California Earthquake Insurance Unpopularity: the Issue Is the Price, Not the Risk Perception Adrien Pothon, Philippe Gueguen, Sylvain Buisine, Pierre-Yves Bard
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
California earthquake insurance unpopularity: the issue is the price, not the risk perception Adrien Pothon, Philippe Gueguen, Sylvain Buisine, Pierre-Yves Bard To cite this version: Adrien Pothon, Philippe Gueguen, Sylvain Buisine, Pierre-Yves Bard. California earthquake insurance unpopularity: the issue is the price, not the risk perception. Natural Hazards and Earth System Sci- ences, Copernicus Publ. / European Geosciences Union, 2019, 19 (8), pp.1909-1924. 10.5194/nhess- 19-1909-2019. hal-03035556 HAL Id: hal-03035556 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-03035556 Submitted on 15 Jan 2021 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Nat. Hazards Earth Syst. Sci., 19, 1909–1924, 2019 https://doi.org/10.5194/nhess-19-1909-2019 © Author(s) 2019. This work is distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 License. California earthquake insurance unpopularity: the issue is the price, not the risk perception Adrien Pothon1,2, Philippe Gueguen1, Sylvain Buisine2, and Pierre-Yves Bard1 1ISTerre, Université de Grenoble-Alpes/Université de Savoie Mont Blanc/CNRS/IRD/IFSTTAR, Grenoble, France 2AXA Group Risk Management, Paris, France Correspondence: Adrien Pothon ([email protected]) Received: 1 February 2019 – Discussion started: 8 February 2019 Revised: 1 August 2019 – Accepted: 2 August 2019 – Published: 29 August 2019 Abstract. Despite California being a highly seismic prone the premium amount, the socio-economic background and region, most homeowners are not covered against this risk. the risk perception (Kunreuther et al., 1978; Palm and Hodg- This study analyses the reasons for homeowners to pur- son, 1992a; Wachtendorf and Sheng, 2002). For the premium chase insurance to cover earthquake losses, with application amount, both a survey conducted by Meltsner (1978) and the in California. A dedicated database is built from 18 differ- statistics collected from insurance data by Buffinton (1961) ent data sources about earthquake insurance, gathering data and Latourrette et al. (2010) show, as expected, a negative since 1921. A new model is developed to assess the take- correlation between the premium amount and the insurance up rate based on the homeowners’ risk awareness and the adoption. Nevertheless, even uninsured homeowners tend to average annual insurance premium amount. Results suggest overestimate the loss they would face in case of a major event that only two extreme situations would lead all owners to and feel vulnerable regardless of their income level (Kun- cover their home with insurance: (1) a widespread belief that reuther et al., 1978; Palm and Hodgson, 1992a). As they are a devastating earthquake is imminent, or alternatively (2) a not expecting much from federal aids, they do not know how massive decrease in the average annual premium amount by they will recover (Kunreuther et al., 1978). a factor exceeding 6 (from USD 980 to 160, 2015 US dol- Consequently the decision to purchase insurance to cover lars). Considering the low likelihood of each situation, we earthquake losses is not correlated to the income level (Kun- conclude from this study that new insurance solutions are reuther et al., 1978; Wachtendorf and Sheng, 2002). Several necessary to fill the protection gap. other socio-economic factors (e.g. the duration of residence, the neighbours’ behaviour, the communication strategies of mass media, real estate agencies and insurance companies) have an impact on the risk perception (Meltsner, 1978; Palm 1 Introduction and Hodgson, 1992a; Lin, 2013). Pricing methods used in the real estate market do not Since 2002, the rate of homeowners insured against earth- take into account seismic risk. Indeed, based on data from quake risk in California has never exceeded 16 %, according the World Housing Encyclopedia, Pothon et al. (2018) have to data provided by the California Department of Insurance shown that building construction price is not correlated to (CDI, 2017b, California Insurance Market Share Reports). the seismic vulnerability rating. Moreover, earthquake in- Such a low rate is surprising in a rich area prone to earth- surance is not mandatory in California for residential mort- quake risk. Consequently, several studies have already inves- gage (CDI, 2019, Information Guides, Earthquake Insur- tigated homeowners’ behaviour regarding earthquake insur- ance). Still, lenders for commercial mortgages are used to ance in California, in order to identify people who might have requiring earthquake insurance only when the probable max- an interest in purchasing earthquake insurance and to under- imum loss is high (Porter et al., 2004). However, Porter et stand why they do not do so. Three main variables have been al. (2004) have shown that taking into account earthquake observed as decisive in purchasing an earthquake insurance: Published by Copernicus Publications on behalf of the European Geosciences Union. 