<<

Marcus Taylor Success for Whom? An Historical-Materialist Critique of in

I. Introduction1 Aftertheproblematicdecadeofthe1990s,thatsaw majorénancialcrisesravagetheeconomiesofEast Asia,MexicoandRussia,Chile hasbecome arare commodityfortheinstitutionscommittedtouphold- ing neoliberalism onaglobal scale.Whilstformer favouriteshavebecometarnishedbycrisis,Chileis stillcelebrated asamodel ofsuccessful neoliberal developmenttobeadmiredandemulatedbyother countriesinLatinAmericaandbeyond.Thisassess- mentisbasedonChile’seconomicperformancein the 1990sthat,asunderlined byEduardoAninat, formerlyChileanMinisterof Finance(1994–9)and nowdeputy managingdirectorof theIMF,wasa periodof vigorousandunprecedented expansion withanaverageannualGDP growthof6.5%.2 Fur- thermore,thesameauthorclaimsthat,despitethe

1 TheauthorwouldliketothankDanielChernilo,SimonClarke,Susanne Soederberg,Alejandro Colás,Adam David Morton,and the HM editorial board forconstructivecriticismofanearlierdraft.Researchforthispaperwasaidedbya grant from the University ofCambridge thatenabled interviews tobecarried out withlabourorganisationsandsocialmovementsin,June2000.Theauthor acknowledgesthekindhelpofJoseBengoa. 2 Aninat2000,p.2.

HistoricalMaterialism,volume10:2(45–75) © KoninklijkeBrillNV,Leiden,2002 Alsoavailableonline–www.brill.nl 46 ï Marcus Taylor recessioncausedbythefalloutfromtheAsiancrisisinthelate1990s,Chile isonceagainsettolead the wayforLatinAmericannationsby resuming healthygrowthinthenewmillennium. Chile hasreceived allthemoreaccoladesfromthemouthpieces of the WashingtonConsensusbecauseitssuccess,asstatedinarecentIMFwork- ingpaper,hasbeenduealmostentirelyto‘goodpolicies’andan‘improved politicalsituation’.3 Firstly,the improved politicalsituationconsistsin the ending ofthePinochetandareturntoelectoralin 1990,markedbytheelectionofacoalitionofcentreandcentre-left parties knownasthe‘Concertación’.Thistransitionissuggestedtohave‘reduced theuncertainty aboutthe rules ofthe politicalandeconomicgame’ and therebypermittedmarketforcestoactinamannerundistortedbyworries overfuturepoliticalcomplications.4 Secondly,the‘goodpolicies’celebrated bytheIMFareatenaciousadherencetoneoliberalprinciplesreèectedinthe maintenanceanddeepeningoftheneoliberaleconomicdevelopmentmodel putinplaceunderthePinochetdictatorship(1973–90).Thosestandingbe- hindChile’sdevelopmentstrategyhaveapplaudedthe‘maturebehaviour’ oftheConcertaciónrégime,whichhasexhibitedéscalprudenceratherthan pursuing‘irresponsibleexpansionistpolicyandbeingprisonersofeconomic ’.5 Insum,theIMFattributestheChileansuccesspreciselytothe abilityofthenewelectedgovernmenttogivefullreigntothefreedomofthe marketandtoshield itfrompossible‘distortions’thatwouldcompromise itsroleastheoptimumresourceallocator. Thisarticleutilisesanhistorical-materialistanalysistoprobebeneaththe surfaceoftheChilean ‘success’ story.An historicalfocusonthe changing relationsbetween state,capitalandlabourallowsadeeper explanationof Chile’seconomicexpansioninthe 1990s,whilstconcurrentlyenabling the articletobroachthe criticalissue of the socialimplicationsofthisformof accumulation.ItisarguedthatChileanneoliberalrestructuring,implemented withinanenvironmentofsystematicrepressionunderthePinochetrégime, wasadesperateandbrutalattempttore-establishtheconditionsforcapital accumulationwithinthe contextof deep crisis.Furthermore,in the1990s,

3 JadresicandZahler2000. 4 JadresicandZahler2000,p.29. 5 Weyland1999,p.65. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 47 withprecipitousconditionsintheglobalpoliticaleconomyandtheemergence ofanelectedrégimecommittedtoassuringapoliticalandsocialenvironment conducivetocapitalaccumulationbymaintainingtheprofoundsubordina- tionoflabourtocapital,Chileindeedexperiencedaprimary-productexport boom.Thisexportboomunderscored thecelebrated ratesof GDP growth andconstitutestheessenceofthemuch-heraldedChilean‘success’.Neverthe- less,thebasisforthis‘success’ispreciselyaformofsocialrelationscharacter- isedbytheperpetuationofalow-paidandstronglydisciplinedlabourforce. This,inturn,hasgivenrisetoaprofoundlyinequitablesocietymarkedbya dramaticpolarisationofwealth.Inthisrespect,thearticledemonstratespro- foundasymmetriesinherentinChileanneoliberaldevelopmentthatformno partoftheofécialdiscourseofsuccess.Thisisbecausesuchcontradictions areprofoundlyatoddswiththeIMF’sfableofaChileansuccessstoryachieved throughthemediumofuniversallybeneécialfreemarketsabettedbysound governmentalpolicy.

II. The crisis of ISI capital accumulation and the emergence of dictatorial domination The originsof Chileanneoliberalismlayinthecrisisof the priorformof capitalistaccumulation,knownasimportsubstitutionindustrialisation(ISI). Thisaccumulationstrategywasbaseduponthepromotionofendogenous industrialdevelopment viaKeynesian-style stateintervention.In orderto nurturedomesticindustrialproduction,thestateengagedinsubsidiestothe industrialsector,manipulationofexchangeratestocheapenmachineryand technologicalimports,andhightariffsonforeignconsumergoods.Alongside industrialproductionfordomesticmarkets,exportofrawmaterialsremained acriticalfeatureofthedevelopmentstrategy.Thesewerenecessaryto generateforeigncurrencyfortheimportoftechnologyandcapitalgoods.ISI initiallyresultedinrelativelyhighgrowthlevelsthroughoutLatinAmerica. Thisinitialsuccess,however,waspredicated upon expandingmarketsfor rawmaterialsexportsowingtoexpansioninthecapitalistcoreandtheexis- tenceofcapitalreservesaccumulatedduringtheexportboomengendered byWorldWarTwo. The ISI modeofaccumulationalsoservedtotransformsocialstructures within LatinAmerica.Byfostering domesticindustry,the stateaided the 48 ï Marcus Taylor growthofadomesticindustrialbourgeoisieandurbanmiddleclass,whilst thetraditionalland-owningoligarchiessufferedaterminaldecline.InChile, industry’sshare of GDP between 1940and1960increasedby onethirdto 22.2%whilstagriculture fell from14.9%to10.1%.6 Moreover,anecessary corollarytotheexpansionoftheindustrialsectorwasthegrowthandconsoli- dationofanurbanworkingclass.Aspeasantslefttheruralsphereforemploy- mentintherapidlyexpandingurbancentres,theemergenceofa removedfromthetraditionalformsofdominanceexertedinthecountryside constitutedapotentialthreattothedominanceofthebourgeoisie.Organised labourandradicalpoliticalparties–particularlytheCommunistandSocialist parties–weregrowinginsizeand,despiteageneralinabilitytoovercome factionalismatthenationallevel,constitutedanimportantpoliticalforce.7 Emerging fromthese contradictions,anew formofthestatedeveloped alongsidethe ISI accumulationmodel.Contrarytocorporatistmethodsof institutionalisingthelabourmovementseeninotherpartsofLatinAmerica (particularlyandMexico),theChileanstatesoughttoregulatethe relations between capitalandlabourviainterventionistmethodsinthe realmofdistribution,such asindexed wages,subsidised basicgoodsand thedevelopmentofamodestwelfaresystem.Throughinterventiontogrant labouragrowing shareof thesocialproduct,thestateattemptedtohar- nesstheworking classestocapitalistdevelopment,checkthegrowthof subversiveideologies,andprovidetheindustrialandsocialcalmnecessary forsustainedaccumulationandtheexpandedreproductionof . Furthermore,thegrowing purchasing powerof theChileanworking class providedanoutletforthedomesticallyproducedconsumergoods.Assuch, theChilean casecouldbecomparedtoLipietz’sdescriptionof ‘peripheral Fordism’.8 However,unlike thesuggestionsofLipietz’sanalysis,thisform ofthestatedidnotariseinresponsetoconditionsinthecapitalistcorein thelate1960sbuthadclearlybeenindevelopmentsincethecollapseofthe oligarchicstateinthe1930s.Moreover,thedevelopmentoftheinterventionist stateformwasaprocessdrivenbystruggle.Theorganisedlabourmovement inChileretainedsizeableautonomyandideologicalvigourandmadefrequent

