How Should We Write the History of Twentieth-Century Economics?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

How Should We Write the History of Twentieth-Century Economics? OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 15, NO. 4 HOW SHOULD WE WRITE THE HISTORY OF TWENTIETH-CENTURY ECONOMICS? E. ROY WEINTRAUB Duke University1 The modern economist looks at a textbook history of nineteenth-century economics and wonders what, for the twentieth century, will correspond to the chapter titles of ‘Malthus’, ‘Ricardo’, ‘The Mills’, ‘Marx’, and ‘The Rise of Marginalism’. Will monetarism survive editing? Will game theory rate its own section? Will Keynes be a hero or a goat? Economists look to the historian and wonders how the historian decides what is important, and how we go about deciding what will go into a future history book. Eschewing narratives of progress, this paper surveys alternative historiographies for constructing a history of twentieth-century economics, and suggests that the new discipline of science and technology studies provides a number of useful frameworks for telling the story. I. INTRODUCTION field. Faced with any claim of an exclusive or superior path to historical insight, the prudent response is to walk away Historians of science are imposing order on segments of murmuring, ‘live and let live’. (Reingold, 1991, pp. 364–5) the past, often in a ‘narrowing’ or ‘delimited’ way. Some- thing of this nature is inevitable when dealing with, to The modern economist looks at a textbook history of paraphrase William James, the great, blooming confusion nineteenth century economics and wonders what, of reality, past or present. The discourse of students of the history of science now admits more phenomena to the for the twentieth century, will correspond to the field, but without completely expunging older modes. chapter titles of ‘Malthus’, ‘Ricardo’, ‘The Mills’, Each of us can validly take a different slice of what we ‘Marx’, and ‘The Rise of Marginalism’. Will Mon- consider the subject. History of science is an eclectic etarism survive editing? Will Game Theory rate its 1 Surveying twentieth century economics, or economic thought, is a curious task, made more so by the fact that from whomever one seeks advice, one receives a scolding for leaving something out of the account. Without then holding them responsible for what appears here, I thank Gianni Toniolo, Neil De Marchi, and Craufurd Goodwin for their comments and arguments. I apologize to all those authors in my sub-discipline whose works could have been cited, but were not, because of space limitations. © 1999 OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS AND THE OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY LIMITED 139 OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 15, NO. 4 own section? Will Keynes be a hero or a goat? More generally, each method for appraising scien- Economists look to the historian and wonder how tific work attempts to distinguish successes from the historian decides what is important, and how we failures in science, and each defends the ‘right’ go about deciding what will go into a future history method as the one which produces successes. book. To economists, our task as historians appears Consequently, all alternative ‘methodologies’ for to be to ask how economic thought has changed economics would appear to have implicit winners over the century, to address the issue of why it has and losers in economic work: the winning economic changed, what are the significant issues associated ideas, those which emerged from the community’s with those changes, and what are the implications work, are the exemplars of the right methodology. for the future of economic thought. As befits a scientific discipline, this seems to most economists to require the historian to document/explain the II. INDUCTIVIST HEROES progress in economics over the century. Yet as we will see in what follows, while the idea of progress As befits a fin-de-siècle exercise, let us begin by makes sense to economists, it is problematic to asking how historians would have appraised twen- historians. tieth century winners and losers were the method- ology of 1900 to be treasured today. It is fairly clear Nevertheless it is certainly appropriate for the eco- that, at the turn of the twentieth century, science nomics community to ask ‘How do we know what itself, a fortiori economic science, was generally will endure of the twentieth century’s economics?’ understood to be inductivist. Many educated indi- Let me then begin to answer this question by viduals had read Karl Pearson’s The Grammar of describing several ways some historians of science, Science (1911), published in various editions be- and thus historians of economics, have sought to tween 1892 and the first decades of the twentieth ground their judgements in particular appraisal cri- century, and supposed it to be a fairly coherent teria. As we will see, each criterion carries with it a picture of exactly how science proceeded. Pearson ‘right’ way to narrate the history of twentieth century summed up his discussion of the method of science economics, and thus each implies a set of ‘chapter by arguing that titles’ for the century’s history of economics. the scientific method is marked by the following features: In his paper, ‘History of Science and its Rational (a) careful and accurate classification of facts and obser- Reconstructions’, Imre Lakatos (1971) argued that vation of their correlation and sequence; (b) the discov- every particular philosophy of science, that is every ery of scientific laws by aid of the creative imagination; system which develops a normative reconstruction (c) self-criticism in the final touchstone of equal validity for all normally constituted minds. (Pearson, 1911, p. 37) of science and the development of scientific knowl- edge,2 carries with it an associated historiography of Pearson, a phenomenologist, argued that the exter- science. For it is not the case that history of science nal world provided sense impressions which the provides case studies on which philosophers may human being interpreted through brain activity. Using test alternative conceptions of how science oper- the metaphor of the brain as a central telephone ates, but rather that each particular conception of exchange, Pearson had the scientists operating as how science operates constrains the narratives that interpreters of the messages from nature, classify- can be constructed in the history of science: ‘each ing and reconstructing data. The facts of science, internal historiography has its characteristic victori- and thus the facts of economics, ‘excite the mind to ous paradigms’ (Lakatos, 1971, p. 104). For example: the formation of constructs and conceptions, and these again, by association and generalization, fur- the inductivist historian recognizes only two sorts of genuine scientific discoveries: hard factual propositions nish us with the whole range of material to which the and inductive generalizations. These and only these scientific method applies’ (Pearson, 1911, p. 74). constitute the backbone of his internal history. When writing history, he looks out for them—finding them is What then might a forward-looking economist in quite a problem. (Lakatos, 1971) 1900 have forecast to be the important kinds of 2 In economics, these philosophical systems are called methodologies. 140 E. R. Weintraub economic analyses? It is unfortunate that econo- and Arthur Burns and later Milton Friedman, Anna mists did not have a David Hilbert, who at the World Schwartz, and others. They would feature as well Congress of Mathematics in 1900 set out what he work on business cycles connected to the NBER regarded to be the important unsolved problems in project, and sponsored by the Rockefeller Founda- mathematics, for with such a list historians of math- tion in institutes in Europe in the inter-war years ematics have been able to trace research agendas (Rotterdam, Vienna, Kiel, etc.) placing individuals in a number of different sub-fields of mathematics such as Jan Tinbergen, and perhaps Ragnar Frisch, over much of this century, allowing some con- in positions of prominence. Our stories of scientific textualization of ideas such as success and improve- success would highlight the economic ideas of ment and progress within the discipline of math- Wassily Leontief, whose careful classification sys- ematics. Absent a Hilbert, let us instead consider the tem of input–output tables allowed a finer and finer remarkable essay, Man in the Biological and representation of the structure of particular econo- Social Sciences, by Vito Volterra (1906), given on mies, and the usefulness of those representations in the occasion of his 1900 inauguration as Professor managing the command economies of countries in of Theoretical Physics at the University of Rome. the former Soviet bloc. The inductivist Pantheon Volterra, talking about the role that mathematics would include Simon Kuznets, and James Meade was likely to play in applied work, in economics and and Colin Clark, whose development of the ideas of biology specifically, in the new century, argued that: national income accounting gave prominence to the collection and classification of the facts of the [therefore, for economists it is necessary that they] first domestic economy, facts which could be arrayed establish concepts in a way that allows the introduction of measures, and from those measures discover laws, and understood in a Baconian fashion to allow from those laws work back to the hypothesis, then by theorizing to proceed. The work of Edward Denison means of analysis, deduce from the hypothesis a science and Moses Abramovitz would likewise appear with which reasons in a rigorously logical manner about ideal