1910 A. Pothon et al.: California earthquake insurance unpopularity risk for calculating the building’s net asset value can have a the acceptable price for consumers to purchase an earthquake significant impact in earthquake-prone areas like California. insurance cover is. Despite results being at the state level, Also, people insured against earthquake risk can receive they bring a new framework to model earthquake insurance a compensation lower than the loss incurred because most consumption which allows us to quantify the gap between earthquake insurance policies in California include a de- premium amount and homeowners’ willingness to pay, de- ductible amount (i.e. at the charge of the policyholder) and pending on the homeowners’ risk awareness. Last, this study are calibrated based on a total reconstruction cost, declared is also innovative by separately modelling the contribution of by the policyholder. As reported by Marquis et al. (2017) the risk perception and the premium amount to the level of after the 2010–2011 Canterbury (NZL) earthquakes, this earthquake insurance consumption. amount can be inadequate for the actual repair costs. Both In the first section, data are collected from several sources, high deductible amount (Meltsner, 1978; Palm and Hodgson, processed and summarized in a new database. A take-up rate 1992b; Burnett and Burnett, 2009) and underestimated total model is then developed by introducing the two following reconstruction cost (Garatt and Marshall, 2003) can make in- explanatory variables: the average premium amount and the sured people feel unprotected after an earthquake, making subjective annual occurrence probability, defined as the risk this kind of insurance disrepute. perceived by homeowners of being affected by a destructive Since homeowners are aware of the destructive potential of earthquake in 1 year. The perceived annual probability of oc- a major earthquake, the risk perception reflects their personal currence is then studied from 1926 to present, in the next estimate of the occurrence (Kunreuther et al., 1978; Wach- section. Finally, the last section is dedicated to analysing the tendorf and Sheng, 2002). Indeed, most of them disregard current low earthquake insurance take-up rate for California this risk because it is seldom, even if destructive earthquake homeowners. experiences foster insurance underwriting during the follow- ing year (Buffinton, 1961; Kunreuther et al., 1978; Meltsner, 1978; Lin, 2015). Consequently, earthquake insurance pur- 2 Data collection and processing chasing behaviour is correlated with personal understanding Developing such a model, even at the state level, faces a first of seismic risk and is not only related to scientific-based haz- challenge in data collection. Despite the California earth- ard level (Palm and Hodgson, 1992a; Palm, 1995; Wachten- quake insurance market having been widely analysed, data dorf and Sheng, 2002). volume before the 1990s remains low and extracted from sci- With limits in earthquake insurance consumption identi- entific and mass media publications which refer to original fied, the next step is to assess the contribution of each fac- data sources that are no longer available. As a consequence, tor to the take-up rate. Kunreuther et al. (1978) first pro- data description is often sparse and incomplete and values posed a sequential model showing that the individual’s pur- can be subject to errors or bias. Consequently, data quality of chasing behaviour depends on personal risk perception, pre- each dataset has to be assessed. Here, it is done on the basis mium amount and knowledge of insurance solutions. In the of the support (scientific publication or mass media), the data same study (Kunreuther et al., 1978), a numerical model was description (quality of information on the data type and the developed, at the same granularity, failing however to accu- collecting process) and the number of records. The datasets rately reproduce the observed behaviours. According to the with the highest quality are used and presented in Table1 authors, the model failed because many surveyed people had (values are