6 Fortín1985,p.205. 7 SeeRoddick1989. 8 Lipietz1982. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 49 demandsupon thestatethatoften necessitatedmaterialorpoliticalcom- promisesinordertochecktheradicalisationofsuchmovements. Theinterventionistformofthestatewasexpandedwiththe‘Revolution inLiberty’ programmedeveloped by the ChristianDemocratgovernment ofEduardoFrei (1964–70).Frei’sstatedintentionwastopursue socially progressivereformwithina‘neocapitalist’modelofdevelopmentthat wouldcombinestateinterventioninkeyindustries(particularlymining)with substantialforeigninvestment.Theprogrammewasbuoyedbyconsiderable USénancingthroughtheforProgress–aforeignpolicyinitiative intended tostaveoffrevolutioninLatinAmericabypromotingmoderate socialchange.Nevertheless, the ISI modeofdevelopment andcongruent politicalsystemsenteredintocrisisthroughoutLatinAmericaduringthelater 1960sand. TheChileancrisiswasonemomentoftheworld-wideslowingofgrowth inthelate1960sthatturnedintostagnationinthe1970s.Ascountriesemploying ISIstrategieshadremaineddependentonexportingkeyagriculturalandraw materialsinordertogenerateforeignearningsnecessarytoimportindustrial inputsandcapitalgoods,theywerevulnerabletothevicissitudesofworld marketprices.Chile,withitscontinualdependenceoncopperexports,which intheearly1970sconstituted80%ofexportearnings,feltthedownturnin theworldeconomyparticularlysharply.Thisledtogrowingpublicindebted- ness,greaterdependencyonforeigncapitaland,concurrently,greaterpressures toreducesocialspendingandincreaseinvestment.Moreover,owingtothe redistributiveelementoftheChileanISImodel,labourwastakinganincreas- ingportionofthesocialproduct.Inèationwasrisingandbusinessinterests clamouredforacaponwageincreases.Inthesecircumstances,thestatedrew heavilyonforeigncredittoénanceincreasedinvolvementintheeconomy inanattemptintendedtofacilitatetheexpansionofcapitalonanaugmented scale. Underthesepressures,theChileanstatestartedtobreakapartinthe late1960s.Asamomentofcapitalistsocialrelations,thestateis‘stamped throughout,inallitsinstitutions,proceduresandideology,withthecontra- dictionsof capital’.9 Withinthecircumstances of the Chilean crisis,these contradictionsbecamemoreevident,asmanifestedthroughincreasedclass

9 Holloway1991,p.109. 50 ï Marcus Taylor struggleandagrowingéscalcrisisofthestate.Ontheonehand,mobilised labourandsocialgroupsmaintainedtheir demandsonthestateatatime whenrevenueswerefalling.Ontheother,capitalwasdemandingagreater shareofthesocialproductinordertostaveoffthedeepeningcrisis.Therefore, whilstredistributiveelementsandguaranteed wageriseswerebecoming progressivelyhardertosustain,cutsinsocialspendingafter1968increased socialunrestandpropelledtheconfrontationalmobilisationofwell-organised union movements.The latter,somewhatironically,hadbeneétedfromthe government’sattempttofomentpopularsupportfortheRevolutioninLiberty programmebyencouragingunionisation. The growing polarisationof forcesbehind thosecommittedtore-estab- lishingtheconditionsforsustainedcapitalaccumulationandthoseseeking agreaterlevelofredistributioncreatedahotlycontested1970election.The SocialistSalvadorAllende,headingacoalitionofleftpartiesunderthebanner,waselectedpresidentwith36.6%ofthevote,ascomparedwith 35.2%polled by the right-wing candidate.Allende’sresponsetothecrisis wasadeepening ofthedistributivemechanisms,coupledtoaprogramme thatnationalisedkeysectorsoftheeconomy.Theattemptedmixofelements ofstate-withinacapitalistframeworkprovedunabletoresolvethe crisisand,moreover,engenderedinsurmountablepoliticalbarriers.Thepolit- icalforcesoftheRightvehementlyopposedtheprogramme,whilstcapital èightandinvestmentstrikesplungedtheeconomyintofurther woes. Conversely,theAllende régime feltcompelledtodeepen itscommitment toredistributionandfullemployment, thusundermining stillfurther the conditionsforcapitalaccumulation.By1973,deepeconomiccrisisandhigh inèationwascoupledtoconsiderableclassstruggleandagovernmentthat continuedtodirectlythreatentheinterestsofthedomesticbourgeoisieand foreignérms.Withinthesecircumstances,the bourgeoisieandalliesper- ceived,inGuillermoO’Donnell’swords,‘agreatthreattothesurvivalofthe basiccapitalistparametersofsociety’.10 Theresponsewascounterrevolution throughcoup,theformationofanauthoritarianstate,andarestruc- turingprocessthatwouldimplementafundamentalshiftintherelationship betweenstate,capitalandlabour.

10 O’Donnell1979,p.295. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 51

III. The military régime and authoritarian neoliberalism ThepoliticalcrisisthathadescalatedduringtheFreiandAllende régimes culminatedin theseizureof powerin 1973by amilitaryjunta headedby GeneralAugustoPinochet.The militaryleadership thatviolently assumed controlof thestateforgedanarrowalliancewithacoalitionofbourgeois interestswhichprovideditsprincipalsocialbase.Together,themilitaryrégime anditscivilianalliessoughtasolutiontothecrisisthatwouldre-establish theconditionsforstrongcapitalaccumulationaswellaseliminatethepolitical forcesthathadthreatenedthefutureofcapitalisminChile.Althoughthere wasdisagreementbetweendifferentcapitalsandwithinthestateconcerning howtoproceed,theveryprofundityofthecrisisofISIdevelopmentandthe growinginèuenceofinternationallyorientatedconglomerateswithaheavy concentrationin liquidassetsenabled aprojectforradicalrestructuringto gainascendancyintheyearsimmediatelyafterthecoup.11 Underthetechnocraticguidanceofthe‘ChicagoBoys’–Chileanneoclassical economiststrainedattheUniversityofChicago–thePinochetrégimeenvis- agedarestructuringprogrammebasedaroundthreecardinalpillars.Combined together,these wouldredeéne Chile’smodeof accumulationbyradically changingthemannerofitsintegrationwiththeworldeconomy.Firstly,the programmesoughttore-establishChileasaproétablesiteforglobalcapital byremovingtheexistingbarrierstothemovementofthelatter.Thesemeasures includedtheabolitionoftaxesonwealthandcapitalgains,andthewithdrawal ofrestrictionsonproétremittancesbyforeigncapital.Secondly,itcomprised amajorreorientationofnationalproductiontowardstheworldmarket,i.e. aspecialisationinexport-orientatedproductionthatwouldgenerateanew productivestructurebased aroundagro-exportandrawmaterialexport. Thirdly,itproposedasigniécantwithdrawalofthe state’sactivitiesinthe economythroughlarge-scaleprivatisationandstrictéscaldiscipline that incorporatedasubstantialreductioninstatespendingonsocialexpenditures. Tosolvethepoliticalcrisisandtoclearthewayfortheforthcoming restructuringofChileansociety,thestateengagedinapolicyoféercerepres- sionthatserved toannihilatethepoliticalforcesthathadchallenged the basisofChileancapitalism.Theprimaryachievement of therepression wasthedecapitationoforganisedlabour,thedestructionofautonomousand

11 SeeSilva1996,Chapters2–3. 52 ï Marcus Taylor politicallyactiveunionmovements,andthegeneralisedsuppressionofpolit- icalexpressionsofopposition.In total,tensofthousandsof activistswere murdered,jailedorexiled.Therepressionwasatitsmostintenseintheimme- diatepost-coupyears,althoughitremainedstrongthroughouttherégime, withtheperiod 1984–8alonebeing markedby163politicalmurders,446 casesofand1,927politicalarrests,allcommittedwithlegalimpunity.12 Moreover,politicalviolencewassupplemented byanoppressivelabour policythatinvolvedtheprohibitionofstrikes,thedissolutionofunions(until 1979,whentheywereallowedtoreconstituteinacontrolledmanner),sup- pressionofwagesandareformoflabourlegislationthatrelaxedregulations andallowedadramaticdecreaseinérm’ssocialsecurityandtaxbeneétsto workers. Theassaultonorganisedlabourprovidedthenecessarypoliticalclimate in whichtodramaticallycurtailworkers’standardsofliving.Crisiswasattributed towagerisesandtheexpansionofconsumptivestateexpenditureunderthe ISImodeofdevelopmentandthepopuliststateapparatusthatundermined theproétabilityofcapitalistenterprisewhilstreinforcingmarketdistortions. Inresponse,theérstelementofPinochet’sliberalisationprogrammeentailed thefreeingofprices,deregulationoftrade,withdrawalofrestrictionsonthe free mobilityof capital,andremovalofbasicconsumergoodssubsidies. Together,thesemeasuresprecipitatedaprofoundcontractionofdemandas recessionsetinandwagesplungedtoundertwo-thirdsoftheirformervalue intwoyears.13 Theshareofwagesintotalincomefelldramaticallyfrom62.8% in1972–oneofthehighestinLatinAmerica–to41.1%in1976–oneofthe lowest.14 Unemploymentclimbedabove15%andallthesefactorswereexac- erbatedbyasharpreductioningovernmentsocialexpenditure.15 Concurrently, intheagrariansphere,45%ofpeasantswhohadgainedlandintheFreiand Allende agrarianreformslosttheirpropertyrights.Muchofthislandwas notreturnedtothelarge latifundia butwaspurchasedby newagro-export enterprisesthatformedacorepartoftheemerginglargeeconomicgroups.16 In response,the exodusfromthe countrysidetothe citiesgathered pace,