Recommended publications
  • The Austrian School in Bulgaria: a History✩ Nikolay Nenovsky A,*, Pencho Penchev B
    Russian Journal of Economics 4 (2018) 44–64 DOI 10.3897/j.ruje.4.26005 Publication date: 23 April 2018 www.rujec.org The Austrian school in Bulgaria: A history✩ Nikolay Nenovsky a,*, Pencho Penchev b a University of Picardie Jules Verne, Amiens, France b University of National and World Economy, Sofia, Bulgaria Abstract The main goal of this study is to highlight the acceptance, dissemination, interpretation, criticism and make some attempts at contributing to Austrian economics made in Bulgaria during the last 120 years. We consider some of the main characteristics of the Austrian school, such as subjectivism and marginalism, as basic components of the economic thought in Bulgaria and as incentives for the development of some original theoreti- cal contributions. Even during the first few years of Communist regime (1944–1989), with its Marxist monopoly over intellectual life, the Austrian school had some impact on the economic thought in the country. Subsequent to the collapse of Communism, there was a sort of a Renaissance and rediscovery of this school. Another contribution of our study is that it illustrates the adaptability and spontaneous evolution of ideas in a different and sometimes hostile environment. Keywords: history of economic thought, dissemination of economic ideas, Austrian school, Bulgaria. JEL classification: B00, B13, B30, B41. 1. Introduction The emergence and development of specialized economic thought amongst the Bulgarian intellectuals was a process that occurred significantly slowly in comparison to Western and Central Europe. It also had its specific fea- tures. The first of these was that almost until the outset of the 20th century, the economic theories and different concepts related to them were not well known.
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberal Reason and Its Forms: Depoliticisation Through
    Neoliberal Reason and Its Forms: De-Politicisation Through Economisation Yahya M. Madra and Fikret Adaman Department of Economics, Boğaziçi University, Istanbul, Turkey; [email protected] Abstract: This paper offers a historically contextualised intellectual history of the entangled development of three competing post-war economic approaches, viz the Austrian, Chicago and post-Walrasian schools, as three forms of neoliberalism. Taking our cue from Foucault’s reading of neoliberalism as a mode of governmentality under which the social is organised through “economic incentives”, we engage with the recent discussions of neoliberal theory on three accounts: neoliberalism is read as an epistemic horizon including not only “pro-” but also “post-market” positions articulated by post- Walrasian economists who claim that market failures necessitate the design of “incentive-compatible” remedial mechanisms; the Austrian tradition is distinguished from the Chicago-style pro-marketism; and the implications of the differences among the three approaches on economic as well as socio-political life are discussed. The paper maintains that all three approaches promote the de-politicisation of the social through its economisation albeit by way of different theories and policies. Keywords: Michel Foucault, economisation, Austrian School, Chicago School, post- Walrasian School Introduction More than half a decade after the 2008 Crash and with no end in sight to depressive economic conditions, neoliberal reason displays a certain resiliency. In time, the initial calls for intervention and regulation transformed into austerity programs run by technocratic governments. In the absence of a major redistribution of wealth and income, returning to a New Deal arrangement with well paying secure jobs for all, comprehensive social security, free and quality education, accessible healthcare and active government involvement in social welfare, appears to many a nostalgic indulgence.
