Dynamic Strategic Arbitrage∗

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Dynamic Strategic Arbitrage∗ Dynamic Strategic Arbitrage∗ Vincent Fardeauy Frankfurt School of Finance and Managment This version: June 11, 2014 Abstract Asset prices do not adjust instantaneously following uninformative demand or supply shocks. This paper offers a theory based on arbitrageurs' price impact to explain these slow-moving cap- ital dynamics. Arbitrageurs recognizing their price impact break up trades, leading to gradual price adjustments. When shocks are anticipated, prices exhibit a V-shaped pattern, with a peak at the realization of the shocks. The dynamics of market depth and price adjustments depend on the degree of competition between arbitrageurs. When shocks are uncertain, price dynamics depend on the interaction between arbitrageurs' competition and the total risk-bearing capacity of the market. JEL codes: G12, G20, L12; Keywords: Strategic arbitrage, liquidity, price impact, limits of arbitrage. ∗I benefited from comments from Miguel Ant´on,Bruno Biais, Maria-Cecilia Bustamante, Amil Dasgupta, Michael Gordy, Martin Oehmke (discussant), Matt Pritsker, Jean-Charles Rochet, Yuki Sato, Kostas Zachariadis, Jean-Pierre Zigrand and seminar and conference participants at LSE, INSEAD, FRB, the University of Zurich and the 2013 AFA meetings in San Diego. I am grateful to Dimitri Vayanos and Denis Gromb for supervision and insights. Jay Im provided excellent research assistance. This paper is the first part of a paper previously circulated as \Strategic Arbitrage with Entry". All remaining errors are my own. yDepartment of Finance, Frankfurt School of Finance and Management, Sonnemannstrasse 9-11, 60314 Frankfurt am Main, Germany. Email: [email protected]. 1 1 Introduction Empirical evidence shows that prices recover slowly from demand or supply shocks that are unre- lated to future earnings and that these patterns are due to imperfections in the supply of capital. Patterns of slow price adjustments due to these sluggish capital responses have been documented, for instance, in the catastrophe reinsurance markets (Froot and O'Connell, 1999), and in numerous popular arbitrage strategies used by hedge funds such as convertible debt and merger arbitrage (Mitchell, Pedersen and Pulvino, 2007).1 These price patterns present a challenge for models of efficient capital markets based on competitive, rational investors, which predict that the supply of capital is perfectly elastic. This paper proposes a theory based on arbitrageurs' price impact to explain why capital appears to be slow-moving. There is widespread evidence that maket depth is limited, even in actively traded markets, and that investors develop strategies to minimize their price impact.2 Arbitrage in particular typically involves setting up positions in relatively illiquid markets that are often dominated by a few highly specialized sophisticated investors.3 I consider a model in which supply shocks and market segmentation generate price discrepancies between two identical assets. I show that when arbitrageurs recognize their price impact, these price discrepancies are not eliminated instantaneously. Strategic arbitrageurs break up their trades to minimize price impact and exploit price discrepancies longer, which results in gradual price convergence. The interesting feature of the model is that arbitrageurs' price impact and the quantity they trade are both endogenous. The model generates additional predictions which match well-documented empirical findings, such as V-shaped price patterns around anticipated (and uninformative) supply shocks, time- varying market depth, and changes in the sign of basis between identical or closely-related assets. Moreover, the model is extended to analyze arbitrageur's behaviour when the supply shocks are 1See Duffie (2010) for additional examples. 2See Chan and Lakonishok (1993, 1995) and additional references in Section 2. 3Anecdotal evidence reveals that some strategies can be dominated by a one or a handful of arbitrageurs. For instance, LTCM was nicknamed the central bank of volatility (Lowenstein, 2000) as it was selling large amounts of out-of-the-money put options and hedging in the underlying securities. Recently, JP Morgan was put under the spotlight after one of it's traders in the Chief Investment Office accumulated large positions in the CDS markets. The trader, who was called the 'London Whale' by the press and other market participants, was reportedly involved in yield curve arbitrage. See `London Whale' Rattles Debt Market", Wall Street Journal, April 6, 2012. 