12 PetrasandLeiva1994,p.21. 13 Fortín1985,p.163. 14 PetrasandLeiva1994,p.26. 15 Torche2000,p.557. 16 GwynneandKay1997. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 53 increasingthepressureonwagesintheurbancentres.17 Overall,bycreating alarge reserve armyanddropping thevalue of labour-power tounprece- dentedlevelssoastogreatlyincreasetheamountofsurpluslabourextracted inproduction,thePinochetrégimesoughttore-establishtheproétabilityof capitalisminChile. A secondprincipal aspectof the structuraladjustmentprocesswasthe re-privatisationofindustries,banksandlandsthathadbeennationalisedor redistributedinthepreviousepoch.ThisprocesswasintendedtoreverseFrei andAllende’ssocialisationofpropertyin ordertoreassertthe primacyof themarket.However,theprivatisationofstateenterprisesoccurredatwell belowtheirmarketvalue.Fortínnotesthat:‘Forasampleof41companies andbanksrepresenting60%ofthevalueofallcompaniessold,itisestimated thatthepriceofsalewasoftheorderof70%ofthenetvalueoftheassets ofthecompanies’.18 Thisthereforerepresentedasigniécantstatesubsidyto theemergingeconomicgroupsandfacilitatedtheconcentrationofproduc- tiveapparatusinthehandsofasmallconglomerationofeconomicgroups.19 The primarybaseofthese economicgroups wasin the énancialsector where,owing torégime policy,they obtainedpreferential accesstointer- nationalcredit.Firstly,thisallowedthesecompaniestoloandomestically atextremely inèatedlevelsowingtotherégime’spolicyof unregulated interestrates.Secondly,thelargeeconomicgroupstookfulladvantageofthis accesstoforeign capitaltofacilitatethe purchase of banks andindustries soldthrough Pinochet’sprivatisationprogrammeand,thereby,obtaining majorityholdsonthemostdynamicaspectsoftheneweconomy(refer to table below).Assuch,stimulatedbystatepolicy,includingthe erectionof aprivatepensionsschemecontrolledbythemajoreconomicgroups,theaccel- eratedconcentrationandcentralisationofcapitalinChilewasastounding. Withinthedecade,ahandfulofmajoreconomicgroupsgrewtocontrolsome 68%oftheassetsofallcorporationsoperatingontheChileanstockmarket.

17 Riesco1999. 18 Fortín1985,p.173. 19 Notably,although it provided substantialsubsidies forforeign (primarily US) purchaseofthecopperindustry,themilitaryrégimeretainedcontrolof, thehugelyproétablenationalisedcoppercompany.CODELCOaccountedfor39%of Chileancopperexportsandtherevenues werelargely usedtoénancetherégime’s militaryapparatus(Riesco1999). 54 ï Marcus Taylor

Theyalsoaccountedfor45%ofallforeigncapitalborrowedasof1977and, by1980,42%ofallbanking capitalinChile and60%ofallavailableand extendedcredit.20

ConcentrationintheExportSector1988.

Industry NumberofLargeFirms IndustryShare

Mining 7 97.1 Agriculture 8 80.6 ForestProducts 5 78.4 FishProducts 6 51.1 Food 6 67.3 WineandBeverage 2 70.2 Wood 7 78.6 Paper,Cellulose 2 90.0 ChemicalProducts 2 71.4

FromPetrasandLeiva1994,p.36.

Despiteclamorousinternationalacclaimbytheadvocatesofmonetarism,the trajectoryoftherestructuredChileaneconomywasunimpressive.Afterthe immediaterecession,therewasareturntogrowthinthelate1970sandearly 1980sknownastheérst‘economicmiracle’.Nevertheless,in1981,theGNP wasstillbelow thatachievedin 1970.Indeed, between 1974and1981,the GDP growthrateaveraged2.1%,oneofthelowestinLatinAmerica.Almost allgrowthwasconcentratedinnon-traditionalexportswithfreshfruit, lumberandforestrygrowingfrom7.6%ofexportsin1971to20.5%in1981.21 Concurrently,therapidopening of theeconomydestroyedmuchexist- ingindustrialactivity,especiallyin metalandmachinery production,the mechanicalandelectricalsectorsandthecapitalgoodssubsector. Furthertalkof‘miracles’wassilencedbyasevererecessionin1982–3.The deregulationofeconomicactivityandtheliberalisationoftradeandcapital èowshadprompted anenormousexpansionof creditfromprivateinter- nationalbanks.Between1975and1979,US$6,593.6millionofcreditentered

20 PetrasandLeiva1994,pp.23–4. 21 PetrasandLeiva1994,p.25. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 55

Chile,equaltoéveyearsofcopperexports.A sizeableportionofthiscredit wasusedbythestatetoservicethehugeandrapidlygrowingpublicdebt. Nevertheless,mostwaschannelledthroughthemediumofChile’seconomic groupsintohighlyproétablebutspeculativeshort-terminvestments.However, whentheclimateoftheinternationalénancialmarketsshiftedin1982,the short-termforeign investmentsinChilewere liquidatedatanenormously rapidpace.22 TheChileanbubbleburstascapitalèowsdriedupandheaded tosaferandmoreproétablehavens,particularlytheUSA,whichhadunder- takenmammothincreasesinrealinterestrates(from0.8%in1971–80to11.0% in1982).23 Chilewasonceagainplungedintoadeepcrisis.Productionfell by16.7%,ofécialunemploymenttopped26%,andtheeconomywaspropped uponlybymassivestateintervention.During1983–8,averagegovernment spendingasaproportionofGDP was25.1%,whichwas1.5%higherthanin thepopulistperiod1967–72.24 Furthermore,underextremepressurefroma consortiumofcreditorbanksandtheIMF,therégimeassumedresponsibility forprivateexternaldebt(US$7.7billion),thereby socialisingthedebtsrun upbythecountry’scapitalistsandengaginginlargedebt-for-equityswaps.25 A second‘economicmiracle’from1985–9wascreditedtoPinochet’sadoption ofaso-called‘pragmaticneoliberalism’.26 Thisequatedaérmrecommitment torenewedprivatisation,lowertariffs,furtherprivilegestotherawmaterials exportsector,amoderatere-regulationofcapitalèowsandagreatervoice forthebourgeoisieinthepolicyformationprocess.ThegrowthofGDP was basedonceagainonacombinationofmakinguptheidlecapacitycreated by the severedropin productionduring the recessionperiod,thefurther developmentof the ‘new growthpoles’ in theChileanexporteconomy,a boomintheunproductivesectoroftheeconomy(servicesandénance),and highinternationalpricesforcopper.27 Moreover,predicateduponthepolitic- allyreinforcedsubordinationoflabourtocapital,itwasextremelyinequitable formofgrowth.Thetop-earningquintileoftheChileanpopulationin1989 took57.6%ofthenationalincomeandthebottomquintileobtainedamere

22 Fortín1985,p.186. 23 SeeSoederberg2000. 24 MartínezandDíaz1996,p.66. 25 FazioandRiesco1997. 26 SeeSilva1996,Chapter4. 27 PetrasandLeiva1994,pp.32–3. 56 ï Marcus Taylor

4.3%.28 In1989,stoodat42.2%,with14.9%ofthepopulationliving inconditionsofindigence.29 Deterioratingsocialconditionsfuelled existingpoliticaldiscontent. Emergingprotestagainstthedictatorshiptranscendedclasslinestoinclude theunemployed,workingpoorandmiddleclassesaswellassectionsofthe bourgeoisiewhohadfoundthemselveslockedoutofdecision-makingprocesses since themid-1970s.30 Whilstaneclectic mixture of socialmovementsand clandestinepoliticalorganisationsled the initialprotests,intheyearsfol- lowing 1984,amovementbegan tocoalescearoundagroup ofpoliticians connectedtotheoldpoliticalparties.Thisledtotheemergenceofaformidable centristoppositiongroupin1984calledtheAlianzaDemocrática(Democratic Alliance).TheAlianzaDemocráticawasabletoprosperoverothergroups, particularlythemoreradicalMovimientoDemocráticoPopular,owingtoits willingness toinsertitself intotheauthoritarianpoliticalstructuresandto courtbusinesssupport.ThestrengthoftheAlianzaDemocráticalayin itsabilitytoposeitselfastherespectableoppositionwhichwouldpressfor institutionaliseddemocraticopeningswhilstavoidingtheradicalismofother groups. Despitetheostensiblerecoveryoftheeconomy,thelegacyofseverecrisis andtheunremittingpoliticalmovementagainstthe dictatorshippushed Pinochetintomanoeuvresdesignedtoreaférmitslegitimacy.Hencethedic- tatorinitiatedasustainedcampaigntowinpublic supportforanational plebiscitetobeheldinSeptember1988.Theplebiscitehadbeenscheduled bythedictatorshipin1980aspartofitsnewconstitution.Itwasdesigned toallowtheChileanpeopletochoosebetweenafurthereightyearsofmilitary ruleorareturntociviliangovernment.Sincerelyexpectingacomprehensive victory,therégimearrogantlybelievedthattheplebiscitewouldreinforceits legitimacybydisplayingpopularbacking forthedictatorshipproject. Nonetheless,anddespitethesubstantialmachinemobilisedby the dictatorshipandacontinued environment ofrepression,Pinochet had profoundly misjudgedthe breadthof the anti-dictatorshipmovementand wasforcedtorecognisethevictoryofthe‘no’vote,56%to44%.

