie” of reality. 9. Most subsequent authors called it “semiotics” instead. 10. A system that merely indicated that the steak-frites was worth more would, technically, be a ranking system. One that specifies precisely how much more adds an element of “proportionality.” 264 Toward an Anthropological Theory of Value 11. Hence too politically: in France in the ‘60s, Structualists were famous for their political passivity, or even conservatism (since in practice being ‘apolit- ical’ usually means being moderately right wing). 12. Critiques are numerous; I have offered my own alternative model in Graeber 1997. 13. One might note that he has thus managed to add to a simple Saussurean model an element of ranking (but not one of proportionality). 14. This is not to say that Dumont is arguing all societies have these spheres ex- actly; it’s simply an instantly recognizable illustration. 15. To take a more symbolic example from the Western tradition: while in the secular sphere, it is women who give birth to men (a clear gesture of en- compassment), on the higher level of cosmic origins, it was the other way around, with Eve produced from Adam’s rib. 16. In traditional societies, one cannot really speak of “individuals” at all. There is no clear distinction between subjects and objects; rather, actors themselves are made up of different aspects or elements that have different hierarchical values. 17. It served this purpose most famously in Edmund Leach’s (otherwise not at all Formalist) Political Systems of Highland Burma (1954). In the Indian case power (artha) is not at all implicit, but a consciously articulated value (see Dumont 1970:152–66), though it still seems to me to stand on a quite dif- ferent order than “purity.” 18. In fairness, Dumont himself has argued that it is one of the advantages of his hierarchical, holistic approach that it does not make such clear ei- ther/or distinctions (1986:253–56), because hierarchies are inclusive not exclusive, and are defined by their centers and not their edges. But this seems largely a philosophical statement not much reflected in ethno- graphic practice. Chapter 2: pp. 23–47 1. Another factor was the belated publication of Marx’s own “Precapitalist Eco- nomic Formations,” which also took a much more flexible approach than later Marxists had imagined. 2. In the French-speaking and Spanish-speaking world it has remained a much more prominent intellectual trend. 3. The debate between Marxists and Structuralists, then, was between the legiti- macy of a critical perspective, the Structuralists taking up the relativist mantle and coming up with all sorts of arguments that Marxists really were ethno- centric after all. Marilyn Strathern, as we shall see, continues this tradition. 4. There has certainly been some discussion of Marx’s terms “use value” and “exchange value” (e.g., Godelier 1978, Modjeska 1985, most notably, per- haps: Taussig 1980). I tend to agree with those who argue that “use value” and “exchange value” should best be used to describe the inner workings of a capitalist system, and not outside it. Notes 265 5. This conclusion was already implicit in Durkheim’s notion of “organic soli- darity,” in which social solidarity emerges from mutual dependence created by the division of labor. 6. Bourdieu even cites Polanyi on the lack of a “self-regulating market” (1977:183). 7. Bourdieu is pretty up-front about the fact that he is applying economic tech- niques of analysis to just about every field of human action—it is not that all fields are ultimately reducible to economics, he argues, but rather that those studying the economic field have done the best job in isolating certain processes and phenomena (competitive strategies, the formation of certain types of capi- tal, etc.) that actually go on in every field, but are elsewhere, disguised. 8. This can of course be met with the usual objections: if one might as easily be maximizing wealth, or smiles, what’s the point of describing it as “maxi- mizing” at all? 9. Gnostic in the sense that it is assumed that the world we live in is utterly cor- rupt and unredeemable, and that the only salvation possible for humans lies in knowing this. It is only fair to note Bourdieu himself has more recently criticized Derrida for arguing that true gifts are by definition impossible, concluding that “the purely speculative and typically scholastic question of whether generosity and disinterestedness are possible should give way to the political question of the means that have to be implemented in order to cre- ate universes in which, as in gift economies, people have an interest in dis- interestedness and generosity.” (1997:240). 10. As it turned out, it was individual consumption, which is what prosperous academics were doing with their spare time anyway. Bourdieu, true to form, bucked the trend and immediately began critiquing consumption as repro- ducing inequality (1994). 11. As Marilyn Strathern has pointed out, 1992:171, cf. also Comaroff and Co- maroff 1992:151. 