2 stochastic, i.e. when the arbitrage is risky, and study whether arbitrageurs \lean against the wind". I consider a multiperiod model in which arbitrageurs exploit price differences between two identical assets traded in segmented markets (e.g. Siamese twin stocks, a derivative and the equiv- alent security based on the underlying, etc.). In each local market, competitive investors receive endowment shocks that are correlated with the asset payoff. Correlations to the asset payoff are (for simplicity) opposite across local investors, thus market segmentation causes prices to diverge. Stronger hedging needs from local investors create a larger arbitrage \supply" and thus larger price differences. Arbitrageurs can trade in both markets and act as middlemen until assets mature and pay off the same dividend.4 Arbitrageurs are imperfectly competitive. While intermediating trades, they understand that they face downward-sloping demand curves in each market and take into ac- count the impact of their trades on market-clearing prices. This setting with complete information is suitable to analzye cleanly the effects of uninformative supply shocks on price dynamics.5 If arbitrageurs take prices as given, the spread between the prices of the two assets drops instantaneously to zero. Since arbitrageurs are perfectly hedged across markets A and B, they are effectively risk-neutral, and eliminate any mispricing immediately, resulting in perfect risk-sharing and liquidity. By contrast, imperfectly competitive arbitrageurs intermediate only a limited amount between the two markets to keep the spread open and maximize capital gains. Further, as trades have a permanent effect on prices, arbitrageurs break up their trades to exploit the arbitrage as long as possible. When there is a constant arbitrage supply, arbitrageurs reallocate the asset slowly from one market to the other, giving rise to slow-moving capital. A similar mechanism implies that when unanticipated supply shocks occur at some stage, their effects on prices die out only gradually. In both cases, the equilibrium speed of arbitrage increases as more arbitrageurs compete in the trade. This predictable price pattern arises in equilibrium even though all investors have perfect 4The assumptions of market segmentation and identical assets emphasize arbitrageurs' role as intermediaries but are not essential for the results. 5Apart from hedging needs, supply shocks can arise from portfolio rebalancing of passive investors (e.g. index funds or ETFs) around index recompositions, forced liquidations of market participants following shocks to their portfolios (e.g. LTCM unwound its convertible arbitrage activity following losses on other convergence trades), etc. Gromb and Vayanos (2010) provide additional examples. 3 foresight. What induces local investors in, say, market A, to sell today given that in that market the price of the asset will (on average) increase tomorrow? Local investors are willing to sell today because waiting is risky. New information about the fundamental accrues between today and tomorrow and will affect tomorrow's actual price.6 Nevertheless, the anticipation of a more favorable price reduces local investors' willingness to sell today. Hence local investors' perfect foresight erodes arbitrageurs' market power, as in the classical durable goods monopoly problem. The slow-moving dynamics rely crucially on the discreteness of trading and the finiteness of the horizon. The discreteness implies that receiving liquidity today is not exactly equivalent to receiving liquidity tomorrow, while the finite horizon provides arbitrageurs a means to commit to provide only limited liquidity in the future. The model generates additional predictions, including V-shaped price effects around the real- ization of anticipated shocks, time-varying market depth, and sign changes of price differences in case of negative decreasing supply. V-shaped price patterns have been documented around corpo- rate or Treasury bond issuances, and around pre-announced index recompositions, which trigger shifts in uninformed demand for stocks (e.g. from passive investors such as index funds and ETFs), resulting in changes in the net supply.7 These patterns have proven hard to reconcile with rational behavior of market participants because price decreases and reversals are gradual and predictable. This type of price patterns emerges in the model around the realization of pre-announced shocks, even though all market participants are rational. After the realization of the shocks, prices adjust gradually as in the case of surprise shocks. Indeed, arbitrageurs avoid providing any addi- tional liquidity ahead of the shock, so that much of the shock absorption occurs after realization. The anticipation of this behavior by local investors generates an increasing spread up to the real- ization. The striking feature of this result is that, between the announcement and the realization 6Vayanos and Woolley (2008) have a similar effect, which they term a bird-in-the-hand effect. 7Keloharju, Malkmaki,