28 ColomaandRojas2000,p.537. 29 Schneider1993,p.30. 30 SeeSilva1996. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 57

IV. Concertación 1990–2000 Therejectionofcontinuedmilitaryruleintheplebisciteof1988paved thewayforareturntociviliangovernment,commencingwithnationalelec- tionsinlate1989.Fromthepoliticalforcesthathadcometotheforeinthe AlianzaDemocráticathereemergedapartycoalitioncalledtheConcertación, comprisedprincipallyoftheChristianDemocratandSocialistparties.The term‘concertación’signiées‘comingtogether’andtheconvincingelection victoryofthiscentristcoalitionwaswidelyacceptedassymbolisinganew beginning forChile andthe re-incorporationofthesocialsectorsmargin- alisedduringthePinochetrégime. Nevertheless,whilsttheConcertación’spoliticalsuccesshadbeenpropelled byworking-andmiddle-classsupport,theperiodimmediatelyprecedingthe establishmentofthe érstpost-dictatorship government wasmarkedbya considerableconvergenceofthenewpoliticalélitewithbusinessinterests.A formaldialogueoccurredbetweentheorganisedbodiesofcapitalistinterests andthefuturegovernmentinwhichtheConcertaciónpledgedtorecognise thesanctityofprivateproperty,institutionalisethedictatorship’seconomic model,andmakenodramaticchangestothecountry’ssocialstructure.31 As such,itpromisedtoexercise éscalprudenceandrefrainfrom‘populist’ measuresinordertomaintainthepro-businessclimateofthePinochetyears. In return,Chilean capitalistswouldco-operatewiththenewgovernment, maintaininvestmentandrespondtofuturepolicy initiatives.32 Thisrap- prochementbetweentheConcertaciónleadershipandmajoreconomicgroups setthetonefortheensuingdecade. Withinthiscontext,theConcertación–underthepresidenciesofAylwin (1990–4),Frei(1994–9)and,currently,Lagos(2000–5)–has,inprimetechno- craticstyle,doggedlypursued the consolidationandintensiécationof the neoliberalproject.AsDavidHojmanstates:‘Since1990Pinochetstylepolicies havebeenappliedalmostwithoutmodiécations,althoughthereweresome marginaltaxincreases,therevenuefromwhichwastobedevotedtotheéght againstpoverty’.33 Moreover,theelectoralvictoryofSocialistRicardoLagos inDecember1999hasnotmarkedabreakwithpoliciesofhispredecessors.

31 SeePortales2000.MuñozGomáandCaledón1996. 32 Silva1998,pp.237–40. 33 Hojman1995,p.129. 58 ï Marcus Taylor

TheUSStateDepartmentrecentlyconérmedthat:‘Lagoshasputinplacea top-notcheconomicteam:hisprincipaleconomicadvisorsareU.S.-trained andinternationallyacclaimedfortheirtechnicalexpertise, andthey share Lagos’strongcommitmenttoChile’ssuccessfulfree-marketeconomicmodel’.34 The Concertación’sconstantpreoccupationwithsatisfyingthe needs of capitaltothe detriment of socialconsiderationscanbe relatedtoseveral factors.Firstandforemost,itmustbere-emphasisedthatthestateincapi- talistsocietyisintrinsicallyacapitalist state,predicateduponcapitalistsocial relationsofproduction,andconstrainedtoworkwithintheconénesimposed bysuchrelations.35 Assuch,thepossibilitiesandlimitstostateactionarenot determinedmerely atthe level ofpoliticalrelationsbetween the stateand particularcapitals,36 butalsooperateatamorefundamentallevel through theubiquitouspressurestoguaranteetheexpandedreproductionofsocial capital(orcapital-in-general)uponwhichthematerialreproductionofsociety initscapitalistform–thestateincluded–depends.37 Suchpressuresculmi- nateintendenciestowardsgeneralisedeconomic,politicalandsocialcrisis wheneverexpandedaccumulationishindered(manifestedin,forexample, lackofinvestment,capitalèight,balanceofpaymentsdeterioration,sluggish growth,intenseéscalconstraintsandincreasedsocialunrest–allofwhich werepertinentfeaturesofthe1968–73periodinChile). Moreover,the variouspressures onstateactionareneither engendered, contained,norreconcilablewithinsolelyadomesticframework.Statesexist asmomentsof globalcapitalistrelationsandhavenoindependent exis- tenceoutsideof theèuidcontoursof globalaccumulation.38 Althoughthe relationbetweenstate,capitalandlabourwithinanationalsocialformation constitutesthesocialbasisofcapitalistproduction,thelatterisbutonenec- essarynodalpoint in thecontinualcircuitsof capital.The labour-process indeedfacilitatescapitalvalorisation,butthesurplus-labourcontainedwithin acommodityisonlyrealisedinthesphereofcirculationviapurchaseonthe market.Furthermore,therealisationofsurplus-valueandresumptionofthe money-formdoesnotterminatethecircuitbutmerelymarksonefurtherpoint

34 USStateDepartment2001,p.10. 35 SeeHolloway&Picciotto1991;Clarke1991. 36 AsinfractionalistaccountsoftheChileanstatesuchasFortín1985. 37 Clarke1978,1991. 38 Holloway1995;Burnham2001. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 59 inaperpetualprocess.Onreturningtothemoney-form,capitalmustonce againseekoutproductiveinvestment.Therefore,whilstcapitalmustassume aspeciécspatiallocationwithinanationalsocial-formationfortheinstance ofproduction,thecirculationofmoneycapitalandcommoditycapitaltran- scendsnationalboundaries.Assuch,theessenceofcapitalisglobal,although theglobalityof capitalisnonetheless mediatedthrough the existence of national-stateformationswhichcanalterthenatureoftherelationshipbetween nationallylocatedcapitalandglobalcapitalthroughpoliticalregulation. Therein,theChileanstate’scommitmenttofacilitatingtheexpanded reproductionof capitalthroughthemaintenanceof astrictneoliberal tra- jectorymirrorsthecontinuedcrisisofaccumulationonaglobalscaleandthe changingcharacteroftheglobalpoliticaleconomythatthelatterhasinduced. Thepoliticalprojectofneoliberalismhasprovenubiquitousincountriesacross theglobeasitpurportedlyoffersasolutiontocrisisbyre-establishingthe viabilityofcapitalistaccumulationwithinthenational-stateformthroughthe subordinationofbothstateandsocietytothedisciplineofcapitalasaglobal socialrelation.Thus,intheChileancase,neoliberalpoliciesremainfunda- mentalfortheConcertacióngovernmentinitsquesttocontinuouslyreassert thevalidityofaccumulationwithintheChileannational-statevis-à-visthe parametersimposedbythetrajectoryofglobalaccumulation.Forexample, oneoftheprincipalformsinwhichthedisciplineofcapitalisexercisedupon theactionsofthecontemporaryChileanstateisthroughtheconstant necessitytosignalcreditworthinesstointernationalinvestorsandénancial markets.Asdetailedabove,thestructureoftheChileaneconomyispredi- catedinnosmallmeasure upontheconstantinputofforeigncapital,both FDIandshort-termportfoliocapital.A constantinèuxofcapitalisnecessary toservice high-levels ofprivate-sectordebtandtoimplementthetechno- logicaladvancesnecessaryforsustainedproductivityincreasestokeepChilean productscompetitiveonglobalmarkets.Concurrently,asigniécantdecline in capitalinèowsoracceleratedcapitaloutèowsthreatenstoplunge the Chileaneconomyintoseriouscrisis.39 Inthisrespect,theintrinsicmobilityof capitalinitsmoneyformmeansthat,toattractandretaincapitalwithinthe

39 Forexample,during theAsianCrisis, whichclosedmanymarkets forChilean exports,Chile experienced US$2.1billion ofcapitalèight in 1998alone;IMF2000, p.101. 60 ï Marcus Taylor

Chileansocialformation,requirestheprovisionofthemoststableandproétable investmentenvironmentpossible.This,inturn,ispredicateduponthestate’s adherencetothe‘goodpolicies’taxonomisedbytheIMF,WorldBankand others,andnecessarilyentailsreproducingtheprofound subordination oflabourtocapitalengendered during the militaryrégime’srestructuring programme. Nonetheless,althoughthecapitaliststatefacesconsiderablepressure to subordinateitsactionswithintheconénesimposedbythesocialformofcap- italistreproductioninitsnationalandglobalmoments,thesepressuresdo notexistassomeformofexternalorcoercive‘capitallogic’.Rather,they assertthemselvesandaremediatedthroughcomplexprocessesofpolitical andsocialstruggle experienced inallofthevariousfracturedmoments of capitalistsocialrelations.Hence, theyarepresent atmanylevels, from strugglesoverthenatureoflabourrelations,conèictswithintheinstitution- alisedpoliticalprocess,andindiversesocialmovementsthatchallengethe quotidianformsofstateinterventionintosocialreproduction.Inthefaceof multifariousinstancesofstruggle,thereisnocertaintythatthestatecandis- ciplinelabourorparticularcapitalstorestraindemandswithintheconénes ofthedevelopmentmodel.Indeed,theoftencontradictoryreactionsofthe statetovariedinstancesofconèictcansometimesservetopushtherelations between state,capitalandlabourbeyondthe limitsof the capitalistsocial form.Moreover,thestateisnotastaticthing,butundergoestransformation asparticularstruggleséndexpressionwithinthechangingformofthestate. AsBobFineelaborates,inrelationtotheconcretetrajectoryofpoliticaland socialstruggles,‘fromoneperiodtothenext[thestate]maybecomemore orlessalienatedfromthepeople,moreorlesssubjecttodemocraticcontrol, moreorlessbureaucratic,moreorlessboundbytherulesoflaw,moreor lesspermissiveof working-classorganisations,etc.’40 In thisrespect,itis importanttoemphasisehowthereadinessoftheConcertaciónpoliticalélite toreconcilethemselvestothelimitsoftheneoliberalformofaccumulation isaccentuatedbyboththeweaknessofpopularmovementsafterthecrip- plingexperienceofalmosttwodecadesofrepressivedictatorship,andbythe