12. “In a surprisingly wide range of societies... it is in the interests of those in power to completely freeze the flow of commodities, by creating a closed universe of commodities and a rigid set of regulations about how they are to move” (1985:57). He never mentions any cases in which powerful people try to increase the scope of exchange, or powerless ones, to limit it. 13. Though some of the essays in the collection do: notably Patrick Geary’s su- perb discussion of the circulation of medieval relics (1986). 14. Similarly, where Levi-Strauss (1949) argued that men create society by ex- changing their sisters with other men, in marriage, Weiner (1987) empha- sizes “sibling intimacy,” the degree to which even after marriage, men refuse to give their sisters up. 15. It traces back originally, perhaps, to the work of Roy Wagner (1975). It is hard to trace precise genealogies: in what follows, for instance, I emphasize the degree to which Strathern’s theoretical models draw on Gregory’s ideas; but Gregory has pointed out his own work was in large part inspired by Strathern’s early ethnography (1975; see Gregory 1998:10). 266 Toward an Anthropological Theory of Value 16. Objecting to such a project on principle seems odd. The danger is if one mistakes the model for reality: for instance, taking exception to someone else’s interpretation of a particular Melanesian exchange because “Melane- sians” couldn’t possibly think like that—although admittedly it’s a tempta- tion next to no one who develops this kind of model, Strathern included, seems entirely able to resist. 17. What really seems to really annoy most feminist critics, I think, is that in a work about gender that is 344 pages long, she feels this admission can be postponed until page 325. 18. It’s not clear which of the two she is arguing; I tend to assume the latter, be- cause there is some fairly strong evidence that even the Melpa-speaking peo- ple she takes as her primary example do recognize such a unique creative core (see e.g., A. Strathern 1979). 19. When reading Strathern, it helps to develop one’s own glossary of Strath- ernian terms and the words a more conventional scholar would probably use in their place. Mine includes: to elicit to perceive value meaning (or importance) compared to distinguished from enchainments obligations to coerce to persuade, or make someone feel obliged to do something 20. This is inspired in part by a particularly Melpa idiom of “cause” and “origin” (though see also Errington and Gewertz 1987). The donor is the “cause” of the gift being given, while its “source” or “origin” is whatever, in that con- text, is seen as giving rise to it.
Recommended publications
  • Maurice Godelier and the Study of Ideology
    MAURICE GODELIER AND THE STUDY OF' IDEOLOGY In recent years we have seen a gradual coming together of two trends in social anthropology which were earlier often thought of as opposite poles, namely the structuralist and the marxist.marxist 0 1'hisThis development has been most marked within French anthropology. Where\vhere Levi-Strauss in 1962 was conte~tconte:p.t to leave to other disciplines the study of inffastructures proper (1966: 131) he now admits a determining role (though not the spie determining role) to the relationship between man and his techno-economic environment (1974). And, where marxist·anthropologistamarxist anthropologists never thought of questioning the axiom that it is the economic infrastructure which 'in the last analysis' determines the form and evolution of social formations, and frustrated the rest of us by always beginning with that 'last analysis' and never getting around to any of the previous ones, today ideology appeq,rsappe~rs among the mostmost.frequent frequent topics for marxist analysis. Among those, explicitly concerned with the combination of structuralist and marxist approaches is. MauriceMa.urice Godelier.InGodelier •.. In this paper I wish to take up some points relating to Godelier's work on religion, ideology and the like. Religion We·We may well take as a point of departure a brief paper by Godelier entitled 'Toward a Marxist Anthropology of Religion', in which he gives 'an example of how Marxist anthropologists can .. proceed to analyze religion in the pre-capitalist societies which are their
    [Show full text]
  • Gifts and Commodities (Second Edition)
    GIFTS AND COMMODITIES Hau BOOKS Executive Editor Giovanni da Col Managing Editor Sean M. Dowdy Editorial Board Anne-Christine Taylor Carlos Fausto Danilyn Rutherford Ilana Gershon Jason Throop Joel Robbins Jonathan Parry Michael Lempert Stephan Palmié www.haubooks.com GIFTS AND COMMODITIES (SECOND EditIon) C. A. Gregory Foreword by Marilyn Strathern New Preface by the Author Hau Books Chicago © 2015 by C. A. Gregory and Hau Books. First Edition © 1982 Academic Press, London. All rights reserved. Cover and layout design: Sheehan Moore Typesetting: Prepress Plus (www.prepressplus.in) ISBN: 978-0-9905050-1-3 LCCN: 2014953483 Hau Books Chicago Distribution Center 11030 S. Langley Chicago, IL 60628 www.haubooks.com Hau Books is marketed and distributed by The University of Chicago Press. www.press.uchicago.edu Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper. For