Recommended publications
  • 2017 Financial Services Industry Outlook
    NEW YORK 535 Madison Avenue, 19th Floor New York, NY 10022 +1 212 207 1000 SAN FRANCISCO One Market Street, Spear Tower, Suite 3600 San Francisco, CA 94105 +1 415 293 8426 DENVER 999 Eighteenth Street, Suite 3000 2017 Denver, CO 80202 FINANCIAL SERVICES +1 303 893 2899 INDUSTRY REVIEW MEMBER, FINRA / SIPC SYDNEY Level 2, 9 Castlereagh Street Sydney, NSW, 2000 +61 419 460 509 BERKSHIRE CAPITAL SECURITIES LLC (ARBN 146 206 859) IS A LIMITED LIABILITY COMPANY INCORPORATED IN THE UNITED STATES AND REGISTERED AS A FOREIGN COMPANY IN AUSTRALIA UNDER THE CORPORATIONS ACT 2001. BERKSHIRE CAPITAL IS EXEMPT FROM THE REQUIREMENTS TO HOLD AN AUSTRALIAN FINANCIAL SERVICES LICENCE UNDER THE AUSTRALIAN CORPORATIONS ACT IN RESPECT OF THE FINANCIAL SERVICES IT PROVIDES. BERKSHIRE CAPITAL IS REGULATED BY THE SEC UNDER US LAWS, WHICH DIFFER FROM AUSTRALIAN LAWS. LONDON 11 Haymarket, 2nd Floor London, SW1Y 4BP United Kingdom +44 20 7828 2828 BERKSHIRE CAPITAL SECURITIES LIMITED IS AUTHORISED AND REGULATED BY THE FINANCIAL CONDUCT AUTHORITY (REGISTRATION NUMBER 188637). www.berkcap.com CONTENTS ABOUT BERKSHIRE CAPITAL Summary 1 Berkshire Capital is an independent employee-owned investment bank specializing in M&A in the financial services sector. With more completed transactions in this space than any Traditional Investment Management 6 other investment bank, we help clients find successful, long-lasting partnerships. Wealth Management 9 Founded in 1983, Berkshire Capital is headquartered in New York with partners located in Cross Border 13 London, Sydney, San Francisco, Denver and Philadelphia. Our partners have been with the firm an average of 14 years. We are recognized as a leading expert in the asset management, Real Estate 17 wealth management, alternatives, real estate and broker/dealer industries.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Convergence Trading with Unobservable Pricing Errors
    OPTIMAL CONVERGENCE TRADING WITH UNOBSERVABLE PRICING ERRORS SÜHAN ALTAY, KATIA COLANERI, AND ZEHRA EKSI Abstract. We study a dynamic portfolio optimization problem related to convergence trading, which is an investment strategy that exploits temporary mispricing by simultane- ously buying relatively underpriced assets and selling short relatively overpriced ones with the expectation that their prices converge in the future. We build on the model of Liu and Timmermann [22] and extend it by incorporating unobservable Markov-modulated pricing errors into the price dynamics of two co-integrated assets. We characterize the optimal portfolio strategies in full and partial information settings both under the assumption of unrestricted and beta-neutral strategies. By using the innovations approach, we provide the filtering equation that is essential for solving the optimization problem under partial information. Finally, in order to illustrate the model capabilities, we provide an example with a two-state Markov chain. 1. Introduction Convergence-type trading strategies have become one of the most popular trading strate- gies that are used to capitalize on market inefficiencies, or deviations from “equilibrium,” especially with the rapid developments in algorithmic and high-frequency trading. For a typical convergence trade, temporary mispricing is exploited by simultaneously buying rel- atively underpriced assets and selling short relatively overpriced assets in anticipation that at some future date their prices will have become closer. Thus one can profit by the extent of the convergence. A prime example of a convergence trade is a pairs trading strategy that involves a long position and a short position in a pair of similar stocks that have moved together historically and hence an investor can profit from the relative value trade arising arXiv:1910.01438v2 [q-fin.PM] 7 Oct 2019 from the cointegration between asset price dynamics involved in the trade.
