Lew Andow Ska, Ptak (Eds.) Undoing Property?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Lew Andow Ska, Ptak (Eds.) Undoing Property? ? PROPERTY LEWANDOWSKA, PTAK (EDS.) UNDOING 2013 Undoing Property? Aenc David Berry Nils Bohlin Sean Dockray Rasmus Fleischer Antonia Hirsch David Horvitz Marsia Lewandowska Mattin Open Music Archive Matteo Pasquinelli Claire Pentecost Laurel Ptak Florian Schneider Matthew Stadler Marilyn Strathern Kuba Szreder Marina Vishmidt CONTENTS 11 Preface Binna Choi, Maria Lind, Emily Pethick 14 As We May Think David Berry 17 Introduction Marysia Lewandowska, Laurel Ptak 27 The Sabotage of Debt Matteo Pasquinelli 37 Cruel Economy of Authorship Kuba Szreder 53 Improvisation and Communization Mattin 69 Copying Is Always Transformative Rasmus Fleischer in conversation with Laurel Ptak 81 Fields of Zombies: Biotech Agriculture and the Privatization of Knowledge Claire Pentecost 93 Public Access, Private Access David Horvitz 117 Thing 001895 (playing cards) Agency 129 The Edges of the Public Domain Open Music Archive 141 Seat Belt Patent 1962 Nils Bohlin 145 The Artist’s Trust Marysia Lewandowska 159 Abstraction and the Currency of the Social Marina Vishmidt in conversation with Laurel Ptak 171 From Ownership to Belonging Matthew Stadler 183 Interface, Access, Loss Sean Dockray 195 Imaginary Property Florian Schneider 207 Reproducing the Future Marilyn Strathern in conversation with Marysia Lewandowska 221 Exchange and Circulation Antonia Hirsch 237 Common Pool Resources 247 Contributors 254 Acknowledgments PREFACE Today, across the world people are 11 engaged in exploring the bounds of locality, community, and commons. From Ramallah and Holon to Caracas and New York, these partly forgotten notions are being both revisited and retrieved. This revival is a sign of the urgent need to find contemporary ways of dealing with existence under capital- ism in crisis. Undoing Property? forms part of this widespread urge. Specifically, it gives the urge more fuel through its specific focus on property, usually thought of as either untouchable or unshakable, and how it can possibly be undone. Here, undoing takes the form of an attitude. This attitude is not of critique, or hammering problems, but of a criticality that seeks out and weaves together minor but yet multiple possibilities, emerging between the fissures. A unique and very timely collection of essays, art projects, and conversations, Undoing Property? was conceptualized and carried out over a four-year period by artist Marysia Lewandowska and curator Laurel Ptak. The project has slowly evolved in a purposeful way, allowing a space for conversations, resilience, and careful negotia- tions. These have been constituent parts of an artistic practice, evidenced through Lewandowska’s work and guided by Ptak’s curatorial attentiveness to cultural practices at the edges of contem- porary art. The publication has involved several of the key agents in recent debates on the contested relationships between culture, political economy, immaterial production, and the public realm. Its perspective is multifaceted, yet grounded in the fields of art, cultural production, and activism. Together, the contributions set forth propositions—ranging from the imaginative and visionary to the abstract and concrete—on modes of thinking about how things can be different, and how to act accordingly. Brought together in this book, they exceed the so-called reputational economies of authorship (as forms of property) by creating positions that share affinities with collectively authored works. Undoing Property? is part of the multiyear project COHAB (2012–2014), which investigates meaningful ways in which artists and organizations can be deeply invested within their local contexts and at the same time form close dialogues in an international arena. Drawing on areas of commonality, such as the “situated” ways of working of the three institutions involved—namely Casco – Office 12 for Art, Design and Theory, Utrecht; Tensta konsthall, Stockholm; and the Showroom, London—COHAB is a framework for inquiry about cohabitation. This book sheds light on and enacts forms of cohabitation itself. This has been apparent in the process of its production, which included four seminars in the series “Publishing in Process: Ownership in Question," which the editors conceived and realized