Review of International Studies (2003), 29, 139–143 Copyright © British International Studies Association DOI: 10.1017/S0260210503000081 The political ‘complications’ of digital information networks: a reply to ‘The of Bandwidth’

GIAMPIERO GIACOMELLO

Abstract. In ‘The Politics of Bandwidth’, Geoffrey Herrera examines the relationship between the information revolution and international affairs. His main point is that the evolution and ultimate shape of a mature digital information network will be decided by a three-way political struggle between states, firms and individuals. This short essay intends to expand and refine some of Herrera’s assumptions. More importantly, however, the essay draws attention to the factor that Herrera neglects, namely the difference that being a makes when determining the outcome of the three-way struggle.

Scholars and scientists alike have long recognised that studying the connections between international politics and technology is an undertaking crucial to under- standing the world’s dynamics. Information technology is a new addition, but it has already attracted a large following.1 Social scientists, however, have a harder time investigating the social implications of modern technologies than, say, lawyers or engineers, because the latter can, to a larger extent, discount the human factor, while the former cannot. Deprived of the neat and tidier categorisations of law and engineering, social scientists are mostly left to ‘the margins’ to sort out the untidy and the messy. Geoffrey Herrera’s article,2 ‘The Politics of Bandwidth’, undoubtedly contributes to offering a more precise (or at least, less messy) framework for the analysis of political implications of global information networks.3 I find his approach very convincing, and few among academics, politicians and business leaders and the

1 For a valuable list see fn.2 in Geoffrey Herrera, ‘The Politics of Bandwidth: International Political Implications of a Global Digital information Network’, Review of International Studies, 28 (2002), pp. 93–122. Other examples may include Karl Deutsch, ‘The Impact of Communications Upon the Theory of ,’ in A. S. Abdul, Theory of International Relations (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1968), pp. 74–92, Howard H. Frederick, Global Communications and International Relations (Celmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishing, 1993), Amid Mowlana Global Information and World Communication (London: Sage, 1997), and Jerry Everard, Virtual States. The and Boundaries of the Nation-State (London and New York: Routledge, 2000). 2 Herrera, ‘The Politics of Bandwidth’. 3 Herrera stresses the uniqueness and integration of a single information network, composed of different infrastructures, media and protocols, but unified by universal digitalisation. I prefer to maintain the emphasis on multiplicity and lack of true inter-operability as more correct from the technical point of view, and thus will use ‘networks’ as plural. Furthermore, the degree of integration apparently assumed by Herrera is still several years away. 139 140 Giampiero Giacomello public opinion would doubt the growing economic and social importance of ‘electronic prowess’.4 But I also believe that, given the complexity and novelty of the topic, it also demands more accuracy (we are left with the messy and the untidy, do not forget that). In this reply to his article, I will begin with reviewing the shared assumptions, and then proceed to analyse the issue that Herrera did not tackle in detail, namely the implications of being a democratic state. This crucial differen- tiation may have tremendous influence on the three-player structure, and hence deeply affect the evolution of digital information networks.

The primacy of politics and the three-player structure

First and foremost, most of the time, politics guides technology and not vice versa. When the state decides to put enough resources behind a scientific project, the outcome can be as remarkable as putting men on the moon or splitting the atom.5 The leading position of politics, however, does not mean that policymakers and other elected officials are swift at understanding the political implications of technological transformations. Furthermore, politics may be in command, but its implementation is always done via national legal structures (that is, by bills into laws), which are also slow to reflect changes. In this respect, a case such as cloning technology, where have to react constantly to new scientific developments, is rather telling. The consequence of this situation, namely an image of the slowness of the state (both as apparatus and entity), certainly does not enhance the perception of the state’s centrality in technological development in the eyes of public opinion. If this is the case, then modern technologies (not only mature information networks) will indeed hinder the state’s economic and political control, and then trigger that transformation of the international system that Herrera describes.6 Second, Herrera’s identification of the three-way political struggle between states, firms and individuals instead of the standard (and sometimes futile) ‘opposing pairs of possibilities’ (for example, strong or weak state, wealth or poverty, and so on), as the key to appreciating the effects of modern information networks is certainly convincing.7 Yet, this predicament requires greater analytical efforts on the part of scholars of international politics, and makes forecasting even more difficult.8 Game

4 On the ‘Electronic National Prowess’ (ENP) measure to replace GNP as indicator of national status see Daniel Franklin, ‘The Next Measure of National Machismo’, The World in 2001 (The Economist Publications, 2001), pp. 116–19. 5 For an analysis of the rise of the ‘scientific state’ see Susan Strange, States and Markets (London: Pinter Publishers, 1988). 6 Herrera, ‘The Politics of Bandwidth’, p. 96. 7 Ibid., p. 95. This trilateral approach has been used by other authors. See for instance Giampiero Giacomello, ‘The Digital Challenge: National Governments and the Control of the Internet’, (unpublished Ph.D thesis, European University Institute Fiesole, 2001). Herrera (p. 95) distinguishes individuals as ‘consumers’ and ‘citizens’. 8 Forecasting and predicaments have long been demonstrated to be out of reach for scholars of international relations, but the development of a few more ‘quasi-laws’ would certainly increase the credibility of the field as a whole. For an in-depth investigation of this issue, see John Lewis Gaddis, ‘International Relations Theory and the End of the Cold War’, in Sean M. Lynn-Jones and Steven E. Miller (eds.) The Cold War and After: Prospect for Peace, expanded edition (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1993). A reply to ‘The Politics of Bandwidth’ 141