    [Show full text]
  • Europe's Largest Single Managers Ranked by a Um
    2013 IN ASSOCIATION WITH IN ASSOCIATION 5O EUROPEEUROPE’S LARGEST SINGLE MANAGERS RANKED BY AUM EUROPE50 01 02 03 04 Brevan Howard Man BlueCrest Capital Blackrock Management 1 1 1 1 Total AUM (as at 30.06.13) Total AUM (as at 30.06.13) Total AUM (as at 01.04.13) Total AUM (as at 30.06.13) $40.0bn $35.6bn $34.22bn $28.7bn 2 2 2 2 2012 ranking 2012 ranking 2012 ranking 2012 ranking 2 1 3 6 3 3 3 3 Founded Founded Founded Founded 2002 1783 (as a cooperage) 2000 1988 4 4 4 4 Founders/principals Founders/principals Founders/principals Founders/principals Alan Howard Manny Roman (CEO), Luke Ellis (President), Mike Platt, Leda Braga Larry Fink Jonathan Sorrell (CFO) 5 5 5 Hedge fund(s) 5 Hedge fund(s) Hedge fund(s) Fund name: Brevan Howard Master Fund Hedge fund(s) Fund name: BlueCrest Capital International Fund name: UK Emerging Companies Hedge Limited Fund name: Man AHL Diversified plc Inception date: 12/2000 Fund Inception date: 04/2003 Inception date:03/1996 AUM: $13.5bn Inception date: Not disclosed AUM: $27.4bn AUM: $7.9bn Portfolio manager: Mike Platt AUM: Not disclosed Portfolio manager: Multiple portfolio Portfolio manager: Tim Wong, Matthew Strategy: Global macro Portfolio manager: Not disclosed managers Sargaison Asset classes: Not disclosed Strategy: Equity long/short Strategy: Global macro, relative value Strategy: Managed futures Domicile: Not disclosed Asset classes: Not disclosed Asset classes: Fixed income and FX Asset classes: Cross asset Domicile: Not disclosed Domicile: Cayman Islands Domicile: Ireland Fund name: BlueTrend
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Convergence Trade Strategies*
    Optimal Convergence Trade Strategies∗ Jun Liu† Allan Timmermann‡ UC San Diego and SAIF UC San Diego and CREATES October4,2012 Abstract Convergence trades exploit temporary mispricing by simultaneously buying relatively un- derpriced assets and selling short relatively overpriced assets. This paper studies optimal con- vergence trades under both recurring and non-recurring arbitrage opportunities represented by continuing and ‘stopped’ cointegrated price processes and considers both fixed and stochastic (Poisson) horizons. We demonstrate that conventional long-short delta neutral strategies are generally suboptimal and show that it can be optimal to simultaneously go long (or short) in two mispriced assets. We also find that the optimal portfolio holdings critically depend on whether the risky asset position is liquidated when prices converge. Our theoretical results are illustrated using parameters estimated on pairs of Chinese bank shares that are traded on both the Hong Kong and China stock exchanges. We find that the optimal convergence trade strategy can yield economically large gains compared to a delta neutral strategy. Key words: convergence trades; risky arbitrage; delta neutrality; optimal portfolio choice ∗The paper was previously circulated under the title Optimal Arbitrage Strategies. We thank the Editor, Pietro Veronesi, and an anonymous referee for detailed and constructive comments on the paper. We also thank Alberto Jurij Plazzi, Jun Pan, seminar participants at the CREATES workshop on Dynamic Asset Allocation, Blackrock, Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance, and Remin University of China for helpful discussions and comments. Antonio Gargano provided excellent research assistance. Timmermann acknowledges support from CREATES, funded by the Danish National Research Foundation. †UCSD and Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance (SAIF).
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Pricing with Arbitrage Activity∗
    Asset pricing with arbitrage activity∗ Julien Hugonniery Rodolfo Prietoz Forthcoming: Journal of Financial Economics Abstract We study an economy populated by three groups of myopic agents: Constrained agents subject to a portfolio constraint that limits their risk-taking, unconstrained agents subject to a standard nonnegative wealth constraint, and arbitrageurs with access to a credit facility. Such credit is valuable as it allows arbitrageurs to exploit the limited arbitrage opportunities that emerge endogenously in reaction to the demand imbalance generated by the portfolio constraint. The model is solved in closed-form and we show that, in contrast to existing models with frictions and logarithmic agents, arbitrage activity has an impact on the price level and generates both excess volatility and the leverage effect. We show that these results are due to the fact that arbitrageurs amplify fundamental shocks by levering up in good times and deleveraging in bad times. Keywords: Limits of arbitrage; Rational bubbles; Wealth constraints; Excess volatility; Leverage effect. JEL Classification: D51, D52, G11, G12. ∗A previous draft of this paper was circulated under the title \Arbitrageurs, bubbles and credit conditions". For helpful comments we thank Hengjie Ai, Rui Albuquerque, Harjoat Bhamra, Pablo Casta~neda,Pierre Collin Dufresne, J´er^omeDetemple, Bernard Dumas, Phil Dybvig, Zhiguo He, Leonid Kogan, Mark Loewenstein, Marcel Rindisbacher, and seminar participants at the 2013 AMS meetings at Boston College, the Bank of Canada, Boston University, the 8th Cowles Conference, the 2012 FIRS Conference, the Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, the 4th Finance UC Conference, Universidad Adolfo Ib´a~nez,University of Geneva and University of Lugano.