40 Fine1984,p.14. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 61 tangibleconsequencesfortheformofthestateimpartedbythisparticular historicaltrajectory. Firstly,despitethedefeatsufferedbythedictatorshipinthe1988plebiscite, thissetbackoccurredwithintheconénesofthepoliticalframeworkthatit hadestablished.Assuch,themilitaryrégimewasnotoverwhelmedbypopular mobilisationand,crucially,itstillretained anextremelypowerful position fromwhichtoinèuencethecharacterofthe‘post-authoritarian’state.Inthe periodbetweentheplebiscitedefeatandtheelectionsof1989,themilitary régimeandcivilianrepresentativesnegotiatedtheconstitutionalframework forthetransitionofpower.Withinthisprocess,therégimeensuredthatthere existedmultipleinstitutionalsafeguards(knownas‘authoritarianenclaves’) toimposemoderationupontheincomingelectedgovernment.Theseincluded theappointmentofdesignatedsenatorsthatwouldensurethattheforcesof thepoliticalRightenjoyedamajorityintheSenate,andanelectoralsystem thatcreatedanover-representationofthepartiesoftheRight.41 Suchpartic- ularitiesofthepost-transitionstate-formhasgreatlyabettedthereconciliation oftheConcertaciónwithaneoliberaltrajectorybyimposingpoliticallimits onthepossibilitiesofgovernmentpolicyandalsobyservingasanextremely convenientmeansbywhichtheConcertaciónhasjustiéeditsmoderationto thepopularconstituency.42 Secondly,therelativestrengthsoforganisedlabourandorganisedcapital in thepost-transitionlandscapeareprofoundly uneven. On theone hand, organisedlaboursufferedalmosttwodecadesofsystematicrepressionfrom whichithasnotrecovered.Whilstvarioussocialmovementshadcertainly playedanimportantroleintheearlystruggleagainstthedictatorship,politi- caloppressionandtheeffectsofextremeeconomicmarginalisationperpetuated weaknessesandfactionalismwithinthesesmallgroups.Concurrently,most

41 ForfurtherdetailsontheseauthoritarianenclavesrefertoPortales2000,Siavelis 2000,Taylor1998. 42 Nevertheless,theargument thatthe perseveranceofauthoritarianpolitical structuresalonecansubstantiallyaccountforpolicycontinuitiesintheConcertación era(mademostforciblybyPetrasandLeiva1994)cannotbesustained.By2001,many ofthese same institutional idiosyncrasies actuallyfavourthe Concertación, with little perceptible change in policyterms. Indeed, President Lagos has stated that the willingness ofthe politicalRight toreform the politicalprocess is becausethe constitutionisnow‘onourside’(FinancialTimes 2001). 62 ï Marcus Taylor threwtheirlimitedweightbehindtheConcertación’selectoralmovementin themid-1980sandbecamelessvisibleafterthevictoryofthelatter.43 Given thepoliticalweaknessoforganisedlabourandothersocialmovements,the Concertaciónwasabletoadoptaheavilyélitist(‘cupular’)styleofpolitics thathasservedtoinsulateitspoliticalcadrefrommoreradicalvoiceswith- inthegrassroots ofthecoalitionparties.44 Ontheotherhand,organised business – represented bythe Confederaciónde ProducciónyComercio (ConfederationofProductionandCommerce,CPC)–emergedstrengthened fromtheepochof‘pragmaticneoliberalism’andhasprovedwellorganised, highlymobilised,prescientlyawareofthepoliticalstrengthstemmingfrom itsconcentratedownershipofthemeansofproduction,andcurrentlyenjoys anactiverelationshipwiththe government.Unsurprisingly,the IMFhas applaudedthispoliticalarrangementasakeyaspectoftheChilean‘success’.

V. State, labour and capital under Concertación The Concertación’scommitmenttoneoliberalism hasbeen amply demon- stratedthroughanacceleratedprivatisationprogramme,thesettingofhigh interestratestodrawinforeigncapital,suppressionoftheexchangerateto promoteexports,the signingoffree tradeagreementswiththeMercosur tradingblock(Argentina,Brazil,Uruguay,),aprospective treaty withtheNAFTA block,andafundamentalandoverridingprioritytomain- tainmacro-economicequilibrium throughlow-inèationandbalanced budgets.Indeed,despitethestrainsofthe1998–9recession,thetotaldebtof the non-énancialpublic sector,bothexternalanddomestic,hasremained about10%ofGDP.45 Thisconérmationofthefundamentalsoftheso-called ‘WashingtonConsensus’constitutesthebasisofthesoundpoliciesthatthe IMFhasvigorouslyapplaudedandthathaveelevatedChiletomodelstatus. With theConcertaciónfortifyingtheopennatureoftheeconomy,the majortrendsofneoliberalaccumulationwitnessedunderPinochethavebeen reproduced.Firstly,thepresenceofforeigncapitalandtransnationalérmsin

43 Roberts1998hasadetailedaccountofthetrajectoryofChileansocialmovement activityduringthePinocheteraandimmediatelyaftertheplebiscitevictory,asdoes delaMaza1999. 44 LucyTaylor1998hasprovidedthemostdetailedaccountofthemarginalisation ofthegrassrootswithintheConcertaciónparties. 45 IMF2000,p.99. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 63 theChileaneconomyhascontinuedtoincrease.Foreigncapitalhasdramat- icallyexpanded itsrole inmanynew sectorssuch aselectricity,banking, insurancebrokering,healthandconstruction.Thishasbeenachievedthrough bothnewgovernmentprivatisationsandthrough thetake-overofChilean companies.Forinstance,theroleofforeigncapitalintheconstructionsector hasgrownfromminimallevelsattheendofthe1980stoasituationinwhich 50%ofinvestmentinthissectorisforeignwhilstcompaniesbackedbyfor- eigncapitalstakesome72%ofpublicworkscontracts.46 Atthesametime,theprocessofcapitalconsolidationwithintheChilean economyhasalsoaugmented.Thelarge Chilean conglomerates,suchas LuksicandAngelini,havegrownsubstantiallythroughmergersandacqui- sitions,ashavemanyforeigntransnationalsandparticularlySpanishowned groups.Anotherelementof thiscentralisationhasbeen aconcentrationof capitalthroughcompetitionwhichled,forexample,totheshrinkingofthe numberofprivatepensionfundcompaniesfromthepeakoftwenty-twoin 1993tothirteenin1996.47 Thishasculminatedinasituationinwhichprac- ticallyallsectorsoftheChileaneconomyarecontrolledbylargeérmsthat, inturn,aresubsidiarypartsofthehandfulofhugeeconomicgroupsbased in the énancialsector.48 Asindicatedabove,these economicgroupshave derivedtheirstatusfrompreferentialaccesstointernationalcreditand domesticpension-fundcapital;bothaspectsemergingfromthespeciécform ofénancialderegulationundertakenduringthePinochetrégime. Attheotherendofthespectrum,theChileanworkingclassiscontinually reproducedasalow-wagelabourforce,afèictedwiththe burden of pre- cariousemploymentandadistinctlackofevenbasiclabourrights.Whilst thestatehasacted,ontheone hand,tobuttressthedominanceofcapital, personiéedinthe large economicgroups,ithassimultaneously actedto maintainthesubservientpositionof labourthroughthepreservationof the principaltenets ofthePinochetrégime’srepressivelabourcode.The cheapnessandèexibilityoflabourwithinthesocialformationisaprimary requisite ofpumpingoutincreasedlevelsof surplus-value,whichis,in turn,fundamentaltoattractingincreasedinvestmentandaccentuatingthe