Theory demonstrates that charting the number of available strategies in a three- player game is a demanding task.9 Moreover, mathematicians and physicians in celestial mechanics have tried for centuries to measure the simultaneous, interlocking effects of three objects.10 Calculating the odds of all the possible combinations of interest coalitions under circumstances of shifting alliances (that is, with more than one move in the game) is certainly a challenging endeavour. Yet, there is another, more disturbing effect of the three-player structure, namely when one player, under the proper circumstances, can significantly influence the evolution of digital information networks, much more than the other two would like to see. Individuals can be consumers, citizens or civil liberties activists, legally defending their rights, but if individuals ‘jump across the fence’ into illegality and develop a structure, they become organised crime, a would- be fourth player that is far more dangerous for the international system than any of the others. Unsurprisingly, Susan Strange considered organised crime as the major threat to the world system,11 while states and firms still seem reluctant to give this phenomenon its proper consideration.

Globalisation? Why not ‘OECD-isation’?

Thirdly, digital information networks are undoubtedly one of the critical factors of globalisation, as Herrera correctly points out.12 Globalisation, however, is a label that can be applied almost to any phenomena that, even mildly, exceed locality. Moreover, the concept behind the catchword is equally undetermined to the point that scholars have long given up agreeing on a common definition, and the term is now used as freely and frequently as words like ‘progress’ or ‘civic society’.13 Since

9 Avinash Dixit and Susan Skeath notes that the most obvious difference between the two- and three- player game is the complexity of the game tree. Avinash Dixit and Susan Skeath, Games of Strategy, (New York: W.W. Norton, 1999), p. 58. If the ‘three players’ are further subdivided, for example firms competing for certain standards and consumers as spoilers or supporters of different technologies, the complexity of the game equally increases. 10 This riddle is know as the ‘three-bodies problem’. In addition to Newton, mathematicians such as Eulero, Lagrange, and Poincaré studied the problem and contributed to its resolution, but it was the Finnish astronomer Karl Frithiof Sundman (1873–1949) who produced a definitive and general solution in the early 20th century. Sundman’s infinite series solution can now be simply modelled by modern computers. For an introduction to the three-bodies problem see . Incidentally, roughly the same argument was used during the Cold War in support of the greater stability of the bipolar system vis à vis multipolar systems. However, physics never said (and I have not either) that a system with three objects is unstable, but, simply, that the interactions of the three objects are much more complex to calculate. 11 Susan Strange, The Retreat of the State: The Diffusion of Power in the World Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), p. 121. 12 Herrera, ‘The Politics of Bandwidth’, p. 100. 13 For (a few) different ways of using the expression see Henry Cavanna (ed.), Governance, Globalization and the European Union (Dublin: Four Courts, 2002), Martin Shaw, Theory of the Global State: Globality as an Unfinished Revolution (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001), Robert Sykes, Bruno Palier, and Pauline M. Prior (eds.), Globalization and European Welfare States: Challenges and Change (New York: Palgrave, 2001), Victor Roudometof, Nationalism, Globalization, and Orthodoxy: The Social Origins of Ethnic Conflict in the Balkans (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 2001), and Harold James, The End of Globalization: Lessons from the Great Depression (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2001). 142 Giampiero Giacomello near 95 per cent of the world traffic of digital communications and financial trans- actions is sent to and received by a country that is an OECD member, a more correct description of the occurrence made possible by digital information networks would be ‘OECD-isation’.14 Admittedly this alternative terminology would probably appeal less to ‘globalist’ and ‘anti-globalist’ camps alike. Herrera accurately observes that the economies of peripheral states have always been more susceptible to the alterations of the international economy. What really startles observers now is the extent to which the economic of even advanced industrialised countries are deeply affected by the mishaps of the world economy.15 As nation states’ control over economic declines and other economic actors, such as holders of economic assets or producers of dominant goods, increase their influence in the same realm, non-structural interaction technologies (like digital information networks) bring about unparalleled system transformations. Another limit of the structure proposed by Herrera is that it can work only with network technologies, and, among these, especially with communication technolo- gies. Herrera limits his investigation to a ‘mature, digital information network’. By so doing, he fails to acknowledge, at least, that there are other technologies that may also provoke unforeseeable modifications of the international system. The three- player structure works with digital networks because users have been and are still actively involved in their growth and development, as in the case of the Internet or of digital cryptography, which Herrera specifically analyses.16 In which technological sector, other than software and networking, is there anything like ‘open source’ initiatives or the Request for Comments (RFC) procedure?17 Thus, Internet users still have far more influence on the evolution of that digital network than individuals, whether consumers or civil rights advocates, have with any other technology. Travellers do not enjoy the same ‘power’ in the technologies of mass tourism; biotechnologies and organically-modified food will probably have greater effects on the health and quality of life of individuals than the Internet, and yet the future of these technologies will remain under the control of a handful of private companies. Other technologies that may have long-term consequences for large portions of the world population, such as space exploration and nuclear energy, will stay in the hands of a few national governments.