    [Show full text]
  • Marginal Revolution
    MARGINAL REVOLUTION It took place in the later half of the 19th century Stanley Jevons in England, Carl Menger in Austria and Leon walras at Lausanne, are generally regarded as the founders of marginalist school Hermann Heinrich Gossen of Germany is considered to be the anticipator of the marginalist school The term ‘Marginal Revolution’ is applied to the writings of the above economists because they made fundamental changes in the apparatus of economic analysis They started looking at some of the important economic problems from an altogether new angle different from that of classical economists Marginal economists has been used to analyse the single firm and its behavior, the market for a single product and the formation of individual prices Marginalism dominated Western economic thought for nearly a century until it was challenged by Keynesian attack in 1936 (keynesian economics shifted the sphere of enquiry from micro economics to macro economics where the problems of the economy as a whole are analysed) The provocation for the emergence of marginalist school was provided by the interpretation of classical doctrines especially the labour theory of value and ricardian theory of rent by the socialists Socialists made use of classical theories to say things which were not the intention of the creators of those theories So the leading early marginalists felt the need for thoroughly revising the classical doctrines especially the theory of value They thought by rejecting the labour theory of value and by advocating the marginal utility theory of value, they could strike at the theoretical basis of socialism Economic Ideas of Marginalist School This school concentrated on the ‘margin’ to explain economic phenomena.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • THE NEOLIBERAL THEORY of SOCIETY Simon Clarke
    THE NEOLIBERAL THEORY OF SOCIETY Simon Clarke The ideological foundations of neo-liberalism Neoliberalism presents itself as a doctrine based on the inexorable truths of modern economics. However, despite its scientific trappings, modern economics is not a scientific discipline but the rigorous elaboration of a very specific social theory, which has become so deeply embedded in western thought as to have established itself as no more than common sense, despite the fact that its fundamental assumptions are patently absurd. The foundations of modern economics, and of the ideology of neoliberalism, go back to Adam Smith and his great work, The Wealth of Nations. Over the past two centuries Smith’s arguments have been formalised and developed with greater analytical rigour, but the fundamental assumptions underpinning neoliberalism remain those proposed by Adam Smith. Adam Smith wrote The Wealth of Nations as a critique of the corrupt and self-aggrandising mercantilist state, which drew its revenues from taxing trade and licensing monopolies, which it sought to protect by maintaining an expensive military apparatus and waging costly wars. The theories which supported the state conceived of exchange as a ‘zero-sum game’, in which one party’s gain was the other party’s loss, so the maximum benefit from exchange was to be extracted by force and fraud. The fundamental idea of Smith’s critique was that the ‘wealth of the nation’ derived not from the accumulation of wealth by the state, at the expense of its citizens and foreign powers, but from the development of the division of labour. The division of labour developed as a result of the initiative and enterprise of private individuals and would develop the more rapidly the more such individuals were free to apply their enterprise and initiative and to reap the corresponding rewards.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution
    Florida Law Review Volume 71 Issue 2 Article 4 Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution Herbert Hovenkamp Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/flr Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Recommended Citation Herbert Hovenkamp, Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution, 71 Fla. L. Rev. 455 (). Available at: https://scholarship.law.ufl.edu/flr/vol71/iss2/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by UF Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Florida Law Review by an authorized editor of UF Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Hovenkamp: Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution REGULATION AND THE MARGINALIST REVOLUTION Herbert Hovenkamp* Abstract The marginalist revolution in economics became the foundation for the modern regulatory State with its “mixed” economy. For the classical political economists, value was a function of past averages. Marginalism substituted forward looking theories based on expectations about firm and market performance. Marginalism swept through university economics, and by 1920 or so virtually every academic economist was a marginalist. This Article considers the historical influence of marginalism on regulatory policy in the United States. My view is at odds with those who argue that marginalism saved capitalism by rationalizing it as a more defensible buttress against incipient socialism. While marginalism did permit economists and policy makers to strike a middle ground between laissez faire and socialism, the “middle ground” tilted very strongly toward public control. Ironically, regulation plus private ownership was able to go much further in the United States than socialism ever could because it preserved the rhetoric of capital as privately owned, even as it deprived firms of many of the most important indicia of ownership.