46 Fazio2000. 47 Fazio&Riesco1997,p.95. 48 MartínezandDíaz1996,p.86. 64 ï Marcus Taylor competitiveadvantageof the particularindustryinthe worldmarket.In thisrespect,thePinochetrégimemaximisedtheconditionsforaprofound subordinationof labourtocapitalbydestroyingthe bodiesof organised labour,promulgatingaregressivelabourcode,andwithdrawingthestate’s formercommitmenttoensuring welfare andemployment thatformed the foundationofthepre-coupsocialpact. Nevertheless,thepoliticallegitimacyoftheConcertacióngovernmentshas restedinnosmallpartupontheirpledge tosocialequity.Intheirelection campaignof1989,Concertaciónpromisedto‘introduceprofoundchangesin thejuridicalpositionoforganisedlabourinorderthatthisprovidesworkers withfundamentalrightsandallowsthe strengthening of labourorganisa- tions;sothatthelattercantransformthemselves intoanefécient toolfor wageearnerinterestsandbecomeasubstantialinèuenceinthesociallifeof thecountry’.49 TheConcertación’sproclaimedrationalewasthat,ifthestate wasgoingtorefrainfrominterventionintheeconomicsphere,thenagreater degree of labourorganisationhadtobe permitted in orderthatitcould protectitsowninterests.With labourstrengthened,itcouldincreaseits bargainingprowessandtherebyensureamoreequitabledistributionofthe increasedsocialproductthateconomicgrowthwouldbring. TheConcertación’sactualrecordofoverturningtherepressive labour legislationenactedduringthePinochetrégime,however,hasbeenpoor.The érstattemptatlabourlegislationwasundertakenbytheAylwingovernment in1990,withtheintentionofestablishinga‘labourinstitutionality’thatwould ensure long-termstabilityowingtothe self-adherence of the majorsocial actors,i.e.co-operationbetween capitalandlabourwithinthestructure of the adjustedlabourcode.Inthisway,thegovernment attemptedtoform anindustrialpactbyprovidingaframework whereby organisedlabour acknowledgedprivateownershipandinvestmentaslegitimatebasesofthe Chileaneconomyandrecognisedtheneedforstabilityandthesuppression ofideologyinnegotiations.Conversely,theprivatesectoraccededtotheneed forsomedegreeofaugmentationfortheminimumwage,pensionsandsocial welfare.50

49 CitedinHenríquezRiquelme1999,p.99. 50 Muñoz&Caledón1996,p.198. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 65

Beyond thispromulgationof arhetorical‘pactforindustrialpeace’,the actualreformsundertakenresultedinminimalchanges.Theprincipaldemands ofthelabourmovement,namelytherighttostrikeandtherighttocollective negotiation,remained frustratedunder the new code.Firstly,the right to strikewasindeedre-established,butwiththeextraordinarilydisempowering provisothattheérmispermittedtohirereplacementlabour.Secondly,whilst unionsarenowallowedincreasedrightstoformregionalornationalfeder- ations,nocollectivebargainingcanproceedabovetheleveloftheindividual unionvis-à-vistheérminquestion.Thisreducesthepowerofthenational bodiesoforganisedlabour:labourfederationsaresolelyallowedtoactasa pressuregroupwithinthepoliticalsystemandcannotendeavourtoestablish nationalagreementsregardingpayorlabourrights. Moreover,whilstthefreedomtoéreworkersatwillwascurtailedinthe new code,arbitraryandanti-union éring practisesnonetheless continue in practiseowing toalegal loopholethatallowsemployerstocite theall- encompassingphrase‘needofthecompany’asthereasonfordismissal.If asackedemployee believes thereasontobe unfair,thenshe mayattempt topursuetheissuewithinlabourtribunalsandcould,ifsuccessful,receive compensation.However,the ineféciency of the labourtribunalsmakesthe processrunextremelyslowlyand,moreover,érmshavepreferredtothepay the énes inorder toretainthe abilitytoérethoseworkersattemptingto establishunions.Unsurprisingly,theInternationalLabourOrganisation hasformallydecriedsuch activities;profoundlydeploring the anti-union conductoférmsinChileandhighlightingmanycasesofunionpersecution througharbitraryéring.51 Moreover,encouragedbytheConcertaciónemphasisonconsensual agreementsbetweencapitalandlabourattheleveloftheérm,awidelyused techniquecalled‘convenio’hasgivenaddedstrengthtoemployers.Convenio signiéesasituationwhere employer andemployees give mutualconsent withinanon-regulateddialoguetoabindingagreementonlabourregulations andpracticethatfallsoutsideoftheinstitutionalisedcode.Itcreatesanindi- vidualrelationshipbetweenemployerandemployeeandforbidscollective actionandstriking.Ithasbeenwidelynotedthatconvenios arenearlyalways formedonthesuggestionoftheemployerandtheirsigningofteninvolves

51 ElMostrador 2001. 66 ï Marcus Taylor coercionorcanformapriorconditionforworkerstogainemployment.52 The principalresultsofconvenios aretosatisfytheemployers’desiretodiminish thepossibilityofindustrialconèictandinsulateworkforceregulationfrom outsideinterference. Notably,throughoutthisérstrenovationofthelabourcode,thegovernment remainedadamantthat,despite the concernsraisedbytheprivatesector, the reformswouldnotfetterthe èexibility of the labourmarket.53 In the contemporaneouswordsofthe ProgramadeEconomiadelTrabajo:‘Itispossible toconérmthattherearemanychangesbutwithlittlesubstance’.54 A secondgovernmentalproposaltostrengthen the rightsof labourhad towaituntiltheendofthedecade.Intherunuptothe2000presidential elections,theConcertaciónattemptedtogarnerthepopularsupportthatthey wererapidly losingtoright-wing populist Joaquín Lavín’scampaignby resurrectinglabourlegislationthathadbeenlanguishinginCongress. Theinitiativeincludedstrengtheningthepoweroforganised labourby reinstatingbargainingabovethelevelofthe individualérm.Additionally, theproposalwouldmakeillegitimatethepractiseofimportingreplacement, non-unionised,labourintheeventofastrike.55 Theattempt,however,backéred withbusinessgroupsquicklymobilisingtomakeastrenuousattackonthe proposedchangesthatwouldhavegivenorganisedlabourrenewedpowers. Ultimately,the government wasunable towin thenecessaryvotesinthe senateandthemeasurewasnotpassed.56 ThenetresultofConcertación’slabourpolicyhasbeentogivefullreign totheintensiéedexploitationoflabourthatprovidedthebasisfortherapid expansionoftheChileaneconomyinthe1990s.Withlabourlegislationserv- ing onlytogiveaminimumlevel of protectiontoworkersandwiththe informalandprecariousnatureofChileanemployment,particularlywithin the service sectorandthe agro-exportsector,much of the labourforce is partiallyortotallyexcludedfromthe protectionnormallyoffered through

52 HenríquezRiquelme1999,p.104. 53 Muñoz&Caledón1996,p.199. 54 HenríquezRiquelme1999,p.99. 55 AngellandPollack2000,p.369. 56 Sincethe advent ofthe Lagos administration there has been afurther reform tothelabourcode,madeinSeptember2001.Whilstgiving workersmoremeansto seek recompense forabuses,itdoesnotaccedetothe basicdemands ofthelabour movementbyremovingtheabovestatedimpedimentstotherighttocollectivenego- tiationandtherighttostrike.SeeTaylor2001. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 67 institutionalised labourrelations.57 Thelackofastrongreaférmationof thelegal rightsof the workingpopulationhasalsoseverely frustratedthe formationofastronglabourmovement.Organisedlabour,evenwithinthe formalsector,hasnotbeenstrengthenedandnumericallyremainsatthesame levelasduringthedictatorship.Afterabriefspurtofuniongrowthinthe érsttwoyearsofConcertación,owingtothemomentumgainedbythelabour movementduring thepre-transitionperiod,unionmembership hassince fallenconsiderably,ashastheincidenceofcollectivenegotiation.58 Theresultsofthisspeciécformofsocialrelationsareclear.Withlabour- powerreproducedasalow-remuneratedandèexiblecommoditywithscant institutionalprotectionororganisationalrights,wageshavedevelopedina particularlyskewedfashionduringtheConcertaciónperiod.Intermsofthe minimum wage,andthereby theincomeof the poorestsectorsof Chilean society,theConcertacióngovernmentshavebowedtopressuretomaintain incrementsatalowlevelinordertomaintainthehighlevelsofsurplus-value extraction.In1997,immediatelypriortothelatestrecession,theminimum wage hadjust regained its1982level andstoodsome30%below its1970 level.59 Similarly,cumulativerealwageincreaseshavefailedtokeeponparwith thoseofproductivity;withproductivityrisingby4.8%overthe1990–8period andwageslaggingbehindat3.6%.60 Moreover,itisessentialtorecognisethat theserealwageincreasesarenotsharedequallybetweenthedifferentlevels ofwage-earnersbutarestratiéedaccordingtothemannerofincomedistribu- tion.TheConcertación’sratherironicpoliticalsloganof‘GrowthWithEquity’ isfundamentallyunderminedbythegovernment’sownstatistics.Provided byMIDEPLAN,thegovernmentsocialplanningbureau,thefollowingtable showsthatthebottom60%ofChileansocietyreceivelessthanone-quarter ofthenationalincome.Whenviewedinaninternationalperspective,the1996 WorldBankreportlabelledChileashavingtheseventhmostunequalincome distributioninthedeveloping world,andtheworstinLatinAmericasave forBrazil.61 Sincethen,economicrecessionin1998–9hasonlyincreasedthe

57 HenríquezRiquelme,p.95. 58 DelaMaza1999,p.383. 59 Coloma&Rojas2000,p.511. 60 Fazio2000,p.54. 61 Meller1999,p.51. 68 ï Marcus Taylor extremepolarityofChileansociety.IMFsourcesshowthatin1998the richest10%of Chilean societyappropriatedten timesthe amountof the poorest20%(41%against4.1%oftotalincome).62

Distributionofincome1987–1998

Quintile 1987 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998

First 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.3 4.1 4.1 Second 7.9 8.2 8.5 8.2 8.2 8.2 Third 11.7 12.3 12.2 12.0 11.9 11.8 Fourth 19.0 18.1 18.4 18.5 19.1 19.1 Fifth 57.2 56.9 56.3 56.9 56.7 56.8

FromMIDEPLAN1999.