with an unusual degree of precision and care at Tensta konsthall during the spring of 2012, and which acted as the spring- board for the publication. In turn, the publication will offer itself as another point of departure for various forms of activities to be organized at Casco, the Showroom, and perhaps elsewhere. As directors of these organizations we would like to extend our warmest thanks and admiration to the editors for their engagement with the issues at hand and for their hard work in making them public. Our gratitude extends to the publisher Caroline Schneider for her unwavering support and to Konst & Teknik, the designers who gave the publication its shape. Marysia Lewandowska’s and Laurel Ptak’s insistence on the conditions of property being at the core of any discussion about a future other than one that extends the present remains an inspiration within our multiple contexts. The book leads us toward exploring, problematizing, and expanding the commons, and challenges us to embed these in our work. Binna Choi, Maria Lind, Emily Pethick Introduction Marysia Lewandowska Laurel Ptak 17 PUBLISHING IN In 1793, in the middle of the French 19 PROCESS Revolution, the Musée du Louvre opened its doors—transforming a private palace into a public museum. Art was mobilized to embody Marysia the government’s movement from a monarchy to a democracy. An art collection, previously privately owned, was now shared publicly. Inside, civic, financial (via taxation), and social relationships between Lewandowska, the state and museum-goer arguably stirred a sense of mutual agency, responsibility, and collectivity. In stark contrast, today we see a drive on the part of many governments toward private interests in Laurel Ptak nearly all aspects of our lives—from art, to housing, to health care, to education. What we are experiencing right now feels like a near reversal of the Louvre’s gesture—a turn away from a collectively owned culture. More than 200 years later, in 2009, we began thinking about making a book. Informed by our histories and practices as artist and curator, we started to ask ourselves: who owns culture, information, and knowledge, and what are the conditions, politics, and economies of its production and circulation today? We wanted to bring attention to a growing number of artworks, texts, and initiatives problematiz- ing existing notions of property inside contemporary capitalism. We were also interested in how the possibilities of digital technolo- gies and networked distribution affected these issues. Additionally, we set out to explore art’s current models of ownership, collectivity, publicness, and value already at play. These were not just theoretical concerns: we wanted to test if the context of art itself could be a productive site for critique or action. We worked collaboratively and sought to acknowledge the many collective social processes that underlie the making of a book. This four-year inquiry connected numerous contributors and took on several forms. For instance, we negotiated with our publisher a generous set of non-exclusive rights and the release of a digital version of the publication to circulate for free alongside its traditional printed form. Over a communal pot of soup, we hosted a series of public seminars at Tensta konsthall in Stockholm to discuss the making of the book. Presentations, led by Antonia Hirsch, Florian Schneider, Matthew Stadler, and Marina Vishmidt, known as “Pub- lishing in Process: Ownership in Question,” nurtured this book’s Introduction Marysia Lewandowska, Laurel Ptak 20 development as together we scrutinized what production, property, unequal distribution of what is otherwise collectively produced 21 exchange, and ownership mean to us today. value. The city is a prime site of such relations; we are unable to Somewhere along the way, however, the stakes changed. By decipher how what we encounter physically translates into legal 2011, the very question of what is privately owned and what is public- ownership. The contemporary life of the city, as well as our lives, is ly shared in society began to animate intense political struggles and threatened by unprecedented financial speculation. Such speculation social movements unfolding in numerous parts of the world. This breaks up many aspects of public life, replacing them with more much seemed vivid: capitalism