    [Show full text]
  • Due Diligence for Fixed Income and Credit Strategies
    34724_GrRoundtable.qxp 5/30/07 11:04 AM Page 1 The Education Committee of The GreenwichKnowledge,R Veracity,oundtable Fellowship The Greenwich Roundtable Presents Spring 2007 In This Issue About the Greenwich Roundtable Best Practices in Hedge Fund Investing: DUE DILIGENCE FOR FIXED INCOME Research Council AND CREDIT STRATEGIES Introduction Table of Contents 34724_GrRoundtable.qxp 5/30/07 11:04 AM Page 2 NOTICE G Greenwich Roundtable, Inc. is a not- for-profit corporation with a mission to promote education in alternative investments. To that end, Greenwich R Roundtable, Inc. has facilitated the compilation, printing, and distribu- tion of this publication, but cannot warrant that the content is complete, accurate, or based on reasonable assumptions, and hereby expressly disclaims responsibility and liability to any person for any loss or damage arising out of the use of or any About the Greenwich Roundtable reliance on this publication. Before making any decision utilizing content referenced in this publica- The Greenwich Roundtable, Inc. is a not-for- The Greenwich Roundtable hosts monthly, tion, you are to conduct and rely profit research and educational organization mediated symposiums at the Bruce Museum in upon your own due diligence includ- located in Greenwich, Connecticut, for investors Greenwich, Connecticut. Attendance in these ing the advice you receive from your who allocate capital to alternative investments. It forums is limited to members and their invited professional advisors. is operated in the spirit of an intellectual cooper- guests. Selected invited speakers define com- In consideration for the use of this ative for the alternative investment community. plex issues, analyze risks, reveal opportunities, publication, and by continuing to Mostly, its 200 members are institutional and and share their outlook on the future.
    [Show full text]
  • Hedgeweek Awards 2013 LEADING the WAY UNRIVALLED in CHOICE, QUALITY and EXPERIENCE
    March 2013 Hedgeweek Awards 2013 LEADING THE WAY UNRIVALLED IN CHOICE, QUALITY AND EXPERIENCE LYXOR MANAGED ACCOUNT PLATFORM, INNOVATING SINCE 1998 With $11bn assets under management*, only Lyxor’s Managed Account Platform gives access to over 100 managers, selected among the best in the industry. With the addition of weekly liquidity**, unrivalled transparency and sophisticated monitoring features, you can invest with confidence. We offer investors much more than a platform, we offer our unrivalled experience. Think Managed Accounts, Think Lyxor. HedgeWeek Best Managed Account Platform 2012 • HFMWeek Most Innovative Managed Account Platform 2012 • The Hedge Fund Journal The Leading Managed Account Platform 2012 • Hedge Funds Review #1 Managed Account Platform from Hedge Fund/FoHF viewpoint Dec 2011 For more information visit www.lyxor.com or email [email protected] * As at 31st December 2012. ** 95% of the funds on Lyxor MAP offer weekly liquidity. This material is not intended for use by or targeted at retail customers. It is neither an offer, nor a solicitation, advice or recommendation for the purchase or sale of any securities, financial instruments or investment solutions in any jurisdiction, including the United States, or to enter into any transaction. Securities or financial instruments may not be offered or sold in any jurisdiction, including the United States, absent registration or an exemption from registration under applicable regulations. This material is issued by Lyxor Asset Management S.A., 17 cours Valmy, 92987 Paris
    [Show full text]
  • Speed of Trade and Arbitrage Ariel Lohr, September 2018 Abstract: We
    Speed Of Trade And Arbitrage Ariel Lohr, September 2018 Abstract: We employ a theoretical microstructue model with overconfident traders (Kyle, Obizhaeva, Wang 2017) to demonstrate how market differences effect an arbitrageurs abil- ity/willingness to engage in price correcting trades. The markets differ in the rates at which traders adjust their inventories towards their target levels, "trading speeds". The extent to which trading speed differences across markets effect the degree of price convergence or diver- gence depends on the arbitrageur's preexisting positions in each market. If the arbitrageur trades towards their target in each market at the same prevailing speed the prices converge. Trading speeds are found to be time invariant and the effect of a financial constraint on the arbitrageur increases in the difference between market speeds. 