    [Show full text]
  • History of Economic Thought
    History of economic thought The term economics was coined around 1870 and popularized by Alfred Marshall, as a substitute for the earlier term political economy which has been used through the 18-19th centuries, with Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx as its main thinkers and which today is frequently referred to as the "classical" economic theory. Both economy and economics are derived from the Greek oikos- for "house" or "settlement", and nomos for "laws" or "norms". Economic thought may be roughly divided into three phases: Premodern (Greek, Roman, Arab), Early modern (mercantilist, physiocrats) and Modern (since Adam Smith in the late 18th century). Systematic economic theory has been developed mainly since the birth of the modern era. Premodern economic thought Several ancient philosophers made various economic observations. Among them Aristotle is probably the most important. Mediaeval Arabs also made contributions to the understanding of economics. In particular, Ibn Khaldun of Tunis (1332-1406) wrote on economic and political theory in his Prolegomena, showing for example, how population density is related to the division of labour which leads to economic growth and so in turn to greater population in a virtuous circle. Early Western precursors of economics engaged in the scholastics theological debates during the middle ages. An important topic of discussion was the determination of the just price of a good. In the religious wars following the Reformation in the 16th century, ideas about free trade appeared, later formulated in legal terms by Hugo de Groot or Grotius (Mare liberum). Economic policy in Europe during the late middle ages and early renaissance treated economic activity as a good which was to be taxed to raise revenues for the nobility and the church.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Economics 446-01 History of Economic Thought
    Economics 446-01 History of Economic Thought Spring 2021 Professor Clyde Haulman Office: Tyler 423 Tele: 757-221-2365 email: [email protected] Office Hours: On Zoom Mondays 3:30PM EST and 8:00PM EST and by appointment COURSE OBJECTIVES “...the ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood.” In reality, even practical people “... are usually the slaves of some defunct economists.” With these words, John Maynard Keynes provides a rational for this course. Economic ideas have indeed played a critical role in shaping the world we know and they have day to day impacts on the lives of people everywhere. Understanding the origins of these ideas and how they have developed and transformed into the foundations of the current state of economic analysis is the purpose of this course. Studying the primary works of the some of the ‘giants’ of economics (as well as the works of some lesser giants), we will consider how economic ideas, analysis, and method have both changed and remained the same over time. We will focus on four major ‘schools’ of economic thought -- Classical, Marxian, Neo-Classical, and Keynesian. Classical political economy emerged in the late eighteenth century as an important component of Enlightenment thinking. In part, it developed in response to government intervention in the economy, and its proponents provided theories and policies for commercial and industrial capitalism as well as for the emerging market revolution. The Classical school is represented by the work of Adam Smith, Thomas Malthus, David Ricardo and John Stuart Mill.
    [Show full text]
  • Finance and Class in the Marginalist Revolution Yair Kaldor*
    Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/soceco/mwy043/5238113 by Ben Gurion University of the Negev-Medical Library user on 28 July 2019 Socio-Economic Review, 2018, Vol. 0, No. 0, 1–19 doi: 10.1093/soceco/mwy043 Article Article The cultural foundations of economic categories: finance and class in the marginalist revolution Yair Kaldor* Department of Sociology, University of Wisconsin-Madison, Madison, WI, USA *Correspondence: [email protected] Abstract Economic categories are part of the everyday concepts people use to apprehend social reality. While scholars recognize their importance for social and economic processes, it is not clear how these categories develop when reality itself changes. I address this issue with a framework that incorporates a cultural emphasis on meaning-making with a macro-structural analysis of the conditions in which they take place. I apply this framework to the marginalist revolution of the late 19th century, which marks the birth of neoclassical economics and focus on the new understanding of ‘value’ that emerged during this period. I trace it to the rise of finance and the problem of price fluctuations, and show how its class standpoint helps explain the different outcomes of the marginalist revolution in England, Austria and France. The analysis provides insights into the power of economic ideas and the cultural dimension of structural changes. Key words: economic categories, culture, finance, value, neoclassical economics, economic sociology JEL classification: B History of Economic Thought, N2 History of Financial Markets and Institutions, N1 Macroeconomic and Monetary History 1. Introduction The basic categories of economics appear as self-evident and are hardly in need of explana- tion.