had been steadfast in naming, sepa- private aspirations. Introducing this set of concerns writer Matteo rating, and enforcing property for decades in such a way that it Pasquinelli asks if punk culture and the political movements of 1977 confused and destabilized our notions of what might be collective, anticipated cognitive capitalism, and, if they did, how we are now shared, and afforded to everyone equally, versus what was private, projecting ourselves beyond the current crisis. In sounding the owned, or monopolized. “ruins” that knowledge society and financial capitalism are leaving Inside the context of art, how we thought about property had behind, and examining the crumbling topography of the postindus- its own particularities. Artists have experimented endlessly with the trial metropolis and the sabotage of debt, Pasquinelli connects terms of ownership and authorship. Many refused the notion that an interactions between art and gentrification, art
Recommended publications
  • Princeton/Stanford Working Papers in Classics
    Princeton/Stanford Working Papers in Classics Coin quality, coin quantity, and coin value in early China and the Roman world Version 2.0 September 2010 Walter Scheidel Stanford University Abstract: In ancient China, early bronze ‘tool money’ came to be replaced by round bronze coins that were supplemented by uncoined gold and silver bullion, whereas in the Greco-Roman world, precious-metal coins dominated from the beginnings of coinage. Chinese currency is often interpreted in ‘nominalist’ terms, and although a ‘metallist’ perspective used be common among students of Greco-Roman coinage, putatively fiduciary elements of the Roman currency system are now receiving growing attention. I argue that both the intrinsic properties of coins and the volume of the money supply were the principal determinants of coin value and that fiduciary aspects must not be overrated. These principles apply regardless of whether precious-metal or base-metal currencies were dominant. © Walter Scheidel. [email protected] How was the valuation of ancient coins related to their quality and quantity? How did ancient economies respond to coin debasement and to sharp increases in the money supply relative to the number of goods and transactions? I argue that the same answer – that the result was a devaluation of the coinage in real terms, most commonly leading to price increases – applies to two ostensibly quite different monetary systems, those of early China and the Roman Empire. Coinage in Western and Eastern Eurasia In which ways did these systems differ? 1 In Western Eurasia coinage arose in the form of oblong and later round coins in the Greco-Lydian Aegean, made of electron and then mostly silver, perhaps as early as the late seventh century BCE.
    [Show full text]
  • Gresham's Law - Wikipedia, the Free Encyclopedia
    Gresham's law - Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Gresham's_Law Help us provide free content to the world by donating today! Gresham's law From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia (Redirected from Gresham's Law) Gresham's law is commonly stated: "Bad money drives out good." Gresham's law applies specifically when there are two forms of commodity money in circulation which are forced, by the application of legal-tender laws, to be respected as having the same face value in the marketplace. Gresham's law is named after Sir Thomas Gresham (1519 – 1579), an English financier in Tudor times. Contents 1 Definitions 1.1 "Good money" 1.2 "Bad money" 2 Theory 3 History of the concept 3.1 Origin of the name 4 The law in reverse 5 The law in other fields 6 See also 7 Notes 8 References 9 External links Definitions The terms "good" and "bad" money are used in a technical non-literal sense, and with regard to exchange values imposed by legal-tender legislation, as follows: "Good money" Good money is money that shows little difference between its exchange value and its commodity value. In the original discussions of Gresham's law, money was conceived of entirely as metallic coins, so the commodity value was the market value of the coined bullion of which the coins were made. An example is the US dollar, which was equal to 1/20.67 ounce (1.5048 g) of gold until 1934 — and carried an exchange value (at those fixed rates) roughly equal to its coined-gold market value.