Whenviewedincorrelationwiththevastinequalitiesbetweenincomestrata, itbecomesclearpreciselywhohasbeneétedfromtheChilean‘success’.Those inthetop-earningquintilesofChileansocietyhavemaintainedtheirclaim onagargantuanproportionofthesocialproduct,whilsttheChileanworking classhasbeenreproducedasacheapanddisciplinedlabouringpopulation whosewageincreaseshave straggled behind thoseof productivity.The defendersoftheChileanmodeldonotdwellonsuchaspects.Theypreferto notethat,withthegrowthoftheeconomythathasreincorporatedthehuge unemployedreservearmyofthe1980sintotheworkforce(and,toamuch lesserdegree,agovernmentsponsoredanti-povertyprogrammecalledFOSIS) ofécialpovertylevelshavedeclinedfromthe1990levelof38.6%to21.7%in 1998,withextreme povertydeclining from12.9%to5.6%overthe same period.63 Theyoftenfailtomention,however,thatthisrepresentsareturnto thepovertylevelsof1970. A detailedexaminationoftheextentandcapacityofpopularresistanceto theConcertación’sneoliberaltrajectoryduringthe1990sisbeyondthescope ofthisarticle.Nevertheless,itisimportanttonotethatanoft-citeddepoliti- cisationandapathyoftheChileanpopulationinfaceoftheConcertación’s neoliberal commitmentshaswornthinbythe end of the decade.Spurred

62 IMF2000,p.1. 63 Aninat2000,p.4. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 69 onbyadeterioratingeconomicsituation,protesthasbeen expressed in severalforms.Notably,thepreviously comfortableelectoralpredominance oftheConcertaciónhasbeenrendereddistinctlyvulnerable.Whereas,inthe mid-1990s,disaffectedvoterswerestayingathomeorspoilingtheirballots, the 2001presidential election wascharacterisedby the strongmomentum gatheredbyJoaquínLavin’sright-wingbutpopulistcampaign.Theelection wastheclosestinChileanhistoryandendedinanextremelynarrowvictory fortheConcertacióninthesecondroundofvoting.Moreover,amoreradical oppositionmovementiscentredaroundpartiallyresurgentsocialandlabour movements,withsome30,000suchprotestorsdemonstratingin Santiago on1May2001.ItwouldseemthattheConcertación’sattemptstoreconcile disciplinaryneoliberalismwithapoliticalrhetoricofequitabledevelopment are beginning tocrumble in face oftheir multiple contradictionsandthe increasingvulnerabilitiesoftheneoliberalmodel.

VI. The Chilean boom and the global circuits of capital Ofcourse,therapidexpansionoftheChileaneconomyduringthe1990sdoes notrestsolelyuponthecreationofawell-disciplinedandlow-paidlabour force,norisitreducibletothesubordinationofthestatetoreproducingthe conditionsforaugmentedcapitalaccumulation.Asnotedabove,thesocial relationsofcapitalareglobalinnatureandtranscendthenationalstateform. Chile’sintegrationintothecircuitsofglobalcapital,moreover,hasbeenaccen- tuatedowing tothe speciécpolicies of global insertionfashionedby the Pinochetdictatorshipandampliéed undertheConcertación.Assuch,the Chileanboomoftheearly1990scanonlybeunderstoodwithinthecontext ofglobalcapitalaccumulation.Firstly,thedynamicgrowthofChileanpro- ductioninthe1990smirroredchanging conditionsin theglobal political economythathadalteredthepatternofcapitalinvestmentonaglobalscale. Owingtodeeprecessioninthecapitalistcoreatthebeginningofthedecade, capitaltied-up in productiveactivitiesandinvestmentinNorthAmerica, andEuropeincreasinglyassumeditsliquidmoneyformandsought moreproétableoutletsabroad.Withinthiscontext,Chileappearedasapar- ticularlygoodoptionowingtopoliticalstability,agovernmentthatoffered beneétstoforeigncapitaloperatingwithinitsborders,andawiderangeof investmentopportunitiesaffordedbyChile’suniquelyrichnaturalresources. 70 ï Marcus Taylor

Assuch,Chileexperiencedhugeinèowsofforeigncapitalintheearly1990s thatwere employed todevelopthedynamicandproétablesectorsof the Chilean exporteconomy.Such wasthe massofcapitalèowing intoChile that,facedwitharapidlyappreciatingexchangeratewhichthreatenedthe viabilityofChileanexports,theConcertacióngovernmentevenimplemented aformofcapitalcontroltomoderatetheentryofforeigncapital.64 Chile’sexportboomwasalsonecessarilypredicateduponfavourableprices forChileanrawmaterials,particularlycopper, ontheworldmarkets.The highpriceofcopperintheearly1990smeantthatCODELCO,thestate-owned coppercompany,wastemporarilyelevatedintotheworld’ssixmostproét- ablecompanies.However,thegovernmentandobservershaveviewedthe intenseover-relianceonnaturalresourceexportswarily,owingtoissuesof sustainabilityandvulnerabilitytoworldmarketpriceshifts.Atpresent,brute rawmaterialsconstitute44%ofexports,moderatelyprocessedrawmaterials constitute26%,andmanufactured goodsconstituteamere 10%.65 Indeed, under Concertación,therateof growthof manufacturedexportsdropped from32%in1991to8.2%in1997.66 Despitetheseconcerns,however,anoften proclaimedplantomoveintoa‘secondstage’ofEPIbyincreasingexports ofénishedproducts–i.e.movingtoamorelabour-intensiveformofexport industry–hasnotmaterialised.WiththeChileanstateremainingcommitted totheneoliberalprincipalofnon-intervention,globalcapitalhascontinued toenterthesectorsthatofferthehighestproétsby-and-largewithoutregard forfutureimplicationsintermsofsustainability.TheFDIandforeignshort- terminvestmentthatenabledthedramaticexpansionofproductioncontinues tobedirectedprimarilyattheproétablesectorsofcopper,lumberandfruits, therebypromptingacontinuedintensiécationofrawmaterialsexportanda relianceonmarketsthatarebecominghighly competitiveasothernations increasinglyorientatethemselvestowardsexportproduction. ThevulnerabilityofChiletoexternalshockswasrevealedin1998when, facingacollapseoftheAsianmarketsthatpreviouslyabsorbedonethirdof Chileangoodsandrockedby intense capitalèight, theChilean economy slippedintorecession.

64 SeeSoederberg2000. 65 Castillo1997,p.44. 66 Weyland1999,p.81. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 71

ChileanGDPgrowth1991–9

%Growth 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

GDP 8.0 12.3 7.0 5.7 10.6 7.4 7.4 3.4 –1.1

GDPpercapita 6.2 10.4 5.2 4.0 8.9 5.9 5.9 2.0 –2.4

CEPAL.EconomicIndicators.Santiago,Chile:ECLAC/CEPAL.2000.

Despite the projected recovery of growthin 2000–1,certaincontradictions withinthedevelopmentmodelhaveescalatedandstormcloudshangover the future. Firstly,thereisincreasingmarketcompetitionforChilean raw materialsasgrowingnumbers of peripheral nationsareexpanding export production.In1999,forexample,copperpriceshittheirlowestlevelsince 1959andremainstagnantatlessthanthree-quarterstheaveragepricefrom 1975–99.67 Secondly,inresponsetotherecession,thelargeeconomicgroups borrowedhugeamountsofforeigncapitalinordertoacquireassetsinother partsofSouthAmerica.EventheIMFhasexpressedconcernoverthesoaring levelsofprivatedebtinChile,whichdoubledbetween 1997and1999and nowamountstoamassive50%ofannualGDP.68 Bothstateandbusinessin Chilehaverecentlyvigorouslydismissedthepossibilityoftheover-extension ofcreditleadingtoaspirallingénancialcrisisakintothatof1982–3.However, inthecontextoftheglobaleconomicslowdown,thethreatofacontinent- widerecessionhasmanyinvestorsadoptingarathermorenervousattitude.