    [Show full text]
  • Post-Keynesian Economics
    History and Fundamentals of Post-Keynesian Macroeconomics Marc Lavoie University of Paris 13 University of Ottawa A Modern Guide To Keynesian Macroeconomics And Economic Policies Outline • 1. We set post-Keynesian economics within a set of multiple heterodox schools of thought, in opposition to mainstream schools and quickly identify the main features (presuppositions) of heterodoxy, contrasting them to those of orthodoxy. • 2. We cover a brief history of post-Keynesian economics, in particular its founding moments. • 3. We identify the additional features that characterize post- Keynesian economics relative to closely-related heterodox schools. • 4. We delineate the various streams of post-Keynesian economics: Fundamentalist, Kaleckian, Kaldorian, Sraffian, Institutionalist. • 5. PKE in the limelight: monetary economics 7th FMM International Summer School, Keynesian Macroeconomics and Economic Policies, July-August 2019 PART I Heterodox schools and Keynesian schools Heterodox vs Orthodox economics • HETERODOX PARADIGM • ORTHODOX PARADIGM • NON-ORTHODOX • DOMINANT PARADIGM PARADIGM • THE MAINSTREAM • POST-CLASSICAL PARADIGM • NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS • REVIVAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY • MARGINALISM • REAL-WORLD ECONOMICS 7th FMM International Summer School, Keynesian Macroeconomics and Economic Policies, July-August 2019 • Lee, Lavoie ROPE 2012 • J.E. King • Stockhammer and Ramskögler • Dobusch and Kapeller • D. Dequech • B. Hopkins • M. Vernengo • Earl and Peng • G. Mongiovi • Rochon and Docherty • D. Foley • L. Hoang-Ngoc 7th FMM International Summer School, Keynesian Macroeconomics and Economic Policies, July-August 2019 Hodgson (August 2019 book): Is There a Future for Heterodox Economics? • “Over the last 50 years, and particularly since the financial crash in 2008, the community of heterodox economists has expanded, and its publications have proliferated. But its power in departments of economics has waned.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution
    University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law 5-29-2018 Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution Herbert J. Hovenkamp University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Courts Commons, Economic History Commons, Growth and Development Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Inequality and Stratification Commons, Intellectual Property Law Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Public History Commons, and the Technology and Innovation Commons Repository Citation Hovenkamp, Herbert J., "Regulation and the Marginalist Revolution" (2018). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law. 1984. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/1984 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Hovenkamp Marginalism and Regulation June 2018, Page 1 REGULATION AND THE MARGINALIST REVOLUTION Herbert Hovenkamp* PRELIMINARY DRAFT: PLEASE CONSULT AUTHOR BEFORE CITING Abstract The marginalist revolution in economics became the foundation for the modern regulatory State with its “mixed” economy. Marginalism, whose development defines the boundary between classical political economy and neoclassical economics, completely overturned economists’ theory of value. It developed in the late nineteenth century in England, the Continent and the United States. For the classical political economists, value was a function of past averages. One good example is the wage-fund theory, which saw the optimal rate of wages as a function of the firm’s ability to save from previous profits.
    [Show full text]
  • The Market and the People: on the Incompatibility of Neoliberalism and Democracy
    The Market and the People: On the Incompatibility of Neoliberalism and Democracy Lars Sebastiaan Cornelissen Through gentle digging one can uncover the old latent configurations, but when it comes to determining the system of discourse on the basis of which we still live, as soon as we are obliged to question the words that still resonate in our ears, that are mingled with those we are trying to speak, then archaeology, like Nietzschean philosophy, is forced to work with hammer blows. —Michel Foucault, ‘On the Ways of Writing History’ To Kate, and to all of the friends who made this work possible 3 ABSTRACT This dissertation intervenes in current debates surrounding the relationship between neoliberalism and democracy, developing a novel perspective on the history of neoliberalism. It argues that these debates have overlooked the epistemological framework that made possible the emergence of neoliberalism in the 1940s. On the basis of an analysis of this framework, it offers an understanding of how and why neoliberal political philosophy developed as an anti-democratic doctrine. The first part of this dissertation, consisting of three chapters, engages with contemporary critiques of neoliberalism. The first and second chapters engage with Michel Foucault’s account of what he calls neoliberal “governmentality” and with recent interpretations thereof. Special attention is paid to the methods of analysis used by both Foucault and those who adopt his account. It is argued that for a rigorous understanding of the relationship between neoliberalism and democracy, neoliberal governmentality must be subjected to what Foucault calls “archaeological” analysis. The third chapter explores the archaeological method as developed by Foucault in his early work and compiles a set of analytical tools used in the remainder of the dissertation.
    [Show full text]