    [Show full text]
  • Maria Bieniek MIKOŁAJ KOPERNIK W ŚWIADOMOŚCI UCZNIÓW OLSZTYŃSKICH SZKÓŁ PODSTAWOWYCH I GIMNAZJÓW WYNIKI BADAŃ SONDA
    Maria Bieniek MIKOŁAJ KOPERNIK W ŚWIADOMOŚCI UCZNIÓW OLSZTYŃSKICH SZKÓŁ PODSTAWOWYCH I GIMNAZJÓW WYNIKI BADAŃ SONDAŻOWYCH Słowa kluczowe: Kopernik, sondaż/ankieta, uczniowie, szkoła podstawowa, gimnazjum Schlüsselwörter: Kopernikus, Umfrage/Fragebogen, Schüler, Grundschule, Gymnasium Keywords: Copernicus, survey/questionnaire, students, primary school, high school 1. Wprowadzenie Niewiele postaci w naszej historii zyskało tak wielką popularność, jak Mi- kołaj Kopernik. Nazwisko astronoma, jednego z najwybitniejszych uczonych w dziejach świata, jest powszechnie znane. Już w szkole podstawowej uczeń po- trafi wyrecytować powiedzenie: ,,Wstrzymał Słońce, ruszył Ziemię, polskie go wydało plemię”, stanowiące pochwałę zasług Kopernika. Nie wszyscy pamiętają, że ów popularny dwuwiersz różni się nieco od wersji pierwotnej tej miniatury poetyckiej, a jej autorem jest Jan Nepomucen Kamiński (1777–1855), założyciel teatru polskiego we Lwowie, aktor, reżyser, autor i tłumacz sztuk teatralnych1. W roku 2013 przypadały trzy rocznice związane z życiem Kopernika: 540 urodzin astronoma, 470 rocznica śmierci Kopernika, tyleż samo lat upłynęło od wydania drukiem dzieła O obrotach sfer niebieskich. Była to więc dobra okazja do przyjrzenia się bogatej spuściźnie Mikołaja Kopernika i przypomnienia sylwet- ki propagatora teorii heliocentrycznej. Dla mieszkańców naszego regionu postać Kopernika ma szczególne zna- czenie. Uczony czterdzieści lat swego życia spędził na Warmii, służąc jej miesz- 1 Zob. E. Sternik, Popularny dwuwiersz o Koperniku i jego zapomniany autor, Notatki Płockie, 1973, nr 2, s. 35. Komunikaty Mazursko-Warmińskie, 2014, nr 3(285) 390 Maria Bieniek Mikołaj Kopernik w świadomości uczniów olsztyńskich szkół podstawowych i gimnazjów 391 kańcom swoimi licznymi talentami. Rezydował w Lidzbarku Warmińskim (sie- dem lat), w Olsztynie, gdzie w latach 1516–1519 i 1520–1521 pełnił obowiązki administratora majątków kapituły warmińskiej, oraz we Fromborku, w którym mieszkał (z przerwami) aż dwadzieścia dziewięć lat.
    [Show full text]
  • The Nicolaus Copernicus Grave Mystery. a Dialog of Experts
    POLISH ACADEMY OF ARTS AND SCIENCES The Nicolaus Copernicus On 22–23 February 2010 a scientific conference “The Nicolaus Copernicus grave mystery. A dialogue of experts” was held in Kraków. grave mystery The institutional organizers of the conference were: the European Society for the History of Science, the Copernicus Center for Interdisciplinary Studies, the Polish Academy of Arts and Sciences with its two commissions (the Commission on the History of Science, and the Commission on the Philosophy of Natural Sciences), A dialogue of experts the Institute for the History of Science of the Polish Academy of Sciences, and the Tischner European University. Edited by Michał Kokowski The purpose of this conference was to discuss the controversy surrounding the discovery of the grave of Nicolaus Copernicus and the identification of his remains. For this reason, all the major participants of the search for the grave of Nicolaus Copernicus and critics of these studies were invited to participate in the conference. It was the first, and so far only such meeting when it was poss- ible to speak openly and on equal terms for both the supporters and the critics of the thesis that the grave of the great astronomer had been found and the identification of the found fragments of his skeleton had been completed. [...] In this book, we present the aftermath of the conference – full texts or summa- ries of them, sent by the authors. In the latter case, where possible, additional TERRA information is included on other texts published by the author(s) on the same subject. The texts of articles presented in this monograph were subjected to sev- MERCURIUS eral stages of review process, both explicit and implicit.