VII. Concluding remarks ItisnowpossibletoreturntotheIMF’sassertionthatChile’srapidproduc- tivegrowthinthe1990swasdueto‘goodpolicies’andan‘improvedpolitical situation’ andseparatethe realandéctitiousaspectsof thisprognosis.As farasgoodpolicies areconcerned, the IMF isacclaimingthe immutable activitiesoftheChileanstateinfomentinganextremelyhospitableclimate forcapitalaccumulation.Asdetailedabove,thishasbeenachievedbymain- tainingtheessenceoftherelationshipbetweenstate,capitalandlabourforged duringthedictatorship.Inturn,thisactivitybeliestheneoliberalrhetoricof

67 IMF2000,p.105. 68 IMF2000,p.98.Fazio2000,pp.33–5. 72 ï Marcus Taylor adepoliticised,non-interventioniststateanddemonstratesthatthe state remainsanintegralmomentinreproducingthecapitalrelation,althoughits formsofinterventionareconstantlychanging. Likewise,the‘improvedpoliticalsituation’constitutesthesuccessofthe Concertacióngovernmentsincontainingsocialstrugglesthroughareinvention ofneoliberalism within thecontextof electoraldemocracy.In thisrespect, thattherapidgrowthof the Chileaneconomyoccurredimmediately fol- lowingthetransitionfromdictatorshiptoelectoraldemocracywasparticularly wellreceivedbytheIMF,WorldBankandUSStateDepartment,who,during the1990s,havebeenanxioustopromotegloballyacombinationofneoliberal- ismandhighly-élitistinstitutionalrelationssimilartothatofpost-1990Chile.69 Concurrently,theneoliberalartofreducinggovernancetowhatisproclaimed tobe apurelytechnicalanddepoliticisedexerciseseekstofurtherhide the essentialcapitalistnatureofthe statebehind afaçadeoftechnocratic neutrality. Nevertheless,afterdeconstructingtheIMFtalkofgoodpoliciesandimproved politicalsituationbyfurnishingtheseemptyformswithasocialcontent,the Chileaneconomicboomofthe1990smuststillbelocatedwithinahistorically speciécglobal political-economiccontext.The IMF playsdownthisaspect because,byanalysingtheChileanexampleintermsofaformalinstitutional structure andasaseriesof policy decisions,itisabletopresentaglobal prescriptionforgrowthbasedonamodel in abstractionfromrealsocial, politicalandeconomicrelations.IntheChileancase,thismeansturning a blindeyetospeciéctemporalcircumstances(globaleconomicèuctuationsin theearly1990s)andgeographicalparticularities(Chile’srich rawmaterial reserves)inordertocreatetheillusionofauniversallyapplicablemodelfor successbasedonneoliberal fundamentals.Furthermore, itisprofoundly revealingthattheIMFispromotingasasuccessmodelacountrywithone ofthemostpolarisedwealthdistributionsintheworld.Justasitisclearfor whomtheChileanexperience hasbeen asuccess,itisalsoclearinwhose interestsistheglobalisationoftheneoliberalmodel.

69 Robinson1995. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 73

References Angell,AlanandBennyPollack2000,‘TheChileanPresidentialElectionsof1999–2000 andDemocraticConsolidation’,BulletinofLatinAmericanResearch, 19:357–78.

Aninat,Eduardo2000,‘EmbracingDevelopmentOpportunities’,FinanceandDevelopment, 37,1:http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2000/03/aninat.htm

Burnham,Peter2002,‘ClassStruggle,StatesandGlobalCircuitsofCapital’,inHistorical MaterialismandInternationalRelations,edited byMark Rupert and HazelSmith, London:Routledge.

Castillo,PatriciaOlave1997,ElproyectoneoliberalenChileylaconstruccióndeunanueva economía,MexicoCity:UNAM.

Clarke,Simon1978.‘Capital,FractionsofCapitalandtheState’,CapitalandClass,5: 32–77.

Clarke,Simon1991,‘State,ClassStruggle,andtheReproductionofCapital’,inClarke (ed.)1991.

Clarke,Simon(ed.)1991,TheStateDebate,London:Macmillan.

Coloma,FernandoandPatricioRojas2000,‘EvolucióndelmercadolaboralenChile: reformasyresultados’,inLarraínandVergara(eds.)2000.

DelaMaza,Gonzalo1999,‘LosmovimientossocialesenlademocratisacióndeChile’, inDrakeandJaksic(eds.)1999.

Drake,PaulandIvánJaksic (eds.)1999,Elmodelochileno:democraciaydesarolloenlos noventa,Santiago:LOM.

ElMostrador,‘OITacogedenunciacontraChile porprácticasantisindicales’,1July, SantiagodeChile.

Fazio,Hugo2000,Latransnacionalizacióndelaeconomíachilena:mapadelaextremariqueza alaño2000,Santiago:LOM,2000.

Fazio,HugoandManuelRiesco1997,‘ChileanPensionFundAssociations’,NewLeft Review,I,223:90–100.

FinancialTimes,‘Chile’sLeaderTakesCarefulPathtoReform’,1October.

Fine,Bob1984,DemocracyandtheRuleofLaw,London:PlutoPress.

Fortín,Carlos1985,‘ThePoliticalEconomyofRepressiveMonetarism:theStateand CapitalAccumulationinPost-1973Chile’,inTheStateandCapitalAccumulationin LatinAmerica:Volume1,edited byChristianAnglade and CarlosFortín, London: Macmillan. 74 ï Marcus Taylor

Gwynne, Robert and CristóbalKay1997,‘Agrarian Change and theDemocratic TransitioninChile’,BulletinofLatinAmericanResearch,16,1:3–10.

HenríquezRiquelme,Helia1999,‘LasrelacioneslaboralesenChile:unsistemacolec- tivoóunamplioespacioparaladispersión?’,inDrakeandJaksic(eds.)1999.

Hojman,David1995,‘ChileUnderFrei(Again):TheFirstLatinAmericanTiger–or JustAnotherCat?’,BulletinofLatinAmericanResearch,14,2:127–42.

Holloway,John1991,‘TheStateandEverydayStruggle’inClarke(ed.)1991.

Holloway,John1995,‘GlobalCapitalandtheNationalState’,inGlobalCapital,National StateandthePoliticsofMoney,editedbyWernerBonefeldandJohnHolloway,London: Macmillan.

Holloway,JohnandSolPicciotto,1991,‘Capital,CrisisandtheState’,inClarke(ed.) 1991.

Jadresic,Esteban and RobertoZahler 2000,Chile’sRapidGrowthinthe1990s:Good Policies,GoodLuck,orPoliticalChange,IMFWorkingPaperWP/00/153,Washington: IMF.

Larraín,FelipeandRodrigoVergara (eds.)2000,LatransfomacióneconómicaenChile, Santiago:CentrodeEstudiosPúblicos.

Lipietz,Alain1982,‘TowardsGlobalFordism?’,NewLeftReview,I,132:33–47.

IMF2000,Chile:SelectedIssues,IMFStaffCountryReportNo.00/104,Washington: IMF.

Martínez,JavierandAlvaro Díaz1996,Chile:TheGreatTransformation.Washington: TheBrookingsInstitute.

Meller,Patricio1999,‘PobrezaydistribucióndelingresoenChile’,inDrakeandJaksic (eds.)1999.

MIDEPLAN1999,PobrezaydistribucióndeingresoenChile1990–1998,Santiago:MIDE- PLAN.

MuñozGomá,OscarandCarmenCaledón1996,‘ChileinTransition:Economicand PoliticalStrategies’,in EconomicPolicyandtheTransitiontoDemocracy:TheLatin AmericanExperience,edited byJuanAntonio Morales and GaryMcMahon,New York:St.Martin’sPress.

O’Donnell,Guillermo1979,‘TensionsintheBureaucratic-AuthoritarianStateandthe Question ofDemocracy’,inTheNewinLatinAmerica,edited by DavidCollier,Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress.

Petras,JamesandFernando IgnacioLeiva1994,DemocracyandPovertyinChile:The LimitstoElectoralPolitics,Boulder:WestviewPress. An Historical-Materialist Critique of Neoliberalism in Chile ï 75

Portales,Felipe2000,Chile:unademocraciatutelada,Santiago:EditorialSudamericana.

Riesco,Manuel1999,‘Chile,aQuarterofaCenturyOn’,NewLeftReview,I,238:97–125.

Roberts,Kenneth1998,DeepeningDemocracy:TheModernLeftandSocialMovementsin Chileand,Stanford:StanfordUniversityPress.

Robinson,William1995,PromotingPolyarchy,Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.

Roddick,Jacqueline1989,‘TheState,IndustrialRelationsandtheLabourMovement inChile’,inTheState,IndustrialRelationsandtheLabourMovementinLatinAmerica: Vol.1, edited byJeanCarrière,Nigel Haworth,andJacquelineRoddick,London: Macmillan.

Schneider,Cathy1993,‘Chile:The Underside oftheMiracle’,NACLA Reportonthe Americas,26,4:30–1.

Silva,Eduardo1996,TheStateandCapitalinChile:BusinessElites,Technocrats,andMarket Economics,Boulder:WestviewPress.

Silva,Eduardo 1998,‘Organized Business, Neoliberal EconomicRestructuring, and RedemocratizationinChile’,inOrganizedBusiness,EconomicChange,andDemocracy inLatinAmerica,edited byFranciscoDurandandEduardoSilva,Boulder:Lynne RiennerPress.

Siavelis,Peter2000,ThePresidentandCongressinPostauthoritarianChile:Institutional ConstraintstoDemocraticConsolidation, Pennsylvania:PennsylvaniaStateUniversity Press.

Soederberg,Susanne2000,‘ChileanCapitalControls:PrototypeForWhom?’,paper presentedtoBISA annualconference,20December2000,Bradford,UK.

Taylor,Lucy1998,Citizenship,ParticipationandDemocracy:ChangingDynamicsinChile andArgentina,London:Macmillan.

Taylor,Marcus2001,‘LabourReformandSocialEquityinPost-AuthoritarianChile, 1990–2001’,paperpresentedattheannualBISA conference,17–19December2001, Edinburgh,UK.

Torche,ArístidesL.2000,‘Pobreza,necesidadesbásicasydesigualidad:tresobjetivos paraunasolapolíticasocial’,inLarraín&Vergara(eds.)2000.

USStateDepartment2001,AnnualCountryCommercialGuide–Chile,publishedbythe USEmbassy,Santiago.

Weyland,Kurt1999,‘EconomicPolicyinChile’sNewDemocracy’,JournalofInteramerican StudiesandWorldAffairs,41,3:67–96.