1 1 Introduction This paper contemplates how differences in markets effects an arbitrageurs ability or will- ingness to engage in price correcting trading, enforcing the law of one price. Theoretically if we take some arbitrary return r multiply it by the stochastic dis- count factor m and take the expectation of the product we should recover the fundamental pricing equation 1 = hmri (Cochrane 2009). Any asset pricing model, H : returns ! prices, amounts to an estimation of the homomorphism hm · i which maps elements of a return space to some price space with any r2 = ker(H) being seen as a mispricing in the eyes of the model. Since prices effect returns, asset pricing models amount to restrictions on the price gener- ating process. In reality prices are the results of trading games (i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • The Bond/Old-Bond Spread$
    Journal of Financial Economics 66 (2002) 463–506 The bond/old-bond spread$ Arvind Krishnamurthy Department of Finance, Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL 60208, USA Abstract I document the profits on a trade that is long the old 30-year Treasury bond and short the new 30-year Treasury bond, and is rolled over every auction cycle from June 1995 to November 1999. Despite the systematic convergence of the spread over the auction cycle, the average profits are close to zero. The difference in repo-market financing rates between the two bonds is a significant cost of carry in this trade. I show that variation in the bond/old-bond spread is driven by the Treasury supply of 30-year bonds as well as aggregate factors affecting investors’ preference for liquid assets. r 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: G14; G18; E43; E44 Keywords: Hedge funds; Short sales; CP-Bills spread; Aggregate liquidity; Liquidity crises 1. Introduction Among the most actively traded bonds in the world is the 30-year Treasury bond. Almost since inception the 30-year Treasury bond has served as a benchmark for long term interest rates in the United States.1 The Treasury has, until recently, auctioned 30-year bonds on roughly a six-month cycle. Upon issuance, a bond is dubbed the ‘‘new bond’’ and acquires benchmark status, replacing the bond that was $I thank Phil Bond, Darrell Duffie, Andrea Eisfeldt, Ravi Jagannathan, Owen Lamont, Bob McDonald, Mitch Petersen, Todd Pulvino, Adriano Rampini, Paola Sapienza, Suresh Sundaresan, an anonymous referee, and seminar participants at the Bank of England, the Texas Finance Festival, Columbia University, University of Chicago, Northwestern University, University of Michigan, WFA 2001 conference, and the NBER 2001 Summer Institute for helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Trading Risk, Market Liquidity, and Convergence Trading in the Interest Rate Swap Spread
    John Kambhu Trading Risk, Market Liquidity, and Convergence Trading in the Interest Rate Swap Spread • Trading activity is generally considered to be a 1.Introduction stabilizing force in markets; however, trading risk can sometimes lead to behavior that has he notion that markets are self-stabilizing is a basic the opposite effect. Tprecept in economics and finance. Research and policy decisions are often guided by the view that arbitrage and • An analysis of the interest rate swap market speculative activity move market prices toward fundamentally finds stabilizing as well as destabilizing forces rational values. For example, consider a decision on whether attributable to leveraged trading activity. central banks or bank regulators should intervene before a The study considers how convergence trading severe market disturbance propagates widely to the rest of the risk affects market liquidity and asset price financial system. Such a decision may rest on a judgment of volatility by examining the interest rate swap how quickly the effects of the disturbance would be countered spread and the volume of repo contracts. by equilibrating market forces exerted by investors taking the longer view. • The swap spread tends to converge to its While most economists accept the view that markets are self-stabilizing in the long run, a well-established body of normal level more slowly when traders are research exists on the ways in which destabilizing dynamics can weakened by losses, while higher trading risk persist in markets. For instance, studies on the limits of can cause the spread to diverge from that level. arbitrage show how external as well as internal constraints on trading activity can weaken the stabilizing role of speculators.