    [Show full text]
  • The Preeminence of Gold and Silver As Shariah Money
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Preeminence of Gold and Silver as Shariah Money Krichene, Noureddine and Ghassan, Hassan B. Umm Al-Qura University, IMF 2017 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/95445/ MPRA Paper No. 95445, posted 07 Aug 2019 03:57 UTC The Preeminence of Gold and Silver as Shariah Money Noureddine Krichene1 and Hassan Ghassan2 Published in Thunderbird International Business Review volume 61:821-835, 2019 Abstract Shariah money is gold and silver, supplied by the market on profit criterion. Everywhere, government inconvertible paper money arose from bankruptcy. A government with balanced budgets would never need it. Imposed by force, inconvertible paper is a taxation mean, highly inflationary, and causes impoverishment. Unjust and bankrupt governments will continue to force this despotic money. Islamic Monetary Economics refutes the idea of money as a policy tool. Fully convertible paper is Shariah compliant. Shariah requires a just government to balance its budgets and restore fully gold and silver as lawful money. Key words. Shariah, money, gold-silver, inconvertible paper, inflation, bankruptcy. JEL Classification. E42, E5, F33 1 Professor Noureddine Krichene is an economist, previously affiliated to the International Monetary Fund, and former advisor at the Islamic Development Bank, Jeddah: [email protected] 2 Professor Hassan Ghassan (Corresponding author) is an economist at the University of Umm Al-Qura, Department of economics, Makkah: [email protected] 1 1. Introduction Money is defined as the cash in circulation; it is perfectly liquid, unanimously accepted in all transactions. Previously, it included gold and silver coins. Presently, it is government currency. Money substitutes may be less liquid.
    [Show full text]
  • A Study in Monetary Macroeconomics
    A Study in Monetary Macroeconomics A Study in Monetary Macroeconomics STEFAN HOMBURG 1 3 Great Clarendon Street, Oxford, OX2 6D P, United Kingdom Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries © Stefan Homburg 2017 The moral rights of the author have been asserted First Edition published in 2017 Impression: 1 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permitted by law, by licence or under terms agreed with the appropriate reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department, Oxford University Press, at the address above You must not circulate this work in any other form and you must impose this same condition on any acquirer Published in the United States of America by Oxford University Press 198 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016, United States of America British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data Data available Library of Congress Control Number: 2017931042 ISBN 978–0–19–880753–7 Printed and bound by CPI Group (UK) Ltd, Croydon, CR0 4YY Links to third party websites are provided by Oxford in good faith and for information only. Oxford disclaims any responsibility for the materials contained in any third party website referenced in this work.
    [Show full text]
  • Mathematics on Coins, Part I: the Tale of Two Queens and Two Towering
    The Tale of Two Queens and Two Towering Figures Henryk Fukś Department of Mathematics and Statistics, Brock University St. Catharines, Ontario L2S 3A1, Canada Toronto, Ontario M5T 3J1, Canada Email: [email protected] Abstract In the first article in the series examining mathematics on coins, we discuss two great scien- tists who are not only featured on many coins, but also contributed to both theory and practice of coinage. The first one is Nicolaus Copernicus, author of the treaty Monetae cudendae ratio in which he proposed the law governing competition between money and proposed reform of coinage in the Royal Prussia. The second one is Sir Isaac Newton, warden and Master of the Royal Mint, and overseer of the Great Recoinage of 1696. 1. Two queens Almost two thousand years ago, Roman writer Gaius Petronius Arbiter (ca. 27–66 AD) in his novel “Satiricon” made a cynical remark about money, sola pecunia regnat – only money rules (Satyricon XIV). Although this phrase is taken out of its proper context, it became widely known in the form of a frequently quoted proverb, pecunia regina mundi – “money is the queen of the world”. Eighteen centuries later, Carl Friedrich Gauss (1777–1855), as his biographer W. Sartorius von Waltershausen wants us to believe, uttered words which became one of the most famous mathematical quotes, die Mathematik ist die Königin der Wissenschaften – “mathematics is the queen of sciences”. Thus we have two queens. Their domains sometimes overlap, and this overlap will be the subject of this article. There are at least two levels on which you can consider connections between arXiv:1601.07394v1 [math.HO] 27 Jan 2016 mathematics and money.