14 See, for instance, the last Internet Domain Survey done by the Internet Software Consortium in January 2002. In this survey, computers with a generic domain name such as .com, .edu or a country specific domain name such as .uk or .jp, are queried. The figures resulting from such queries give us a rather accurate idea of the most ‘networked’ countries in the world. Putting aside the generic domains, within the 20 most networked countries, only two ( and Taiwan) were not members of the OECD. All the 25 OECD members were within the top 30 networked countries. In 2001, 94 per cent of all the secure servers (that is, computers that are used for secure commercial and financial transactions and, hence, for electronic commerce) and 95.6 per cent of all the host computers were in OECD countries. OECD, ‘Internet and Electronic Commerce Indicators Update’, . 15 Herrera, ‘The Politics of Bandwidth’, p. 100. 16 Ibid., p. 113–17. 17 An ‘open source’ initiative supplies access to the ‘source code’ (that is, the core) of a software product, so that other independent software developers can refine and improve the product, provided that participants follow a commonly agreed code of conduct. The RFCs procedure was first devised by network engineers working on the Internet. It implies that, in order to achieve the status of ‘technical standard’ for the Internet, draft suggestions for modifications should be made available to the loose community of network engineers and scientists (as in a sort of peer review). Comments and proposed changes are then integrated in the final blueprint. A reply to ‘The Politics of Bandwidth’ 143

What is missing in here?

All these observations, I believe, somehow refine Herrera’s assumptions. But the single most important factor that Herrera neglects is that the three-player structure can only occur under the condition of democracy. States are not all the same.18 can take (and shape) more information because their societies are familiar with the free exchange of information.19 Public opinion in democratic states has far more ‘access points’ to , than its counterparts in autocratic regimes.20 Individuals acting in a democratic system command more ‘voice oppor- tunities’ with their own governments.21 Empirical studies have finally begun to explore the virtuous circle linking democracy, the exchange of information and digital communications.22 In conclusion, Herrera uncovers the elements of change in an emerging inter- national balance of power, but leaves the question of where this transformation may leave us open. Uncertainty is the norm in international politics and, as I argued above, unpredictability is to be expected with this new emerging structure. But if Herrera is right (and I think he is), then the dynamics of international politics will resemble more and more the dynamics of domestic politics, and with this, we are left with at least one certainty. Domestically, democracy rests on civil liberties. After 11 September 2001, a portion of public opinion in some advanced democracies seemed willing to trade a substantial share of those liberties for security, for which the state retains respon- sibility. 23 This trade-off will negatively affect, first and foremost, the digital informa- tion network, when no hard evidence is now available that international terrorism plans to turn this network into its main tool to attack Western societies. Para- doxically, if these most unfortunate conditions were to be spurred by fear and the need for greater certainty about the future, then the world would truly become a capricious place in which to live.

18 It would be unfair, however (and plainly wrong) to argue that Herrera supports the contrary. Indeed, no serious scholar would uphold such a simplistic view of international politics. 19 Robert O. Keohane and Joseph S. Nye, ‘Power and Interdependence in the Information Age’, Foreign Affairs, 77 (1998), pp. 81–94. 20 Thomas Risse-Kappen, ‘Ideas Do Not Float Freely: Transnational Coalitions, Domestic Structures and the End of the Cold War’ in Richard Ned Lebow and Thomas Risse-Kappen (eds.) International Relations Theory and the End of the Cold War (New York: Columbia University Press, 1995), pp. 187–222. 21 The concept of ‘voice opportunities’, from Albert Hischman’s voice, loyalty and exit classification, is discussed in Joseph Grieco, ‘The Maastricht Treaty, Economic Monetary Union and the Neo-Realist Research Program’, Review of International Studies, 21, pp. 21–40. 22 Christopher R. Kedzie, ‘Communication and Democracy: Coincident Revolutions and the Emergent Dictator’s Dilemma’, unpublished Ph.D thesis, RAND Graduate School, Santa Monica (1996) and Giacomello, ‘The Digital Challenge’. 23 See for instance, The Economist, ‘How the World Has (or Hasn’t) Changed’, 27 October 2001, p. 11, The Economist, ‘What September 11th Really Wrought’, 12 January 2002, pp. 23–5.