    [Show full text]
  • 11 New Trading Protocols and Technology Updates
    SEPT WED 11 FX ETRADING EVALUATION DAY 13:50 pm Industry Keynote: How can you best adapt your trading desk to the current evolving market structure, ongoing regulation and technology innovations? Danielle Caravetta, Director of Global Sales, Pragma Securities As the market structure evolves away from traditional Tier 1 bank dominance of liquidity provision, are we seeing a more level playing field between liquidity providers and liquidity takers? How far are electronic trading venues going beyond spot FX, with the e-trading of FX forwards, FX swaps and NDFs, and even OTC FX options? What are the critical success factors that will define the success or failure of current venues as we move towards more consolidation? What are the three biggest technology trends happening right now and how will they practically transform how you trade FX? 14:10 pm Buy Side Only Roundtables: Establishing the buy side wish-list - What is the key criteria you should consider when evaluating new liquidity and technology providers? Meet your roundtable - In your groups of 8-10 buy side, take the chance to introduce yourselves to each other, and collaborate to establish what the top 3 key criteria is you will all look out for when meeting the providers. 14:20 pm Afternoon Coffee Break NEW TRADING PROTOCOLS AND TECHNOLOGY UPDATES 14:50 pm Platform Presentations: What new liquidity innovation is each TCA and Algo Presentations: What new eTrading innovation is each platform promoting to improve your access to new pools? provider promoting to help you improve
    [Show full text]
  • Minutes of the Regular Meeting of the Board of Trustees of the Employees’ Retirement System of the State of Hawaii
    MINUTES OF THE REGULAR MEETING OF THE BOARD OF TRUSTEES OF THE EMPLOYEES’ RETIREMENT SYSTEM OF THE STATE OF HAWAII DECEMBER 11, 2017 CITY FINANCIAL TOWER 201 MERCHANT STREET, SUITE 1200 HONOLULU, HAWAII 96813 Trustees present: Mr. Emmit Kane, Chair Mr. Jerome Rauckhorst, Vice Chair Mr. Vincent Barfield Dr. Catherine Chan Ms. Jackie Ferguson-Miyamoto Mr. Patrick Frane Mr. Wesley Machida Mr. Colbert Matsumoto Staff present: Mr. Thomas Williams, Executive Director Ms. Kanoe Margol, Deputy Executive Director Ms. Donna Curry, Program Specialist Mr. Larry Wolfe, Accounting Manager Mr. Karl Kaneshiro, Retirement Benefits Manager Mr. Vijoy Chattergy, Chief Investment Officer Mr. Aaron Au, Investment Officer – Illiquid Markets Mr. Andrew Chen, Investment Specialist Mr. Anthony Goo, Investment Officer Mr. Howard Hodel, Investment Officer – Risk Management Mr. Ian Wetzel, Investment Specialist Ms. Gerri Konishi, Member Home Loan Assistant Ms. Wanda Kugiya, Secretary Ms. Dale Kehau Kanae, Recording Secretary Attorneys present: Ms. Elmira Tsang, Deputy Attorney General (Counsel for ERS Staff) Ms. Jodi Yi, Deputy Attorney General (Counsel for ERS Staff) Guests present: Mr. Chae Hong, Aon Hewitt Investment Consulting, Inc. Mr. Paul Yett, Hamilton Lane Advisors, LLC Mr. Neil Rue, Pension Consulting Alliance, LLC Mr. Grant Jaffarian, Crable Capital Management, LLC Ms. Lisa Martin, Crable Capital Management, LLC Mr. Lewis Ward, Gabriel, Roeder, Smith and Company (by telephone) Ms. Leigh Gallagher, Graham Capital Management, LP Mr. Edward Tricker, Graham Capital Management, LP Mr. Dan McLaughlin, Kohlberg Kravis Roberts Mr. Justin Pattner, Kohlberg Kravis Roberts Public present: Mr. Riley Fujisaki, House Finance Committee Mr. Robert Nishimoto, Senate Ways & Means 1 QUORUM/CALL TO A quorum being present (Chair Kane, Vice Chair Rauckhorst, and Trustees Chan, ORDER Ferguson-Miyamoto, and Frane), Chair Kane called the regular meeting of the Board of Trustees (Board) of the Employees’ Retirement System (ERS) of the State of Hawaii to order at 9:00 a.m.
    [Show full text]