    [Show full text]
  • Icolaus Copernicus Used His Expertise in Law That He Acquired During His
    Plaque commemorating Nicolaus Johann Friedrich Endersch, Map of Warmia, panorama of Lidzbark Copernicus’ speech in Grudziądz Warmiński in the lower left corner, coloured copperplate, 1755 in 1522, funded in 1959 by the local division of the Polish Historic Association, placed on the house Fragment of a map of Poland with Pomerania and Prussia, Tabula Sarmatiae no 3/5 at the Main Market Square in Grudziądz LAWYER AND ECONOMIST icolaus Copernicus used his expertise in law that he acquired during his studies in Italy in the numerous duties of his administrative, public and scientific functions in the chapter of Warmia. Unfortunately, none of his legal documents remained until today. Copernicus dealt also with economic, financial and administrative matters. Nicolaus Copernicus presents his treaty Monetae cudendae ratio (On the Minting of Coin) in a city This was a result of his scientific interests and his duties in the chapter. He is hall room during the gathering of Royal Prussia estates in Grudziądz in 1522; in the treaty he calls for the author of a treatise on the reform of the Prussian monetary system entitled equalising the value of Prussian and Polish currencies, drawing by Johann Schübeler, ca. 1876 Monetae cudendae ratio (On the Minting of Coin), which he elaborated in the years 1517–1526. In the paper, Copernicus postulated the principle that “bad money drives out good”. About twenty years later, Thomas Gresham repeated this principle, which later came to be referred to as Gresham’s Law. In 1531 Copernicus wrote Ratio panaria Allensteinensis (Olsztyn Bread Tariff) that calculated the price of bread in relation to the price of wheat and rye, and the weight of a loaf.
    [Show full text]
  • The Origin and History of the Polish Money. Part I Pochodzenie I Historia Polskiego Pieniàdza
    BANK I KREDYT listopad-grudzieƒ 2006 On invitation 3 The Origin and History of the Polish Money. Part I Pochodzenie i historia polskiego pieniàdza. Cz´Êç I Grzegorz Wójtowicz* Abstract Streszczenie Poland’s money has a pedigree of over a thousand years. At the Polski pieniàdz ma ponadtysiàcletni rodowód. W koƒcu X wieku end of the 10th century the silver denar began to supplant various srebrny denar zaczà∏ wypieraç ró˝ne towary, które dotychczas commodities that had previously functioned as means of wyst´powa∏y w roli Êrodków p∏atniczych. System denarowy payment. The denar system survived for several centuries. In the przetrwa∏ kilka stuleci. W XIV wieku miejsce denara zajà∏ 14th century, the role of the denar was taken over by the silver srebrny grosz. Koniec XV wieku przyniós∏ narodziny z∏otego grosz. The end of the 15th century witnessed the birth of the polskiego, jako równowartoÊci 30 srebrnych groszy. Poczàtek Polish zloty, taken as equal to 30 silver grosz. The beginnings of dziejowej drogi z∏otego polskiego by∏ obiecujàcy. Z∏oty by∏ the historical path travelled by the Polish zloty were promising. równowartoÊcià z∏otego dukata i srebrnego talara. Potem jednak The zloty corresponded in value to the gold ducat and to the by∏o gorzej. Wraz z kryzysem paƒstwa i gospodarki nast´powa∏ silver thaler. Later, however, things got worse. The crisis of the upadek pieniàdza. Dopiero w koƒcu XVIII wieku moneta state and the economy was accompanied by the decline of the odzyska∏a dobrà jakoÊç. currency. It was not until the end of the 18th century that the Historia monetarna Polski po 1795 r.