Judy, Polly, and Melanie. Contents Foreword by Marilyn Strathern xi Preface to the first edition xv Preface to the second edition xix Acknowledgments liii Introduction lv PART ONE: CONCEPTS I. THE COmpETING THEOriES 3 Political economy 3 The theory of commodities 3 The theory of gifts 9 Economics 19 The theory of modern goods 19 The theory of traditional goods 22 II. A framEWORK OF ANALYSIS 25 The general relation of production to consumption, distribution, and exchange 26 Marx and Lévi-Strauss on reproduction 26 A simple illustrative example 30 The definition of particular economies 32 viii GIFTS AND COMMODITIES III.FTS GI AND COMMODITIES: CIRCULATION 39 The direct exchange of things 40 The social status of transactors 40 The social status of objects 41 The spatial aspect of exchange 44 The temporal dimension of exchange 46 Value and rank 46 The motivation of transactors 50 The circulation of things 55 Velocity of circulation 55 Roads of gift-debt 57 Production and destruction 59 The circulation of people 62 Work-commodities 62 Work-gifts 62 Women-gifts 63 Classificatory kinship terms and prices 68 Circulation and distribution 69 IV.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction Laurent Dousset and Serge Tcherkézoff
    IntroductIon Laurent Dousset and Serge Tcherkézoff ‘From initiation rituals in Papua new Guinea to the twin towers’: this is how Maurice Godelier (2008b) summarizes the anthropological project and its remit, the scope of anthropology. Hegel’s declaration that ‘nothing that is human is foreign to me’ is both apt and applied in practice, simultaneously tracing the purpose of a scientific programme and the curves of a personal trajectory. More than a simple assertion that the human being is a social animal, Maurice Godelier’s work is guided by the precept that the human being has to actively produce society in order to live. It is a condition of existence. the intellectual path of a man who has taught several generations of anthropologists evinces both the broad ambitions of anthropology as a science of universal significance and a view of social reality as a tangible and, in principle, an intelligible set of facts. the practice of the social sciences reveals a constant dialectic between ethnography and theory, the particular and the general, the local and the global, the diversity of facts and their unification in anthropological analysis.t he relentless intellectual movement between the acknowledgement of the particularistic nature of the local and the general scientific project it advances is a constant feature of Maurice Godelier’s corpus. Such a project is feasible only if knowledge is progressively accumulated, if the theoretical apparatus is part of a developing paradigmatic choice, if schools of thought and their epistemological frameworks are non-dogmatic. Students of Maurice Godelier have heard him say, on many occasions, that one needs to be capable of using the ideas and concepts that generate understanding, irrespective of any loyalty towards a particular intellectual guide.
    [Show full text]
  • A General Theory of Economic Flow, Social Exchange, and Hegemonic Relationship
    W&M ScholarWorks Dissertations, Theses, and Masters Projects Theses, Dissertations, & Master Projects 1992 A General Theory of Economic Flow, Social Exchange, and Hegemonic Relationship Donn Robert Grenda College of William & Mary - Arts & Sciences Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.wm.edu/etd Part of the Economic Theory Commons, and the Social and Cultural Anthropology Commons Recommended Citation Grenda, Donn Robert, "A General Theory of Economic Flow, Social Exchange, and Hegemonic Relationship" (1992). Dissertations, Theses, and Masters Projects. Paper 1539625722. https://dx.doi.org/doi:10.21220/s2-kwnn-9j14 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Theses, Dissertations, & Master Projects at W&M ScholarWorks. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations, Theses, and Masters Projects by an authorized administrator of W&M ScholarWorks. For more information, please contact [email protected]. A General Theory of Economic Flow, Social Exchange, and Hegemonic Relationships A Thesis Presented to The Faculty of the Department of Anthropology The College of William and Mary in Virginia In Partial Fulfillment Of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Arts by Donn R. Grenda 1992 This thesis is submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts Author Approved, April 1992 f Norman Barka Theodore Reinhart ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page ACKNOWLEDGMENTS i v LIST OF TABLES..................... .................... v LIST OF FIGURES......................................... vi ABSTRACT............... vii INTRODUCTION............................................ 2 CHAPTER I. AN EXAMINATION OF THE FIELD AND ITS FOUNDERS............................................ 7 CHAPTER II. THE DEVELOPMENT OF A GENERALTHEORY.... 52 CHAPTER III. A GENERAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC FLOW, SOCIAL EXCHANGE, AND HEGEMONIC RELATIONSHIPS......
    [Show full text]
  • Human Origins
    HUMAN ORIGINS Methodology and History in Anthropology Series Editors: David Parkin, Fellow of All Souls College, University of Oxford David Gellner, Fellow of All Souls College, University of Oxford Volume 1 Volume 17 Marcel Mauss: A Centenary Tribute Learning Religion: Anthropological Approaches Edited by Wendy James and N.J. Allen Edited by David Berliner and Ramon Sarró Volume 2 Volume 18 Franz Baerman Steiner: Selected Writings Ways of Knowing: New Approaches in the Anthropology of Volume I: Taboo, Truth and Religion. Knowledge and Learning Franz B. Steiner Edited by Mark Harris Edited by Jeremy Adler and Richard Fardon Volume 19 Volume 3 Difficult Folk? A Political History of Social Anthropology Franz Baerman Steiner. Selected Writings By David Mills Volume II: Orientpolitik, Value, and Civilisation. Volume 20 Franz B. Steiner Human Nature as Capacity: Transcending Discourse and Edited by Jeremy Adler and Richard Fardon Classification Volume 4 Edited by Nigel Rapport The Problem of Context Volume 21 Edited by Roy Dilley The Life of Property: House, Family and Inheritance in Volume 5 Béarn, South-West France Religion in English Everyday Life By Timothy Jenkins By Timothy Jenkins Volume 22 Volume 6 Out of the Study and Into the Field: Ethnographic Theory Hunting the Gatherers: Ethnographic Collectors, Agents and Practice in French Anthropology and Agency in Melanesia, 1870s–1930s Edited by Robert Parkin and Anna de Sales Edited by Michael O’Hanlon and Robert L. Welsh Volume 23 Volume 7 The Scope of Anthropology: Maurice Godelier’s Work in Anthropologists in a Wider World: Essays on Field Context Research Edited by Laurent Dousset and Serge Tcherkézoff Edited by Paul Dresch, Wendy James, and David Parkin Volume 24 Volume 8 Anyone: The Cosmopolitan Subject of Anthropology Categories and Classifications: Maussian Reflections on By Nigel Rapport the Social Volume 25 By N.J.
    [Show full text]
  • Kinship and Commoditization Historical Transformations
    L’Homme Revue française d’anthropologie 154-155 | avril-septembre 2000 Question de parenté Kinship and Commoditization Historical Transformations Andrew Strathern and Pamela J. Stewart Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/lhomme/38 DOI: 10.4000/lhomme.38 ISSN: 1953-8103 Publisher Éditions de l’EHESS Printed version Date of publication: 1 January 2000 Number of pages: 373-390 ISBN: 2-7132-1333-9 ISSN: 0439-4216 Electronic reference Andrew Strathern and Pamela J. Stewart, « Kinship and Commoditization », L’Homme [Online], 154-155 | avril-septembre 2000, Online since 18 May 2007, connection on 03 May 2019. URL : http:// journals.openedition.org/lhomme/38 ; DOI : 10.4000/lhomme.38 © École des hautes études en sciences sociales Kinship and Commoditization Historical Transformations Andrew Strathern & Pamela J. Stewart KINSHIP relations are often considered by anthropologists, as well as by those whom they study, to be at the heart of community processes, involving solidarity, reciprocity, reproduction, and alliance. This « kinship model » of small-scale soci- eties throughout Melanesia has implicitly informed recent formulations regarding ideas of personhood in this part of the world, in which social and relational aspects of the person have been strongly foregrounded in the literature. At the same time, the study of kinship systems, seen as based on structured forms of terminologies, has tended to be placed into the background, whereas it was made central in an earlier phase of theorizing, even if from diverse points of view (e.g. « extensionist » vs « category word » theorists, pro- and anti-genealogy theorists, descent vs alliance theory). In this paper we aim to make a contribution to the study of kinship rela- tions and theories of personhood, but principally by looking at aspects of histori- cal change in systemic terms.