    [Show full text]
  • Carl Menger and the Forerunners of the Austrian School
    3 Carl Menger and the Forerunners of the Austrian School 3.1. Introduction It is generally agreed that the 1871 publication of Principles of Economics (Menger 1981), by Carl Menger (1840-1921), gave birth to the Austrian school of economics. Nevertheless, this author’s chief virtue lay in his ability to adopt and encourage a tradition of thought which originated in continental European Catholicism and the precursors of which date back to the dawn of Greek philosophy and, even more clearly, to the long-established legal, philosophical, and political thought of classical Rome. Indeed, in classical Rome it was discovered that law is essentially based on custom, and that juridical institutions (like linguistic and economic ones) emerge as a result of a long evolutionary process and incorporate a huge volume of information and knowledge, an amount which far exceeds the mental capacity of any ruler, however wise and good. Cicero (De re publica 2.1-2), expressing Cato’s view, writes: “The reason our political system was superior to those of all other countries was that the political systems of other countries had been created by introducing laws and institutions according to the personal judgment of particular individuals, like Minos in Crete and Lycurgus in Sparta… In contrast, our Roman republic is not the personal creation of one man, but of many. It has not been founded during the lifetime of any specific individual, but over a number of centuries and generations. For there has never 38 been in the world a man intelligent enough to foresee everything, and even if we could concentrate all brainpower into the head of one man, it would be impossible for him to take everything into account at the same time, without having accumulated the experience which practice provides over the course of a long period in history.” As we will see, the core of this fundamental idea would provide the basis for Ludwig von Mises’s argument on the theoretical impossibility of socialist planning.
    [Show full text]
  • The History of Government Debt Justification
    ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT: 2012. 17 (3) ISSN 2029-9338 (ONLINE) ISSN 1822-6515 (CD-ROM) THE HISTORY OF GOVERNMENT DEBT JUSTIFICATION Boris Sokolov1, Yana Sokolova2 1Saint Petersburg State University, Russia, [email protected] 2Saint Petersburg State University, Russia, [email protected] http://dx.doi.org/10.5755/j01.em.17.3.2109 Abstract The objective of the paper is to study the evolution of attitudes toward government debt over the period of human history from the Middle Ages to present day. This article is especially relevant in light of recent events. The skyrocketing government debt has recently led to the lowering of credit ratings in the USA, Greece and Italy, which may cause a significant economic downturn. To reach the established objective, the following research methods were employed: comparative analysis and synthesis, historical and logical approaches, observation and aggregation. As a result of conducted research, the history of the national debt justification was divided into five basic stages. The authors critically analyze the theory of capital erosion and demand-side economics. Detailed study of the first four stages showed that attitudes toward public debt evolved from total rejection to approval and all-round justification. However, global financial crisis indicates the transfer to the fifth stage, in which sovereign debts require reasonable restrictions and international regulation. Keywords: government debt, erosion of capital, demand-side economics, financial crisis. JEL Classification: H63, F34, H12, H20, H50, B10, B20. Introduction Historically, the main sources of financing government expenditures have been: taxes, revenues from property, seigniorage and borrowings. The most problematic and widely discussed of them today is government debt.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic and Social Thought Volume 5 June 2018 Issue 2
    Journal of Economic and Social Thought www.kspjournals.org Volume 5 June 2018 Issue 2 Legacies of rational expectations, Lucas’s contributions, and philosophy of time and existence By Hiroaki HAYAKAWA†aa Abstract. This paper explores the close affinity between the theory of rational expectations that revolutionized economics in the 1960s and 1970s and the phenomenology of consciousness and human existence in philosophy that preceded it. In so doing, we trace the evolution of the views in economics on the decision making modes and the role of the market system, from Keynes, to Friedman, to Muth, and then to Lucas, and place the theory of rational expectations in perspective in relation to the phenomenology of the inner time consciousness a la Husserl and of human existence a la Heidegger as well as to Aristotle's ethics of human life as a life of actions. It is argued that the theory of rational expectations, along with its insight and implications, has brought economics to its home ground, that is, the ethical nature of human existence. Keywords. Intertemporal optimization, Rational expectations, Phenomenology, Internal time consciousness, Human existence, Anticipation, Environment, Neutrality of money, Econometric policy evaluation, Ethical nature. JEL. A12, B10,B11, B20,B21, B22, D01, E00, E41. 1. Introduction n the first couple of decades of the post World War II era, Keynes’s General Theory (1936) swept across the field of economics. This theory offered a new I view that could explain why and how an economy may fall into the state of involuntary unemployment as an equilibrium phenomenon if prices and wages are rigid enough.
    [Show full text]