    [Show full text]
  • D. Feil the Evolution of Highland Papua New Guinea Societies; a Reappraisal
    D. Feil The evolution of Highland Papua New Guinea societies; A reappraisal In: Bijdragen tot de Taal-, Land- en Volkenkunde 151 (1995), no: 1, Leiden, 23-43 This PDF-file was downloaded from http://www.kitlv-journals.nl Downloaded from Brill.com09/26/2021 09:52:25PM via free access D.K. FEIL The Evolution of Highland Papua New Guinea Societies A Reappraisal1 'If it turns out that the regional contrasts that form the major themes of this book are valid, Highland students from the east and from societies "intermediate" between east and west will be disturbed to learn that their ancestors came down from trees more recently than those of their western counterparts' (Reay 1990:61). One might argue that books receive the reviewers they deserve. We learn from the above comment, however, that the demons of anthropology's evolutionary past have yet to be exorcised in some quarters at least, even in the 1990s. This is just one perspective of many from which The Evolution of Highland Papua New Guinea Societies (Feil 1987) has been reviewed in the years since its publication. Dozens of reviews and review articles in many different languages have appeared, both in anthropology and allied disciplines, even in the popular press. One well-known Highlands anthropologist has reviewed it three times - four if one counts the fact that he refereed the original manuscript for the eventual publisher in the first place. (My early elation over the first of his reviews turned sour when the second appeared; the third was 'mixed', but mercifully in German, where some of the subtleties of language may well have eluded me.
    [Show full text]
  • Creative Democracy: an Anthropology of and by Means of Design
    Title Creative Democracy: an Anthropology of and by means of Design Type The sis URL https://ualresearchonline.arts.ac.uk/id/eprint/15979/ Dat e 2 0 2 0 Citation Pierri, Paola (2020) Creative Democracy: an Anthropology of and by means of Design. PhD thesis, University of the Arts London. Cr e a to rs Pierri, Paola Usage Guidelines Please refer to usage guidelines at http://ualresearchonline.arts.ac.uk/policies.html or alternatively contact [email protected] . License: Creative Commons Attribution Non-commercial No Derivatives Unless otherwise stated, copyright owned by the author Creative Democracy: an Anthropology of and by means of Design Paola Pierri University of the Arts London London College of Communication A Thesis submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy at the University of the Arts London February 2020 Supervisory Team: Director of Study: Dr. Alison Prendiville, London College of Communication Supervisor: Dr. Adam Drazin, University College London Paola Pierri Doctoral Thesis Table of Contents Abstract ..................................................................................................................................................... 4 Acknowledgements .............................................................................................................................. 5 List of Annexes ....................................................................................................................................... 6 List of Figures ........................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • In the Matter of Marxism
    03-Tilley-3290-Ch01.qxd 11/17/2005 6:57 PM Page 13 1 IN THE MATTER OF MARXISM Bill Maurer The real unity of the world consists in its have insisted on an account of actually existing materiality, and this is proved not only by a few ‘men’ in their real, material conditions of exis- juggled phrases, but by a long and wearisome tence. Reactions against abstraction in theory development of philosophy and natural science. more recently often explicitly or implicitly (Engels, Anti-Dühring, 1877) invoke the Marxist heritage as both a theoreti- cal formation and an agenda for oppositional You make me feel mighty real. political practice. As Marx wrote in his eleventh thesis on Feuerbach, ‘The philosophers have (Sylvester, 1978) only interpreted the world, in various ways; the point is to change it.’ Or, as a colleague once put it to me, ‘Derrida never helped save a WHAT’S THE MATTER WITH Guatemalan peasant.’ MARXISM? This chapter uses a narrow delineation of the field of Marxist-inspired debate and critique, emphasizing those anthropologists (and, to a It is difficult to think about materiality, or to lesser extent, archaeologists) who explicitly think materially about the social, without invoke Marxism in its various guises and who thinking about Marxism. The Cold War led seek in Marxist theories a method and a theory many scholars in the West to use ‘materialism’ for thinking materially about the social. The as a code word for Marxism for much of the chapter pays particular attention to the instances twentieth century. More recently, in certain when such authors attempt to think critically quarters of social scientific thought, materiality about what difference it makes to stress mate- stands in for the empirical or the real, as against riality and to think ‘materially’.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Heritage Making in Contemporary Spain Author(S): Jaume Franquesa Source: Current Anthropology, Vol
    On Keeping and Selling: The Political Economy of Heritage Making in Contemporary Spain Author(s): Jaume Franquesa Source: Current Anthropology, Vol. 54, No. 3 (June 2013), pp. 346-369 Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/670620 . Accessed: 20/05/2013 16:27 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press and Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Current Anthropology. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 137.108.145.45 on Mon, 20 May 2013 16:27:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 346 Current Anthropology Volume 54, Number 3, June 2013 On Keeping and Selling The Political Economy of Heritage Making in Contemporary Spain by Jaume Franquesa In recent years, heritage has become a hegemonic idiom helping to legitimize, but also resist, the gentrification and private appropriation of urban space in a global conjuncture dominated by neoliberal policies and voracious real estate pressures. Through the analysis of a conflict around a historical building in a gentrifying neighborhood in Palma (Spain), and drawing on recent contributions analyzing the processual character of cultural heritage as well as on Annette Weiner’s theoretical insights on inalienability, the article explores the economic logic that underpins this hegemonic character of heritage.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Anthropology History, Ethnography, Critique
    Economic Anthropology History, Ethnography, Critique Chris Hann and Keith Hart polity Economic Anthropology also historians and sociologists (and many varieties under each of those labels) - must join forces. Some economists 1 claim a special status for their discipline and locate it closer to the 'hard' sciences than to 'soft' disciplines in the humanities. We take a critical and historical view of such claims, but it is Introduction: Economic not our intention to offer a romantic, utopian alternative to Anthropology economics. We are aware that economics is in some ways as diverse as anthropology. Our aim is to bring the two closer together and this makes us critical of mainstream positions on both sides. Previous accounts of economic anthropology linked it to the founding fathers of modern social theory - notably Marx, Weber and Durkheim. Occasionally the history was Anthropologists aim to discover the principles of · social traced back to the political economists of the Enlightenment. organization at every level from the most particular to the We argue that the core questions are much older than this. universal. The purpose of economic anthropology in the nine­ Ultimately, economic anthropology addresses questions of teenth century, even before it took shape as 'the economics of human nature and well-being, questions that have preoc­ primitive man', was to test the claim that a world economic cupied every society's philosophers from the beginning. We order must be founded on the principles that underpinned make a case for an economic anthropology that is able to a Western industrial society striving for universality. The investigate this 'human economy' anywhere in time and search was on for alternatives that might support a more just space, as a creation of all humanity.
    [Show full text]
  • Focality and Extension in Kinship Essays in Memory of Harold W
    FOCALITY AND EXTENSION IN KINSHIP ESSAYS IN MEMORY OF HAROLD W. SCHEFFLER FOCALITY AND EXTENSION IN KINSHIP ESSAYS IN MEMORY OF HAROLD W. SCHEFFLER EDITED BY WARREN SHAPIRO Published by ANU Press The Australian National University Acton ACT 2601, Australia Email: [email protected] This title is also available online at press.anu.edu.au A catalogue record for this book is available from the National Library of Australia ISBN(s): 9781760461812 (print) 9781760461829 (eBook) This title is published under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial- NoDerivatives 4.0 International (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0). The full licence terms are available at creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ legalcode Cover design and layout by ANU Press. Cover photograph of Hal Scheffler by Ray Kelly. This edition © 2018 ANU Press To the memory of Harold Walter Scheffler, a compassionate man of the highest scholarly standards Contents List of Figures and Tables . ix Acknowledgements . xiii Contributors . xv Part I. Introduction: Hal Scheffler’s Extensionism in Historical Perspective and its Relevance to Current Controversies . 3 Warren Shapiro and Dwight Read Part II. The Battle Joined 1 . Hal Scheffler Versus David Schneider and His Admirers, in the Light of What We Now Know About Trobriand Kinship . 31 Warren Shapiro 2 . Extension Problem: Resolution Through an Unexpected Source . 59 Dwight Read Part III. Ethnographic Explorations of Extensionist Theory 3 . Action, Metaphor and Extensions in Kinship . 119 Andrew Strathern and Pamela J. Stewart 4 . Should I Stay or Should I Go? Hunter-Gatherer Networking Through Bilateral Kin . 133 Russell D. Greaves and Karen L.
    [Show full text]